Advertisement

Environmental Modeling & Assessment

, Volume 11, Issue 2, pp 115–130 | Cite as

Overcompliance, labeling, and lobbying: The case of credence goods

  • Stefanie Engel
Article

This paper presents a model of quality choice in the case of credence goods, i.e., when consumers cannot observe quality even after purchase. It shows that firms may voluntarily overcomply, i.e., produce high quality, even when doing so implies giving up short-run profits. This generalizes results on reputation effects derived in the IO literature for the case of experience goods. The crucial assumptions of the model are that there is a positive degree of monitoring of firms’ claims and a positive probability that the firm is of an “honest type,” i.e., always prefers to produce high quality. The result also helps explain why we see phenomena such as firms voluntarily overcomplying with environmental standards, food safety laws, etc. It is shown that overcompliance is more likely when consumers learn about all (positive and negative) monitoring results than when consumers only find out about firms that have been found cheating, as is often the case in practice. I further show that even firms that pretend to be producing high quality while really producing low quality may have an incentive to lobby for stricter monitoring. This helps explain, for example, why firms in Europe and the United States lobby for the implementation of voluntary environmental audits, third-party labeling agencies or other disclosure strategies.

Keywords

labeling overcompliance credence goods quality goods 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. 1.
    J.F. Tomer, The human firm in the natural environment: a socio-economic analysis of its behavior, Ecol. Econ. 6 (1992) 119–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. 2.
    B. Smart, Beyond Compliance. A New Industry View of the Environment (World Resources Institute, Washington, DC, 1992).Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    Spiegel Special, Wege aus der Weltkrise. Oko-Bilanz ’95 (Spiegel-Verlag, Hamburg, Germany, February 1995).Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    Greenberg/Lake, New Priorities for Energy Policy, Polling Report (Washington, DC, February 8, 1993).Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    T. Tietenberg, Disclosure strategies for pollution control, Environ. Resour. Econ. 11(3–4) (1998) 587–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. 6.
    F. Allen, Reputation and product quality, RAND J. Econ. 15 (1984) 311–327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. 7.
    B. Klein and K. Leffler, The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance, J. Polit. Econ. 81 (1981) 615–641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. 8.
    C. Shapiro, Premiums for high quality products as rents to reputation, Q. J. Econ. 98 (1983) 659–680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. 9.
    J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1988) pp. 125–126.Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    D. Kreps and R. Wilson, Reputation and imperfect information, J. Econ. Theory 27 (1982) 253–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. 11.
    P. Milgrom and J. Roberts, Predation, reputation, and entry deterrence, J. Econ. Theory 27 (1982) 280–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. 12.
    A. Wolinsky, Competition in markets for credence goods, J. Inst. Theor. Econ. 151(1) (1995) 117–131.Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    W. Emons, Credence goods and fraudulant experts, RAND J. Econ. 28(1) (1997) 107–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 14.
    S. Arora and S. Gangopadhyay, Toward a Theoretical Model of Voluntary Overcompliance, Discussion Paper 94–11 (Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, 1994).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, Inc. 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Center for Development ResearchUniversity of BonnBonnGermany

Personalised recommendations