Skip to main content
Log in

Not quite the best response: truth-telling, strategy-proof matching, and the manipulation of others

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Following the advice of economists, school choice programs around the world have lately been adopting strategy-proof mechanisms. However, experimental evidence presents a high variation of truth-telling rates for strategy-proof mechanisms. We crash test the connection between the strategy-proofness of the mechanism and truth-telling. We employ a within-subjects design by making subjects take two simultaneous decisions: one with no strategic uncertainty and one with some uncertainty and partial information about the strategies of other players. We find that providing information about the out-of-equilibrium strategies played by others has a negative and significant effect on truth-telling rates. That is, most participants in our within-subjects design try and fail to best-respond to changes in the environment. We also find that more sophisticated subjects are more likely to play the dominant strategy (truth-telling) across all the treatments. These results have potentially important implications for the design of markets based on strategy-proof matching mechanisms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other noticeable experimental papers in the literature are Kagel and Roth (2000), Haruvy and Unver (2007), Echenique et al. (2016), Niederle and Yariv (2009), Featherstone and Mayefsky (2011), Chen and Kesten (2016), Hugh-Jones et al. (2014), Klijn et al. (2013), Hakimov and Kesten (2014), Niederle et al (2013), Featherstone and Niederle (2013), Braun et al. (2014).

  2. In a recent paper, Ding and Schotter (2014a, b) show that in a repeated environment chatting and intergenerational advice decrease the truth-telling of subjects. This evidence only supports our hypothesis of conditioning the strategies on the behavior of other players.

  3. Subjects are asked to fulfill rankings for both baseline and treatment in the same decision screen. Both rankings are submitted together.

  4. More precisely, subjects had three options: 55% chance of baseline to be payoff relevant and 45% chance of treatment, 50% chance for baseline and treatment and 45% chance for baseline and 55% chance for treatment. The vast majority of subjects chose 50–50.

  5. Note that the true top choice is a best response in the Baseline. Reporting the true top choice in any other position of the list is irrelevant for a payoff in the CBMT, and thus all submissions with this kind of manipulation are compatible with best response reporting. In all other treatments best response requires the full list to be reported truthfully.

  6. In Table 4 we report pairwise treatment comparisons. Note that the Baseline versus Treatment comparison are the within-subjects. Treatment versus Treatment comparisons are between-subjects.

  7. The highest truth-telling rates are found in experiments in which no information is provided about either the stated or underlying preferences.

  8. In the experiment, subjects were also asked the following question: The allocation procedure is constructed in such a way to guarantee students an assignment at least as good as their district school, according to the ranking list: True or False. However, we do not include the answers in our analysis, as a lot of subjects did not understand the formulation. In the post-experiment questionnaires subjects complained (those who answered incorrectly), that in fact you can get a worse school than your district school if you listed the worse school higher in the ranking lists. Thus, we concluded that the question was not clearly formulated and excluded it from our analysis.

  9. Thorough in relative terms: in the typical economic experiment subjects get just 15 min to read experimental instructions before they are asked to participate in incentive-based tasks. The training of participants in real-life market design tasks based on TTC is far less intense.

References

  • Abdulkadiroğlu, A., Pathak, P. A., Roth, A. E., & Sönmez, T. (2005). The Boston public school match. American Economic Review, 95, 368–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abdulkadiroğlu, A., & Sönmez, T. (2003). School choice: A mechanism design approach. American Economic Review, 93(3), 729–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braun, S., Dwenger, N., Kübler, D., & Westkamp, A. (2014). Implementing quotas in university admissions: An experimental analysis. Games and Economic Behavior, 85, 232–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Kesten, O. (2016). College and high school admissions reforms in China: An experimental analysis. Working paper.

  • Chen, Y., & Sönmez, T. (2002). Improving efficiency of on-campus housing: An experimental study. The American Economic Review, 92(5), 1669–1686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Sönmez, T. (2006). School choice: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Theory, 127(1), 202–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crosetto, P., & Filippin, A. (2013). The bomb risk elicitation task. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47(1), 31–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ding, T, & Schotter, S. (2014a). Matching and chatting: An experimental study of the impact of network. Working Paper.

