Advertisement

European Journal of Law and Economics

, Volume 39, Issue 1, pp 119–144 | Cite as

Organized crime, extortion and entrepreneurship under uncertainty

  • Pasquale L. Scandizzo
  • Marco VenturaEmail author
Article

Abstract

This article investigates the impact of organized crime (OC) on economic activity in conditions of dynamic uncertainty. It shows that the hypothesis of rationality does not imply a one to one correspondence between illegal behavior and expected benefits and costs of the criminal action, since two different regimes may ensue from the threat of racketeering. These two regimes will be respectively characterized by acquiescence and no private protection activities, and by optimal private protection that will push OC into a zone of inaction. The latter outcome will correspond to a Stackelberg equilibrium of a preventive type in the sense that the action of the firm as a leader will confine OC in a zone of temporary inaction. Since the extent to which private protection will succeed in deterring the criminal is lower the higher is uncertainty, and the higher are public protection activities, switching from one regime to the other may thus be determined even by small changes in uncertainty or public protection. If public protection is below a critical level, the threat of extortion also creates incentives for the firm to enter an agreement with the criminal, by negotiating an acceptable rate of extortion. At the same time, however, higher public protection will favor a better deal for the victim in such a negotiation.

Keywords

Crime Dynamic programming Protection cost Uncertainty Option value 

JEL Classification

K14 K42 D74 C61 

References

  1. Arquilla, J., & Ronfeldt, D. (2001). Networks and netwars: The future of terror, crime, and militancy. Santa Monica: Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
  2. At, C., & Chappe, N. (2008). Timing of crime. Learning and Sanction, Review of Law & Economics, 4(1), 36–44.Google Scholar
  3. Bandeira, O. (2003). Land reform, the market for protection, and the origins of the Sicilian mafia: Theory and evidence. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 19, 218–244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bartel, A. P.-. (1975). An analysis of firm demand for protection against crime. Journal of Legal Studies, 4, 443–478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 160–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Block, A. (1980). East side–west side. Organizing crime in New York 1930–1950. Cardiff: University College Cardiff Press.Google Scholar
  7. Buscaglia, E. (2008). The paradox of expected punishment: Legal and economic factors determining success and failure in the fight against organized crime. Review of Law & Economics, 4(1), Article 14.Google Scholar
  8. Campos N. F. (2000). Never around noon: On the nature and causes of the transition shadow. Center for Economic Reseach and Graduate Education Discussion paper: 1999–19.Google Scholar
  9. Chambliss, W. J. (1978). On the take: Prom petty crooks to presidents. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Chand S., K. Moene K. (1999). Rent grabbing and Russia’s economic collapse. Memo No 25/99, Department of Economics, University of Oslo.Google Scholar
  11. Clotfelter, C. T. (1977). Public services, private substitutes, and demand for protection against crime. American Economic Review, 67, 867–877.Google Scholar
  12. Clotfelter, C. T. (1978). Private security and the public safety. Journal of Urban Economics, 5, 388–402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Cressey, D. R. (1969). Theft of the nation—The structure and operations of organized crime in America. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
  14. DeAngelo, G., & Charness, G. (2012). Deterrence, expected cost, uncertainty and voting: Experimental evidence. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 73–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Dixit, A., & Pindyck, R. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Economist (The) (2003). The global menace of local strife. The Economist, May 22, 2003.Google Scholar
  17. Engelen, P. J. (2004). Criminal behavior: A real option approach with an application to restricting illegal insider trading. European Journal of Law and Economics, 17(3), 329–352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Frye, T., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2000). Rackets, regulation, and the rule of law. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 16, 478–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gambetta, D. (1993). The Sicilian Mafia: The business of private protection. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  20. Haller, M. H. (1990). Illegal enterprise: a theoretical and historical interpretation. Criminology, 28(2), 207–237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Harsanyi, J. (1967). Games with incomplete information played by Bayesian players. Management Science, 14(3), 159–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Harsanyi, J. (1968). Games with incomplete information played by Bayesian players part II. Management Science, 14(5), 320–334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Helsley, R. W., & Strange, W. C. (2005). Mixed markets and crime. Journal of Public Economics, 89(7), 1251–1275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hostetter, G. L., & Beesley, T. Q. (1929). It’s a Racket!. Chicago: Les Quin Books.Google Scholar
