Advertisement

Blocking change: facing the drag of status quo fisheries institutions

  • Mark Axelrod
Original Paper
  • 134 Downloads

Abstract

Under what conditions can international environmental institutions survive changing power alignments? This article argues that relatively declining powers and private domestic actors play an important role in preserving the status quo because they are eager to retain advantages that existing institutions afford them. This effort to block change affects fisheries negotiations, in particular, by allowing powerful actors to avoid new rules once an institution is in place. I hypothesize, first, that relatively declining fishing powers attempt to retain past institutional successes, while emerging fishing powers seek to alter the status quo. Second, negotiating positions reflect not only a country’s position in the world, but also the access provided to domestic stakeholders who wish to gain, or fear losses, from new agreements. Therefore, I hypothesize that powerful beneficiaries in domestic politics push relatively declining powers to support the status quo when those private actors benefit from highly legalized past agreements and participate in foreign policy decisions. I test these hypotheses by exploring US and EU approaches to fisheries treaty negotiations through archival research and interviews with fisheries negotiators. The evidence supports hypotheses that status quo powers seek to protect earlier deals more intensely when they negotiate with rising fishing powers, and when private parties are most influential. As hypothesized, both governments are particularly protective of the most complex earlier agreements under these conditions.

Keywords

Fisheries negotiations Historical institutionalism Power shifts Domestic politics Path dependence 

Notes

Acknowledgments

This study benefited from thoughtful anonymous reviewer comments, as well as comments on earlier iterations by Tim Büthe, Joe Grieco, Margaret McKean, Michael Schechter, David Soskice, Bill Taylor, and participants in the 2014 Norwich Conference on Earth System Governance. I also thank the US and EU officials who gave their time to discuss negotiating experiences.