  • Ding, T, & Schotter, S. (2014b). Intergenerational advice and matching: An experimental study. Working Paper.

  • Echenique, F., Wilson, A., & Yariv, L. (2016). Clearinghouses for two-sided matching: An experimental study. Quantitative Economics, 7(2), 449–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Featherstone, C & Mayefsky, E. (2011). Why Do Some Clearinghouses Yield Stable Outcomes? Experimental Evidence on Out-of-Equilibrium Truth-Telling. Working paper.

  • Featherstone, C., & Niederle, M. (2013). Improving on strategy-proof school choice mechanisms: An experimental investigation. Working Paper.

  • Fisher, C. (2009). Manipulation and the match. JAMA: TheJournal of the American Medical Association, 302(12), 1266–1267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D., & Shapley, L. S. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage. The American Mathematical Monthly, 69(1), 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guillen, P. & Hakimov R. (2015). The Effectiveness of top-down advice in strategy-proof mechanisms: A field experiment. Working paper.

  • Guillen, P., & Hing, A. (2014). Lying through their teeth: Third party advice and truth telling in a strategy proof mechanism. European Economic Review, 70(October), 178–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakimov, R. & Kesten, O. (2014). Equitable top trading cycles mechanism for school choice: Theory and experiment. Working paper.

  • Haruvy, E., & Unver, U. (2007). Equilibrium Selection and the Role of Information in Repeated Matching Markets. Economic Letters, 94, 284–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassidim, A., Marciano-Romm, D., Schorrer, R. & Romm, A. (2015). Strategic players in a strategy-proof environment. Working paper.

  • Hugh-Jones, D, Kurino, M, & Vanberg, C. (2014). An experimental study on the incentives of the probabilistic serial mechanism. Games and Economic Behavior, 87, 367–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J., & Roth, A. (2000). The dynamics of reorganization in matching markets: A laboratory experiment motivated by a natural experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1), 201–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klijn, F., Pais, J., & Vorsatz, M. (2013). Preference intensities and risk aversion in school choice: A laboratory experiment. Experimental Economics, 16(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagarkar, P., & Janis, P. (2012). Fixing the ‘match’: How to play the game. Journal of Graduate Medical Education, 4(2), 142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niederle, M., Roth, A., & Unver, U. (2013). Unraveling results from comparable demand and supply. Games, 4(2), 243–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niederle, M. & Yariv, L. (2009). Decentralized matching with aligned preferences. Working paper.

  • Pais, J., & Pintér, A. (2008). School choice and information: An experimental study on matching mechanisms. Games and Economic Behavior, 64(1), 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pais, J., Pintér, Á., & Veszteg, R. (2011). College admissions and the role of information: An experimental study. International Economic Review, 52(3), 713–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees-Jones, A. (2015). Suboptimal behavior in strategy-proof mechanisms: Evidence from the residency match. Working paper.

  • Roth, A. E. (1984). The evolution of the labor market for medical interns and residents: A case study in game theory. The Journal of Political Economy, 92, 991–1016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., & Peranson, E. (1999). The redesign of the matching market for American physicians: Some engineering aspects of economic design. No. w6963. National bureau of economic research.

  • Vanacore, A. (2012). Centralized enrollment in Recovery School District gets first tryout. http://www.nola.com/education/index.ssf/2012/04/centralized_enrollment_in_reco.html.

  • Wonderlic, E., & Hovland, C. (1939). The personnel test: A restandardized abridgment of the Otis S-A test for business and industrial use. Journal of Applied Psychology, 23(6), 685–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zizzo, D. J. (2010). Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 13, 75–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Dorothea Kübler, Frank Heinemann, Bettina Klaus and Glenn Harrison for their kind comments and support; to Nina Bonge for helping us programming the experiments and conducting the sessions; and to Jennifer Rontganger for the copy editing.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rustamdjan Hakimov.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 483 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guillen, P., Hakimov, R. Not quite the best response: truth-telling, strategy-proof matching, and the manipulation of others. Exp Econ 20, 670–686 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9505-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9505-0

Keywords

Navigation