Advertisement

International Tax and Public Finance

, Volume 12, Issue 4, pp 395–422 | Cite as

Government Weakness and Local Public Debt Development in Flemish Municipalities

  • John AshworthEmail author
  • Benny Geys
  • Bruno Heyndels
Article

Abstract

The Weak Government Hypothesis states that government fragmentation leads to higher public deficits and debt. This relation can be explained by government inaction, common pool problems or the strategic use of debt that arise in coalition governments. Importantly, whereas government inaction models concentrate on the short-term effects of government fragmentation on indebtedness, common pool and strategic debt models imply that such effects will persist in the long term. We test these hypotheses using a large panel of data on municipal debt in 298 Flemish municipalities (1977–2000). We find that there is no long-run effect from weak governments. However, there is general support for the fact that the number of parties in a coalition has a positive effect on the municipality’s short-term debt levels–in line with government inaction models.

Keywords

government fragmentation debt local government 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Alesina, A. and A. Drazen. (1991). “Why are Stabilizations Delayed?” American Economic Review 81(5), 1170–1188.Google Scholar
  2. Alesina, A. and R. Perotti. (1995). “The Political Economy of Budget Deficits,” IMF Staff Papers 42(1), 1–31.Google Scholar
  3. Alesina, A. and G. Tabellini. (1990). “A Positive Theory of Fiscal Deficits and Government Debt,” Review of Economic Studies 57, 403–414.Google Scholar
  4. Alt, J. E. and R. C. Lowry. (1994). “Divided Government, Fiscal Institutions and Budget Deficits: Evidence from the States,” American Political Science Review 88(4), 811–828.Google Scholar
  5. Baber, W. R. and P. K. Sen. (1986). “The Political Process and the use of Debt Financing by State Governments,” Public Choice 48, 201–215.Google Scholar
  6. Balassone, F. and R. Giordano. (2001). “Budget Deficits and Coalition Governments,” Public Choice 106, 327–349.Google Scholar
  7. Banzhaf, J. F. (1965). “Weighted Voting doesn’t Work: A Mathematical Analysis,” Rutgers Law Review 19, 317–343.Google Scholar
  8. Borelli, S. A. and T. J. Royed. (1995). “Government ‘Strength’ and Budget Deficits in Advanced Democracies,” European Journal of Political Research 28, 225–260.Google Scholar
  9. Borge, L.-E. (2003). “The Political Economy of Budget Deficits: A Study of Norwegian Local Governments,” Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Trondheim, mimeo.Google Scholar
  10. Bowling, C. J. and M. R. Ferguson. (2001). “Divided Government, Interest Representation and Policy Differences: Competing Explanations of Gridlock in the Fifty States,” Journal of Politics 63(1), 182–206.Google Scholar
  11. Breitung, J. (2000). “The Local Power of Some Unit Root Tests for Panel Data,” Advances in Econometric: A Research Annual 15, 161–177.Google Scholar
  12. Bulow, J. and P. Klemperer. (1999). “The Generalised War of Attrition,” American Economic Review 89, 175–189.Google Scholar
  13. Clingermayer, J. C. and D. B. Wood. (1995). “Disentangling Patterns of State Debt Financing,” American Political Science Review 89(1), 108–120.Google Scholar
  14. Davidson, R. and J. G. MacKinnon. (1981). “Several Test for Model Specification in the Presence of Alternative Hypotheses,” Econometrica 49, 781–793.Google Scholar
  15. de Haan, J. and J.-E. Sturm. (1994). “Political and Institutional Determinants of Fiscal Policy in the European Community,” Public Choice 80(1–2), 157–172.Google Scholar
  16. de Haan, J. and J.-E. Sturm. (1997). “Political and Economic Determinants of OECD Budget Deficits and Government Expenditures: A Reinvestigation,” European Journal of Political Economy 13, 739–750.Google Scholar
  17. de Haan, J., J.-E. Sturm and G. Beekhuis. (1999). “The Weak Government Hypothesis: Some New Evidence,” Public Choice 101, 163–176.Google Scholar
  18. Deschouwer, K. (1996). “Nationale partijen en gemeenteraadsverkiezingen.” In J. Buelens and K. Deschouwer (Eds.), De dorpsstraat is de wetstraat niet Brussels: VUBPress, pp. 13–25.Google Scholar
  19. Dexia. (2001). “Analyse van de lokale financiën vanuit de invalshoek van de national rekeningen (1970–2000). In De Financiën van de Lokale Overheden in 2000 Brussels: Dexia Bank, pp. 103–135.Google Scholar
  20. Edin, P.-A. and H. Ohlsson. (1991). “Political Determinants of Budget Deficits: Coalition Effects versus Minority Effects,” European Economic Review 35, 1597–1603.Google Scholar
  21. Fernandez, R. and D. Rodrik. (1991). “Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty,” American Economic Review 81(5), 1146–1155.Google Scholar
  22. Fiorino, N. and U. Triacca. (2003). “Coalition Governments and Fiscal Performance in Italy (1950-1992). An Impulse Response Analysis,” paper presented at the annual EPCS-conference, 26–28 April, Aarhus, 20pp.Google Scholar
  23. Franzese, R. J. (2001). “The Positive Political Economy of Public Debt: An Empirical Examination of the OECD Postwar Experience,” University of Michigan, mimeo.Google Scholar
  24. Freitag, M. and P. Sciarini. (2001). “The Political Economy of Budget Deficits in the European union: the Role of International Constraints and Domestic Structure,” European Union Politics 2(2), 163–189.Google Scholar
  25. Galli, E and F. Padovano. (2002). A “Comparative Test of Alternative Theories of the Determinants of Italian Public Deficits (1950–1998),” Public Choice 113, 37–58.Google Scholar
  26. Glazer, A. (1989). “Politics and the Choice of Durability,” American Economic Review 79(5), 1207–1213.Google Scholar
  27. Grilli, V., D. Masciandaro and G. Tabellini. (1991). “Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the Industrial Countries,” Economic Policy 13, 342–392.Google Scholar
  28. Hadri, K. (2000). “Testing for Stationarity in Heterogeneous Panel Data,” Econometrics Journal 3, 148–161.Google Scholar
  29. Hagen, T. P. and S. I. Vabo. (2005). “Political Characteristics, Institutional Procedures and Fiscal Performance: Panel Analysies in Norwegian Local Governments, 1991–1998,” European Journal of Political Research 44(1), 43–64.Google Scholar
  30. Hahm, S. D., M. S. Kamlet and D. C. Mowery. (1996). “The Political Economy of Deficit Spending in Nine Industrialized Parliamentary Democracies: The Role of Fiscal Institutions,” Comparative Political Studies 29(1), 52–77.Google Scholar
  31. Hallerberg, M. and J. Von Hagen. (1999). “Electoral Institutions, Cabinet Negotiations and Budget Deficits in the European Union.” In J. M. Poterba and J. von Hagen (Eds.), Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 209–232Google Scholar
  32. Harris, R. and R. Sollis. (2003). Applied Time Series Modelling and Forecasting John Wiley, Chichester.Google Scholar
  33. Hibbs, D. (1977). “Political Parties and Macro-Economic Policy,” American Political Science Review 71, 1467–1487.Google Scholar
  34. Howitt, P. and R. Wintrobe. (1995). “The Political Economy of Inaction,” Journal of Public Economics 56, 329–353.Google Scholar
  35. Huber, G., M. Kocher and M. Sutter. (2003). “Government Strength, Power Dispersion in Governments and Budget Deficits in OECD Countries. A Voting Power Approach,” Public Choice 116(3–4), 333–350.Google Scholar
  36. Im, K. S., M. H. Pesaran and Y. Shin. (2003). “Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous Panels,” Journal of Econometrics 115, 53–74.Google Scholar
  37. Imbeau, L. M. and K. Chenard. (2002). “The Political Economy of Public Deficits: A Review Essay,” ECPR Working Paper 2002–01, 27 pp.Google Scholar
  38. Imbeau, L. M., F. Pétry and M. Lamari. (2001). “Left-Right Party Ideology and Government Policies: A Meta-Analysis,” European Journal of Political Research 40, 1–29.Google Scholar
  39. Jochimsen B. and R. Nuscheler. (2004). “The Political Economy of the German Länder Deficits,” paper presented at the annual EPCS-Conference 2004, Berlin, Germany, 25 pp.Google Scholar
  40. Jones, M. P., P. Sanguinetti and M. Tommasi. (2000). “Politics, Institutions and Fiscal Performance in a Federal System: An Analysis of the Argentine Provinces,” Journal of Development Economics 61(2), 305–333.Google Scholar
  41. Kalseth, J. and J. Rattsø. (1998). “Political Control of Administrative Spending: the Case of Local Governments in Norway,” Economics and Politics 10(1), 63–83.Google Scholar
  42. Kao, C. H. (1999). “Spurious Regression and Residual Based Tests of Cointegration in Panel Data,” Journal of Econometrics 90, 1–44.Google Scholar
  43. Kirchgässner, G. (2003). “The Effects of Fiscal Institutions on Public Finance: a Survey of the Empirical Evidence.” In S. Winer and H. Shibata. (Eds.), Political Economy and Public Finance Cheltanham: Edward Elgar Publishing Inc., pp. 145–177.Google Scholar
  44. Kontopoulos, Y. and R. Perotti. (1998). Fragmented Fiscal Policy. Columbia University mimeo.Google Scholar
  45. Kontopoulos, Y. and R. Perotti. (1999). “Government Fragmentation and Fiscal Policy Outcomes: Evidence from OECD Countries.” In J. M. Poterba and J. Von Hagen (Eds.), Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance (NBER Conference Report). Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 81–102.Google Scholar
  46. Krause, G. A. (2000). “Partisan and Ideological Sources of Fiscal Deficits in the United States,” American Journal of Political Science 44(3), 541–559.Google Scholar
  47. Laakso, M. and R. Taagepera. (1979). “Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe,” Comparative Political Studies 12(1), 3–27.Google Scholar
  48. Lambertini, L. (2003). “Are Budget Deficits used Strategically?” Boston College Working Paper in Economics, no. 578, 38 pp.Google Scholar
  49. Lijphart, A. and M. M. L. Crepaz. (1991). “Corporatism and Consensus Democracy in Eighteen Countries: Conceptual and Empirical Linkages,” British Journal of Political Science 21, 235–256.Google Scholar
  50. McCoskey, S. and C. H. Kao. (1999). “Testing for the Stability of a Production Function with Urbanisation as a Shift Factor,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61(4), 671–690.Google Scholar
  51. Millar, J. (1997). “The Effects of Budgetary Rules on Fiscal Performance and Macroeconomic Stabilisation,” Bank of Canada Working Paper nr. 97–15, 49 pp.Google Scholar
  52. Moesen, W. (1985). “De gemeentefinanciën in België,” Maandblad Economie 49(4), 363–367.Google Scholar
  53. Myers, S. C. (1984). “The Capital Structure Puzzle,” Journal of Finance 39, 575–592.Google Scholar
  54. Myers, S. C. and N. Majluf. (1984). “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions when Firms have Information that Investors do not have,” Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187–221.Google Scholar
  55. Neto O. A., F. Blanco and H. Borsani. (2001). “The Political Determinants of Public Deficits in Latin America (1980–1998),” paper presented at the annual Latin American Studies Association meeting 2001, Washington DC, 29 pp.Google Scholar
  56. Olson, M. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Olson, M. (1993). “Dictatorship, Democracy and Development,” American Political Science Review 87(3), 567–576.Google Scholar
  58. Padovano, F. and L. Venturi. (2001). “Wars of Attrition in Italian Government Coalitions and Fiscal Performance: 1948–1994,” Public Choice 109, 15–54.Google Scholar
  59. Pedroni, P. (1995). “Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties in Pooled Time Series Tests with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis,” Indiana University Working Papers in Economics no. 95–013.Google Scholar
  60. Pedroni, P. (1999). “Critical Values for Cointegration Tests in Heterogeneous Panels with Multiple Regressors,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61(4), 653–670.Google Scholar
  61. Perotti, R. and Y. Kontopoulos. (2002). “Fragmented Fiscal Policy,” Journal of Public Economics 86, 191–222.Google Scholar
  62. Perron, P. (1988). “Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Further Evidence from a New Approach,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12(2–3), 297–332.Google Scholar
  63. Persson, T. and L. Svensson. (1989). “Why a Stubborn Conservative would run a Deficit: Policy with Time-Inconsistent Preferences,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(2), 325–345.Google Scholar
  64. Petterson-Lidbom, P. (2001). “An Empirical Investigation of Strategic Use of Debt, Journal of Political Economy,” 109(3), 570–583.Google Scholar
  65. Poterba, J. M. (1994). “State Responses to Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions and Politics,” Journal of Political Economy 102(4), 799–821.Google Scholar
  66. Rae, D. W. (1971). The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, Revised edition. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  67. Rattsø, J. and P. Tovmo. (2002). “Fiscal Discipline and Asymmetric Adjustment of Revenues and Expenditures: Local Government Responses to Shocks in Denmark,” Public Finance Review 30(3), 208–234.Google Scholar
  68. Ricciuti, R. (2004). “Political Fragmentation and Fiscal Outcomes,” Public Choice 118, 365–388.Google Scholar
  69. Roubini, N. and J. D. Sachs. (1989a). “Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies,” European Economic Review 33, 903–938.Google Scholar
  70. Roubini, N. and J. D. Sachs. (1989b). “Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries,” Economic Policy: A European Forum 8, 99–132.Google Scholar
  71. Rumi, C. (2004). “Political Determinants of Fiscal Performance for the Argentine Provinces,” paper presented at the annual PCS-Conference 2004, Baltimore, 18 pp.Google Scholar
  72. Schaltegger, C. A. and L. P. Feld. (2004). “Do Large Cabinets Favor Large Governments? Evidence from Sub-Federal Jurisdictions,” CESifo Working Paper Series no. 1294, 27 pp.Google Scholar
  73. Schmidt, M.G. (1996). “When Parties Matter, A Review of the Possibilities and Limits of Partisan Influence of Public Policy,” European Journal of Political Research 30, 155–183.Google Scholar
  74. Shapley, L. S. and M. Shubik. (1954). “A Method for Evaluating the Distribution of Power in a Committee Systems,” American Political Science Review 48, 787–792.Google Scholar
  75. Sutter, M. (2003). “The Political Economy of Fiscal Policy: An Experimental Study on the Strategic Use of Deficits,” Public Choice 116(3–4), 313–332.Google Scholar
  76. Tabellini, G. and A. Alesina. (1990). “Voting on the Budget Deficit,” American Economic Review 80(1), 37–49.Google Scholar
  77. Tornell, A. and P. R. Lane. (1999). “The Voracity Effect,” American Economic Review 89(1), 22–46.Google Scholar
  78. Tovmo, P. (2001). “Budgetary Procedures and Deficits in Norwegian Local Governments,” Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Trondheim, mimeo.Google Scholar
  79. Tsebelis, G. (1995a). “Decision-Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism,” British Journal of Political Science 25(3), 289–325.Google Scholar
  80. Tsebelis, G. (1995b). “Veto Players and Law Production in Parliamentary Democracies.” In H. Döring (Ed.), Parliaments and Majority Rule in Western Europe. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, pp. 83–111.Google Scholar
  81. Tullock, G. (1959). “Problems of Majority Voting,” Journal of Political Economy 67, 571–579.Google Scholar
  82. Van Audenhove, M. (1990). Geschiedenis van de gemeentefinanciën in de economische, financiële en sociale evolutie van België 1918–1985. Gemeentekrediet, Brussel.Google Scholar
  83. Velasco, A. (1999). “A Model of Endogenous Fiscal Deficits and Delayed Fiscal Reforms.” In J. M. Poterba and J. Von Hagen (Eds.), Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance(NBER Conference Report). Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 37–57.Google Scholar
  84. Velasco, A. (2000). “Debts and Deficits with Fragmented Fiscal Policymaking,” Journal of Public Economics 76, 105–125.Google Scholar
  85. Volkerink, B. (1999). “Political and Institutional Determinants of Budget Deficits: A Review and Some New Empirical Evidence for OECD Countries,” mimeo.Google Scholar
  86. Volkerink, B. and J. de Haan. (2001). “Fragmented Government Effects on Fiscal Policy: New Evidence,” Public Choice 109, 221–242.Google Scholar
  87. Weingast, B. R., K. A. Shepsle and C. Johnson. (1981). “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics,” Journal of Political Economy 89(4), 642–664.Google Scholar
  88. Woo, J. (2003). “Economic, Political and Institutional Determinants of Public Deficits,” Journal of Public Economics 87, 387–426.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. 2005

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of DurhamDurhamEngland
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsVrije Universiteit BrusselBrusselBelgium

Personalised recommendations