References

  1. Aggarwal, V. K. (Ed.). (1998). Institutional designs for a complex world: Bargaining, linkages and nesting. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Alter, K. J. (2006). Private litigants and the new international courts. Comparative Political Studies, 39(1), 22–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Axelrod, M. (2011). Climate change and global fisheries management: Linking issues to protect ecosystems or to save political interests? Global Environmental Politics, 11(3), 64–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Balton, D. A. (2004). International fisheries: Testimony before the House Committee on Resources, Subcommittee on Fisheries Conservation, Wildlife, and Oceans. http://www.state.gov/g/oes/rls/rm/2004/32245.htm. Accessed December 4, 2007.
  5. Balton, D. A. (2005). Ocean treaties: Senate Committee on Foreign Relations. http://www.state.gov/g/oes/rls/rm/54128.htm. Accessed December 4, 2007.
  6. Barkin, J. S., & DeSombre, E. R. (2013). Saving global fisheries: Reducing fishing capacity to promote sustainability. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  7. Bennett, A. (2004). Case study methods: Design, use, and comparative advantages. In D. F. Sprinz & Y. Wolinsky-Nahmias (Eds.), Models, numbers, and cases: Methods for studying international relations (pp. 19–55). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  8. Bretherton, C., & Vogler, J. (2008). The European Union as a sustainable development actor: The case of External Fisheries Policy. Journal of European Integration, 30(3), 401–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Caddy, J. F. (1996). An objective approach to the negotiation of allocations from shared living resources. Marine Policy, 20(2), 145–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Council of the European Union. (2004). Communication from the Commission on an Integrated Framework for Fisheries Partnership Agreements with Third Countries—Draft Council conclusions. COM(2002) 637 final (15243/02 PECHE 224). 7 July.Google Scholar
  11. Daw, T., & Gray, T. (2005). Fisheries science and sustainability in international policy: A study of failure in the European Union’s Common Fisheries Policy. Marine Policy, 29(3), 189–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Deere, C. (2000). Net gains: Linking fisheries management, international trade and sustainable development. Cambridge: IUCN.Google Scholar
  13. DeSombre, E. R. (2000). Domestic sources of international environmental policy: Industry, environmentalists, and U.S. power. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  14. DeSombre, E., & Barkin, J. S. (2000). Unilateralism and multilateralism in international fisheries management. Global Governance, 6(3), 339–360.Google Scholar
  15. DG Fisheries. (2006). Interview, European Commission, DG Fisheries. Belgium: Brussels.Google Scholar
  16. Directorate-General for Fisheries and Maritime Affairs – European Commission. (2007). The European Community External Fisheries Policy. http://europa.eu.int/comm/fisheries/policy_en.htm. Accessed 9 Oct 2007.
  17. Drezner, D. W. (2007). All politics is global: Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  18. European Commission. (1999). Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament: Community participation in Regional Fisheries Organisations (RFOs). COM(1999) 613 final. 8 December.Google Scholar
  19. European Commission. (2002). Communication from the Commission on an integrated framework for fisheries partnership agreements with third countries. COM(2002) 637 final. 23 December.Google Scholar
  20. European Commission. (2007). Bilateral fisheries partnership agreements between the EC and third countries. http://ec.europa.eu/fisheries/cfp/external_relations/bilateral_agreements_en.htm. Accessed October 9, 2007.
  21. European Community. (2009). The common fisheries policy: A user’s guide. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.Google Scholar
  22. Eurostat/FAO. (2014). Annual catches in all regions as % of total world catches. http://europa.eu/pol/fish/index_en.htm. Accessed June 2014.
  23. FAO. (2012). Yearbook of fishery statistics. ftp://fao.org/fi/stat/summary/default.htm.
  24. Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1146–1155.Google Scholar
  25. Grafton, R. Q., Hilborn, R., Ridgeway, L., Squires, D., Williams, M., Garcia, S., et al. (2008). Positioning fisheries in a changing world. Marine Policy, 32(4), 630–634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Harsem, Ø., & Hoel, A. H. (2012). Climate change and adaptive capacity in fisheries management: The case of Norway. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 13, 49–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Helfer, L. R. (2009). Regime shifting in the international intellectual property system. Perspectives on Politics, 7(1), 39–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Johnstone, N. (1996). The economics of fisheries access agreements: Perspectives on the EU-senegal case. Environmental economics programme discussion paper. London: International Institute for Environment and Development.Google Scholar
  30. Kaczynski, V. M., & Fluharty, D. L. (2002). European policies in West Africa: Who benefits from fisheries agreements? Marine Policy, 26(2), 75–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kahler, M. (2000). Conclusion: The causes and consequences of legalization. International Organization, 54(3), 661–683.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Kelemen, R. D., & Vogel, D. (2010). Trading places: The role of the United States and the European Union in international environmental politics. Comparative Political Studies, 43(4), 427–456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Keohane, R. O., Moravcsik, A., & Slaughter, A.-M. (2000). Legalized dispute resolution: Interstate and transnational. International Organization, 54(3), 457–488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Kerr, W. A. (1999). International trade in transgenic food products: A new focus for agricultural trade disputes. The World Economy, 22(2), 245–259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55(4), 761–799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. LaFraniere, S. (2008). Europe takes Africa’s fish, and boatloads of migrants follow. New York City: New York Times.Google Scholar
