International Tax and Public Finance

, Volume 17, Issue 3, pp 295–314 | Cite as

Political economy of prudent budgetary policy

Open Access
Article

Abstract

The principles of tax smoothing and public debt management with stochastic shocks to future national income are extended for prudence. A prudent government deliberately underestimates future national income and the tax base, especially if the variance and persistence of shocks hitting the tax base are large and the tax rate is high. As a precaution the tax rate is thus set higher and public spending lower to build precautionary buffers. This leads to gradual reductions in debt and debt service over time and thus, depending on political preferences, cuts in taxes or increases in public spending. Prudence offsets the intertemporal spending, tax and debt biases resulting from common-pool distortions. Appointing a strong finance minister with as many voting rights as the spending ministers combined ensures that the intratemporal common-pool distortions of an excessively large public sector are eliminated. A strong and prudent minister of finance can thus offset the impatient profligacy of squabbling spending ministers. However, if voters care about outcomes on election eve, finance ministers are tempted to build excessive precautionary buffers early on to dish out tax cuts and boost spending on election eve. Too much prudence may thus be abused for short-run electoral gains.

Keywords

Precautionary taxation and saving Common pool Electoral budget cycles 

JEL Classification

H21 H60 

References

  1. Aiyagari, R. (1995). Optimal capital income taxation with incomplete markets, borrowing constraints, and constant discounting. Journal of Political Economy, 103(6), 1158–1175. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aiyagari, R., & McGrattan, E. R. (1998). The optimum quantity of debt. Journal of Monetary Economics, 42, 447–469. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Aiyagari, R., Marcet, A., Sargent, T. J., & Seppälä, J. (2002). Optimal taxation without state-contingent debt. Journal of Political Economy, 110(6), 1220–1254. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Alesina, A., & Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Review of Economic Studies, 57(3), 403–414. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Barro, R. J. (1979). On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), 940–971. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Beetsma, R., & van Wijnbergen, S. (2007). Zalm-norm geen zegen maar bron van instabiliteit. Trouw, 14 March. Google Scholar
  7. Bommier, A. (2006). Uncertain lifetime and intertemporal choice: risk aversion as a rationale for time discounting. International Economic Review, 47(4), 1223–1246. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bommier, A., & Rochet, J.-C. (2006). Risk aversion and planning horizons. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(4), 708–734. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Chari, V. V., Christiano, L. J., & Kehoe, P. J. (1994). Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 617–652. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Drazen, A. (2000). The political business cycle after twenty five years (Mimeograph). University of Maryland and Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Google Scholar
  11. Eeckhoudt, L., & Gollier, C. (2005). The impact of prudence on optimal prevention. Economic Theory, 26, 989–994. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Hallerberg, M., & von Hagen, J. (1997). Electoral institutions, cabinet negotiations, and budget deficits in the European Union (Working Paper No. 6341). NBER, Cambridge, MA. Google Scholar
  13. Jacobs, B. (2007). De Zalmnorm en het begrotingsbeleid 1994–2007. Tijdschrift voor Openbare Financiën, 1. Google Scholar
  14. Kimball, M. S. (1990). Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 58, 53–73. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Persson, T., & Svensson, L. E. O. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: policy with time-inconsistent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 325–345. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics. Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Google Scholar
  18. Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169–1189. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36. Google Scholar
  20. Shin, Y. (2006). Ramsey meets Bewley: optimal government financing with incomplete markets (Mimeograph). University of Wisconsin-Madison. Google Scholar
  21. Sibley, D. S. Permanent and transitory effects of optimal consumption with wage income uncertainty, Journal of Economic Theory, 68–82 (1975). Google Scholar
  22. Swank, O. H. (2002). Budgetary devices for curbing spending prone ministers and bureaucrats. Public Choice, 111, 237–257. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Velasco, A. (2000). Debts and deficits with fragmented fiscal policymaking. Journal of Public Economics, 76(1), 105–125. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. van der Ploeg, F. (1993). A closed-form solution for a model of precautionary saving. Review of Economic Studies, 60(2), 385–396. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. van der Ploeg, F. (2007). Prudent budgetary policy—Political economy of precautionary taxation (Working Paper No. 1973). CESifo, Munich. Google Scholar
  26. Von Hagen, J., & Harden, I. J. (1995). Budget processes and commitment to fiscal discipline. European Economic Review, 39, 771–779. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Whittle, P. (1990). Risk-sensitive optimal control. Chichester: Wiley. Google Scholar
  28. Zeldes, S. P. (1989). Optimal consumption with stochastic income: deviations from certainty equivalence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 275–298. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of Oxford, Manor Road BuildingOxfordUK
  2. 2.MlntUniversity of AmsterdamAmsterdamThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations