Advertisement

European Journal of Law and Economics

, Volume 35, Issue 3, pp 409–426 | Cite as

Property versus political holdouts: the case of the TGV rail line Lyon–Budapest in Italy

  • Livia C. NavoneEmail author
Article
  • 275 Downloads

Abstract

The law and economics literature commonly justifies the state’s taking power on the grounds that it is necessary to overcome holdouts and, thus, allow efficient development projects to move forward (A development project is efficient when the benefit it generates exceeds its cost.). By permitting the government to take private property rights non-consensually, the taking power limits the ability of private property owners to engage in strategic bargaining with the government and puts a cap on their ability to extract payments from the government in exchange for agreeing to transfer their rights. In this paper, I will argue that the standard story is highly incomplete and, therefore, inaccurate. It conveniently ignores the ability of politically powerful groups to block development projects by exercising their de facto veto power over proposed projects. Such groups do not necessarily have rights in any properties directly affected by the project. Once these groups, whom I call “political holdouts”, are added to the analysis, it becomes clear that the payment of just compensation—or any other aspect of eminent domain law and regulatory takings jurissprudence—will not help to remove their opposition and, a fortiori, cannot guarantee efficient development. I will explore the phenomenon of “political holdouts” and analyze its causes. As I will show, political holdouts are ubiquitous. Political holdouts may arise with respect to most of what passes for public policy projects, under either the aegis of eminent domain or the government’s police power, and also with respect to non-NIMBY projects. This observation may seem counterintuitive at first. However, one should consider that efficient development projects create a surplus over which powerful interest groups compete. As should be clear, what is of interest to localities and political groups is not the overall utility of a particular development project, but rather their payoff from it. Municipalities may oppose projects that benefit them simply to increase their share of the overall surplus generated by the project. Hence, the problem I point out is significant and acute. In the remainder of this paper, I will discuss in depth how the problem of political holdouts affected the construction of a fast train line (the Lyon–Torino–Milano–Trieste–Khoper–Ljubljana–Budapest TGV line) in northern Italy.

Keywords

Property rights economics Eminent domain Regulatory takings Holdouts NIMBY Lyon–Budapest TGV line 

