Advertisement

Effects of funding mechanisms on participation in multilateral environmental agreements

  • Steffen Mohrenberg
  • Vally KoubiEmail author
  • Thomas Bernauer
Original Paper
  • 61 Downloads

Abstract

The “rational design approach” to studying international agreements holds that policy-makers evaluate costs and benefits of cooperation when designing treaties and subsequently deciding on participation. To influence this cost–benefit calculus, treaty designers sometimes include a fund from which financial assistance is provided to treaty members and to which treaty members contribute. We argue that the inclusion of a funding mechanism in a treaty can increase but also decrease the costs (benefits) of membership and can thus influence state choices on participation in both directions. Specifically, we argue that: (1) overall, states are more likely to join international agreements that include a fund; (2) the probability of joining is higher for agreements including a fund if contributions to the fund are voluntary; and (3) countries are more likely to join agreements including a fund that disburses assistance only to a select group of treaty members. We test these arguments using a new dataset with information on 154 countries’ ratification behavior toward 178 multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs) from 1950 to 2011. Our findings are in line with these arguments. The main policy implication is that MEA designers interested in maximizing treaty participation should include a formal funding mechanism and, in an effort to balance out positive and negative effects this might have on participation, base this mechanism on voluntary contributions and selective entitlements.

Keywords

Multilateral environmental agreements Ratification Fund Voluntary contributions Fund usage 