  39. Le Manach, F., Andriamahefazafy, M., Harper, S., Harris, A., Hosch, G., Lange, G.-M., et al. (2013). Who gets what? Developing a more equitable framework for EU fishing agreements. Marine Policy, 38, 257–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Mitchell, R. B. (1999). International environmental common pool resources: More common than domestic but more difficult to manage. In J. S. Barkin & G. Shambaugh (Eds.), Anarchy and the environment: The international relations of common pool resources (pp. 26–50). Albany, NY: SUNY Press.Google Scholar
  41. Mitchell, R. B. (2012). Oran Young and international institutions. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 13, 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Mutume, G. (2002). Africa seeks to safeguard its fisheries. Africa Recovery, 16(1), 12.Google Scholar
  43. Negroponte, J. D. (2007). The UN Convention on the Law of the Sea: Written testimony before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee. http://www.state.gov/s/d/2007/92921.htm. Accessed 4 Dec 2007.
  44. Oberthür, S., & Gehring, T. (2006). Conceptual foundations of institutional interaction. In S. Oberthür & T. Gehring (Eds.), Institutional interaction in global environmental governance: Synergy and conflict among international and EU policies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  45. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Pauly, D., Christensen, V., Dalsgaard, J., Froese, R., & Torres, F. (1998). Fishing down marine food webs. Science, 279, 860–863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Pauly, D., Watson, R., & Alder, J. (2005). Global trends in world fisheries: Impacts on marine ecosystems and food security. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 360, 5–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Pierson, P. (2000). Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics. American Political Science Review, 94(2), 251–267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Pierson, P., & Skocpol, T. (2002). Historical institutionalism in contemporary political science. In I. Katznelson & H. V. Milner (Eds.), Political science: The state of the discipline. Washington, DC: Norton.Google Scholar
  50. Princen, S. (2010). Venue shifts and policy change in EU fisheries policy. Marine Policy, 34(1), 36–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Rosen, F., & Olsson, P. (2013). Institutional entrepreneurs, global networks, and the emergence of international institutions for ecosystem-based management: The Coral Triangle Initiative. Marine Policy, 38, 195–204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Rosenthal, E. (2008). Europe’s appetite for seafood propels illegal trade. New York City: New York Times.Google Scholar
  53. Sebenius, J. K. (1983). Negotiation arithmetic: Adding and subtracting issues and parties. International Organization, 37(2), 281–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Shaffer, G. C. (2003). Defending interests: Public–private partnerships in WTO litigation. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
  55. Taft, W. H. (2003). Accession to the 1982 Law of the Sea Convention and ratification of the 1994 Agreement amending part XI of the Law of the Sea Convention: Testimony before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee. http://www.state.gov/g/oes/rls/rm/2003/25573.htm. Accessed 4 Dec 2007.
  56. Tansey, O. (2007). Process tracing and elite interviewing: A case for non-probability sampling. PS. Political Science and Politics, 40(4), 765–772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Turner, J. F. (2003). Accession to the 1982 Law of the Sea Convention and ratification of the 1994 Agreement amending part XI of the Law of the Sea Convention: Testimony before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee. http://www.state.gov/g/oes/rls/rm/2003/25572.htm. Accessed 4 Dec 2007.
  59. Undercurrent News. (2015). EU, Mauritania reach new deal on fisheries. https://www.undercurrentnews.com/2015/07/13/eu-mauritania-reach-new-deal-on-fisheries/. Accessed May 3, 2016.
  60. United Nations. (2003). Final clauses of multilateral treaties: Handbook. United Nations.Google Scholar
  61. US Department of Commerce. (2007). Interview, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, National Marine Fisheries Service. Maryland: Silver Spring.Google Scholar
  62. US Department of State. (2003). U.S. Hosts Signing of Revised Inter-American Tropical Tuna Convention. http://www.state.gov/r/pa/prs/ps/2003/26337.htm. Accessed 4 Dec 2007.
  63. US Department of State. (2007a). Interview, US Department of State, Bureau of Oceans and International Environmental and Scientific Affairs. Washington, DC: US Department of State.Google Scholar
  64. US Department of State. (2007b). Interview, US Department of State, Bureau of Oceans and International Environmental and Scientific Affairs, Office of Ecology and Terrestrial Conservation. Washington, DC: US Department of State.Google Scholar
  65. Vogel, D. (2003). The hare and the tortoise revisited: The new politics of consumer and environmental regulation in Europe. British Journal of Political Science, 33(4), 557–580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Webster, D. G. (2009). Adaptive governance: The dynamics of Atlantic fisheries management. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  67. Young, O. R. (1989). The politics of international regime formation: Managing natural resources and the environment. International Organization, 43, 349–375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.James Madison College and Department of Fisheries and WildlifeMichigan State UniversityEast LansingUSA

Personalised recommendations