JEL Classification

K10 K11 R40 R14 R52 Q50 H41 

References

  1. Bacow, L. S., & Milkey, J. R. (1982). Overcoming local opposition to hazardous waste facilities: The Massachusetts approach. Harvard Environmental Law Review, 6, 265.Google Scholar
  2. Banner, S. (2002). Transitions between property regimes. Journal of Legal Studies, 31, 359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Barros, D. B. (2004). The police power and the takings clause. University of Miami Law Review, 58, 471.Google Scholar
  4. Bell, A., & Parchomovsky, G. (2001). Takings reassessed. Virginia Law Review, 87, 277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bell, A., & Parchomovsky, G. (2006). The uselessness of public use. Columbia Law Review, 106, 1412.Google Scholar
  6. Blume, L., & Rubinfeld, D. (1984). Compensation for taking: An economic analysis. California Law Review, 72, 569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Blume, L., Rubinfeld, D., & Shapiro, P. (1984). The taking of land: When should compensation be paid? Quaterly Journal of Economics, 99, 71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bobbio, N. (1990). L’Età dei Diritti (2nd ed.).Google Scholar
  9. Bouckaert, B. (1990). What is property? Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 13, 775.Google Scholar
  10. Calabresi, G., & Melamed, D. A. (1972). Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral. Harvard Law Review, 85, 1089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cameron, R. M., & Carson, R. T. (1986). Property rights, protest and the siting of hazardous waste facilities. American Economic Review, 76, 285.Google Scholar
  12. Caplan, B. (2001a). Rational ignorance vs. rational irrationality. Kyklos, 54, 3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Caplan, B. (2001b). Rational irrationality and the microfoundations of political failure. Public Choice, 107, 311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Cooter, R. (1982). The cost of coase. Journal of Legal Studies, XI, 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cooter, R. & Ulen, T. (1997) Law and Economics, vol.149 (2nd ed.).Google Scholar
  16. Dagan, H. (1999). Takings and distributive justice. Virginia Law Review, 85, 741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Dagan, H., & Heller, M. A. (2001). The liberal commons. Yale Law Journal, 110, 549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Dahl, R. A. (2001). How democratic is the American constitution? (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  19. Depoorter, B. (2004). The several lives of mickey mouse: The expanding boundaries of intellectual property law. Virginia Journal of Law and Technology, 9(4).Google Scholar
  20. Depoorter, B. (2006). Horizontal political externalities: The supply and demand of disaster management. Duke Law Journal, 56, 101.Google Scholar
  21. Ellickson, R. C. (1996). Takings legislation: A comment. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 20, 75.Google Scholar
  22. Epstein, R. A. (1985). Takings: Private property and the power of eminent domain (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  23. Epstein, R. A. (1987). Takings: Descent and resurrection, The Supreme Court Review, 1.Google Scholar
  24. Farber, D. A. (1992). Economic analysis and just compensation. International Review of Law & Economics, 12, 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Fischel, W. A. (1995). Regulatory takings: Law, economics and politics (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  26. Fischel, W., & Shapiro, P. (1989). A constitutional choice model of compensation for taking. International Review of Law and Economics, 9, 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gerrard, M. B. (1994). The victims of NIMBY. Fordham Urban Law Journal, 25, 495.Google Scholar
  28. Heller, M. A., & Krier, J. E. (1999). Deterrence and distribution in the law of takings. Harvard Law Review, 112, 997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Hermalin, B. E. (1995). An economic analysis of takings. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11, 64.Google Scholar
  30. Inhaber, H. (1992). Of LULUs, NIMBYs, and NIMTOOs. Public Interest, 52, 63.Google Scholar
  31. Kaplow, L. (1986). An economic analysis of legal transitions. Harvard Law Review, 99, 509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lambert, T., & Boerner, C. (1997). Environmental inequity: Economic causes, economic solution. Yale Journal on Regulation, 14, 195.Google Scholar
  33. Lemley, M. A. (1999). The modern Lanham act and the death of common sense. Yale Law Journal, 108, 1687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Levmore, S. (1990). Just compensation and just politics. Connecticut Law Review, 22, 285.Google Scholar
  35. Levmore, S. (1991). Takings, torts, and special interests. Virginia Law Review, 77, 1333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Levmore, S. (2002). Two stories about the evolution of property rights. Journal of Legal Studies, 31, 421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Libecap, G. D. (1990). Contracting for property rights (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  38. Maduro, M. P. (2003). Contrapunctual law: Europe’s constitutional pluralism in action. In N. Walker (Ed.), Sovereignty in Transition (pp. 501–537). Oxford: Hart.Google Scholar
  39. Maduro, M. P. (2008). Interpreting European Law—Judicial adjudication in a context of constitutional pluralism, Working Paper IE Law, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1134503 .
  40. Matheny, A. R., & Williams, B. A. (1985). Knowledge versus NIMBY: Assessing florida’s strategy for siting hazardous waste disposal facilities. Policy Studies Journal, 14, 70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Michelman, F. (1967). Property, utility, and fairness: Comments on the ethical foundations of just compensation law. Harvard Law Review, 80, 1165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. O’Hare, M. et al. (1983). Facility siting and public opposition (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  43. O’Hare, M., & Sanderson, D. (1993). Facility siting and compensation: Lessons from the Massachusetts experience. Journal of Policy Analysis, 12, 364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Portney, K. E. (1991). Siting hazardous waste treatment facilities: The NIMBY syndrome (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  45. Rabe, B. G. (1994). Beyond nimby: Hazardous waste siting in Canada and in the United States (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  46. Richman, B., & Boerner, C. (2005). A transaction cost economizing approach to regulation: Understanding the NIMBY problem and improving regulatory responses, Duke Law School Legal Studies Paper No. 56.Google Scholar
  47. Rose, C. M. (1984). Mahon reconstructed: Why the takings issue is still a muddle. Southern California Law Review, 57, 56.Google Scholar
  48. Rose, C. M. (1990). Property, rights, regulatory regimes and the new takings jurisprudence—an evolutionary approach. Tennessee Law Review, 57, 577.Google Scholar
  49. Rubenfeld, J. (Ed.). (1993). Usings. Yale Law Journal, 102:1077.Google Scholar
  50. Sax, J. (1964). Takings and the police power. Yale Law Journal, 74, 36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Stein, E. (1981). Lawyers, judges and the making of a transnational constitution. American Journal of International Law, 75, 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Walker, N. (2002). The Idea of constitutional pluralism. Modern Law Review, 65, 317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Weiler, J. H. H. (2002). A constitution for Europe? Some hard choices. Journal of Common Market Studies, 40, 563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Zagrebelsky, G. (1992). Il Diritto Mite (1st ed.).Google Scholar
  55. Zywicki, T. J. (2002). Baptists? The political economy of environmental interest groups. Case Western Reserve Law Review, 53, 315.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Università degli Studi del Piemonte OrientaleNovaraItaly

Personalised recommendations