Notes

References

  1. Barrett, S. (2005). Environment and statecraft: The strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  3. Beck, N., Katz, J. N., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously. Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 42(4), 1260–1288.Google Scholar
  4. Benedick, R. E. (1991). Ozone diplomacy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2010). A comparison of international and domestic sources of global governance dynamics. British Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 509–538.Google Scholar
  6. Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2013). Is there a “Depth versus Participation” dilemma in international cooperation? Review of International Organizations, 8(4), 477–497.Google Scholar
  7. Beron, K. J., Murdoch, J. C., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). Why cooperate? Public goods, economic power, and the Montreal Protocol. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 286–297.Google Scholar
  8. Böhmelt, T., & Spilker, G. (2016). The interaction of international institutions from a social network perspective. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 16(1), 67–89.Google Scholar
  9. Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.Google Scholar
  10. Chayes, A. H., & Chayes, A. (1990). From law enforcement to dispute settlement: A new approach to arms control verification and compliance. International Security, 14(4), 147–164.Google Scholar
  11. Chayes, A., & Chayes, A. H. (1993). On compliance. International Organization, 47(2), 175–205.Google Scholar
  12. Chayes, A., & Chayes, A. H. (1995). The new sovereignty: Compliance with international regulatory agreements. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Cui, L., & Gui, H. (2015). Sharing the burden of financing the green climate fund in the Post-Kyoto era. International Journal of Climate Change Strategies and Management, 7(2), 206–221.Google Scholar
  14. de Zeeuw, A. (2015). International environmental agreements. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 7(1), 151–168.Google Scholar
  15. DeSombre, E. R., & Kauffman, J. (1996). The Montreal Protocol multilateral fund: Partial success story. In R. O. Keohane & M. A. Levy (Eds.), Institutions for environmental aid (pp. 91–126). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  16. Dinda, S. (2004). Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis: A survey. Ecological Economics, 49(4), 431–455.Google Scholar
  17. Downs, G. W., Rocke, D. M., & Barsoom, P. N. (1996). Is the good news about compliance good news about cooperation? International Organization, 50(03), 379–406.Google Scholar
  18. Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M. P. (2015). The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150–3182.Google Scholar
  19. Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (2000). Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: What determines legislative delay? Public Choice, 104(3), 345–368.Google Scholar
  20. Fridahl, M., & Linnér, B.-O. (2016). Perspectives on the green climate fund: Possible compromises on capitalization and balanced allocation. Climate and Development, 8(2), 105–109.Google Scholar
  21. Gleditsch, K. S. (2002). Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46, 712–724.Google Scholar
  22. Guzman, A. T. (2005). The design of international agreements. The European Journal of International Law, 16(4), 579–612.Google Scholar
  23. Hathaway, O. A. (2003). The cost of commitment. Stanford Law Review, 55, 1821–1862.Google Scholar
  24. Hathaway, O. A. (2008). Treaties’ end: The past, present and future of international lawmaking in the United States. Yale Law Journal, 117(7), 1236–1372.Google Scholar
  25. King, G., Tomz, M., & Wittenberg, J. (2000). Making the most of statistical analyses: Improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 44(2), 341–355.Google Scholar
  26. Koremenos, B. (2005). Contracting around international uncertainty. The American Political Science Review, 99(4), 549–565.Google Scholar
  27. Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55(4), 761–799.Google Scholar
  28. Markandya, A., Antimiani, A., Costantini, V., Martini, C., Palma, A., & Tommasino, M. C. (2015). Analyzing trade-offs in international climate policy options: The case of the green climate fund. World Development, 74, 93–107.Google Scholar
  29. Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2002). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 18002002. http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm.
  30. McGrath, L. F. (2015). Estimating onsets of binary events in panel data. Political Analysis, 23(4), 534–549.Google Scholar
  31. Mitchell, R. B. (1994). Regime design matters: Intentional oil pollution and treaty compliance. International Organization, 48(3), 425–458.Google Scholar
  32. Mitchell, R. B. (2014). International environmental agreements database project (Version 2014.3). http://iea.uoregon.edu/.
  33. Mitchell, R. B., & Keilbach, P. M. (2001). Situation structure and institutional design: Reciprocity, coercion, and exchange. International Organization, 55(4), 891–917.Google Scholar
  34. Noakes, D. J., Fang, L., Hipel, K. W., & Kilgour, D. M. (2005). The Pacific Salmon Treaty: A century of debate and an uncertain future. Group Decision and Negotiation, 14(6), 501–522.Google Scholar
  35. Perrin, S., & Bernauer, T. (2010). International regime formation revisited: Explaining ratification behaviour with respect to Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution Agreements in Europe. European Union Politics, 11(3), 405–426.Google Scholar
  36. Pevehouse, J. C., Nordstrom, T., & Warnke, K. (2004). The COW-2 international organizations dataset version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 101–119.Google Scholar
  37. Rao, P. K. (2002). International Environmental Law and Economics. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
  38. Raustiala, K. (2005). Form and substance in international agreements. The American Journal of International Law, 99(3), 581–614.Google Scholar
  39. Roberts, J. T., Parks, B. C., & Vasquez, A. (2004). Who ratifies environmental treaties and why? Institutionalism, structuralism and participation by 192 nations in 22 treaties. Global Environmental Politics, 4(3), 22–64.Google Scholar
  40. Rosendorff, B. P., & Milner, H. V. (2001). The optimal design of international trade institutions: Uncertainty and escape. International Organization, 55(4), 829–857.Google Scholar
  41. Sælen, H. (2016). Side-payments: An effective instrument for building climate clubs? International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 16(6), 909–932.Google Scholar
  42. Smith, S. J., van Aardenne, J., Klimont, Z., Andres, R. J., Volke, A., & Delgado Arias, S. (2011a). Anthropogenic sulfur dioxide emissions, 1850-2005: National and regional data set by source category, Version 2.86. NASA Socioeconomic Data and Applications Center (SEDAC). http://dx.doi.org/10.7927/H49884X9. Accessed 25 July, 2016.
  43. Smith, S. J., van Aardenne, J., Klimont, Z., Andres, R. J., Volke, A., & Delgado Arias, S. (2011b). Anthropogenic sulfur dioxide emissions: 1850–2005. Atmospheric Chemistry and Physics, 11, 1101–1116.Google Scholar
  44. Spilker, G., & Koubi, V. (2016). The effects of treaty legality and domestic institutional hurdles on environmental treaty ratification. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 16(2), 223–238.Google Scholar
  45. Stern, D. I. (2005). Global sulfur emissions from 1850 to 2000. Chemosphere, 58, 163–175.Google Scholar
  46. Subramanian, N., & Urpelainen, J. (2014). Addressing cross-border environmental displacement: When can international treaties help? International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 14(1), 25–46.Google Scholar
  47. UNDP. (2016). Pursuing the 1.5°C limit: Benefits and opportunities. www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/librarypage/climate-and-disaster-resilience-/pursuing-the-1-5c-limit—benefits-and-opportunities.html. Accessed July 21, 2017.
  48. von Stein, J. (2008). The international law and politics of climate change: Ratification of the United Nations Framework Convention and the Kyoto Protocol. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(2), 243–268.Google Scholar
  49. Wangler, L., Altamirano-Cabrera, J.-C., & Weikard, H.-P. (2013). The political economy of international environmental agreements: A Survey. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 13(3), 387–403.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature B.V. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Steffen Mohrenberg
    • 1
  • Vally Koubi
    • 1
    Email author
  • Thomas Bernauer
    • 1
  1. 1.ETH ZurichZurichSwitzerland

Personalised recommendations