  25. Hylton, K. N. (1996). Optimal law enforcement and victim precaution. Rand Journal of Economics, 27, 197–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Karush W. (1939). Minima of Functions of several variables with inequalities as side constraints. M.Sc. Dissertation. Dept. of Mathematics, Univ. of Chicago, Chicago, IL.Google Scholar
  27. Konrad, K., & Skaperdas, S. (1998). Extortion. Economica, 65, 461–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Korzhyk D. Conitzer, V., Parr R. (2011). Solving Stackelberg games with uncertain observability. In Procedings of 10th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems (AAMAS 2011), Tumer, Yolum, Sonenberg and Stone (eds.), May, 2–6, 2011, Taipei, Taiwan.Google Scholar
  29. Kuhn H.W., Tucker, A. W. (1951). Nonlinear programming. In Proceedings of 2nd Berkeley symposium. Berkeley: University of California Press. pp. 481–492. http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.bsmsp/1200500249. MR47303.
  30. Lacroix, G., & Marceau, N. (1995). Private protection against crime. Journal of Urban Economics, 37(1), 72–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Lambrecht, B., & Perraudin, W. (2003). Real options and preemption under incomplete information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(4), 619–643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Maran, A. G. D. (2010). Mafia: Inside the dark heart: The rise and fall of the Sicilian Mafia. Google eBook: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  33. Mehlum, H., Moene, K., & Torvik, R. (2003). Destructive creativity. Nordic Journal of Political Economy, 29, 77–84.Google Scholar
  34. Nash, J. (1951). Non-cooperative games. Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Paddock, J. L., Siegel, D. R., & Smith, J. L. (1988). Option valuation of claims on real assets: The case of offshore petroleum leases. The Quarterly Journal of Econom-ics, 103, 479–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Pakes, A. S. (1986). Patents as options: Some estimates of the value of holding european patent stocks. Econometrica, 54(4), 755–784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Pakes, A. S., Simpson, M. (1989). Patent renewal data. Brooking papers on economic activity: Microeconomics, pp 331–410.Google Scholar
  38. Paoli, L. (2003). Mafia brotherhoods. Organized crime, Italian style. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  39. Peltzman, S. (1975). The effects of automobile safety regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 83, 677–725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Pita, J. (2011). Real-world security games: Toward addressing human decision-making uncertainty (extended abstract). In Proceedings of 10th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems (AAMAS 2011), Tumer, Yolum, Sonenberg & Stone (eds.), 2–6 May 2011, Taipei, Taiwan, pp. 1359–1360.Google Scholar
  41. Rakow, T., & Newell, B. R. (2010). Degrees of uncertainty: An overview and framework for future research on experience-based choice. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 23, 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Ruggiero, V. (1996). Organized and corporate crime in Europe. Offers that can’t be refused. Aldershot: Dartmouth.Google Scholar
  43. Scandizzo, P. L., & Ventura, M. (2010). Sharing risk through concession contracts. European Journal of Operational Research, 207(1), 363–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Schankerman, M. (1998). How valuable is patent protection? Estimates by Technology Field, Rand Journal of Economics, 29(1), 77–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Schelling, T. C. (1984). Choice and consequences. Harvard: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Schwartz, E. S. (2004). Patents and R&D as real options. Economic Notes, 33(1), 23–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Shavel, S. (1991). Individual precautions to prevent theft: Private versus socially optimal behaviour. International Journal of Law and Economics, 11(2), 123–132.Google Scholar
  48. Short, M. (1984). Crime inc.: The story of organized crime. London: Thames-Mandarin.Google Scholar
  49. Shubik, M. (1991). A game theoretic approach to political economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  50. van Soest, D. P., & Bulte, E. H. (2001). Does the energy-efficiency paradox exist? Technological progress and uncertainty. Environmental & Resource Economics, 18(1), 101–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Volkov, V. (2002). Violent entrepreneurs. The use of force in the making of Russian capitalism. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  52. Weeds, H. (2002). strategic delay in a real options model of R&D competition. Review of Economic Studies, 69(3), 729–747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Faculty of EconomicsUniversity of Rome “Tor Vergata”RomeItaly
  2. 2.ISTAT, Italian National Institute of StatisticsRomeItaly

Personalised recommendations