Religion, law and development: Islam and Christianity—Why is it in Occident and not in the Orient that man invented the institutions of freedom?
- 620 Downloads
- 9 Citations
Abstract
This article answers the following question: why were institutions of freedom not invented in the Orient but in occident? It upholds that Christianity predisposed the West to discover institutions of freedom when Islam didn’t. In the first section it explains the decline and economic rise of the Orient and Occident as derived from Kant’s hypothesis (2.1) and geographical conditions (2.2). It explains in the second section the invention of institutions of freedom in Europe by two moral innovations: the secularising of law and the invention of the individual (3). The secularising of law was the result of Christian property theology which recognised man’s place in God’s creation (3.1). Secularising of politics and the Christians’ desire for autonomy vis-à-vis political authorities originated in individual rights being conceived as normal and incited man to insist upon respect from public authorities. The advent of individual rights was at the origin of the implementation of a secular constitutional right applying to all men, even the sovereign (3.2). The third section explains why political and social Islam did not predispose Muslims to discover the institutions of freedom, capitalism. Islamic law distanced the Orient from capitalism as it developed a religion of community salvation hostile to individualism and its rights (4.1); it never disassociated the rule of God from the rule of law (4.2) and it did not consider individual rights sacred or private property (4.3). The article concludes with the way in which economic theory could conceive of the religion variable in economic growth and development (5).
Keywords
Religion Liberty Development and property rightsJEL classification
O57 K11 D72References
- Acemoglu, D. (2003). Causes profondes de la pauvreté. Une perspective historique pour évaluer le rôle des institutions dans le développement économique. Finances and Développement, juin.Google Scholar
- Adelman, I., & Morris, C. T. (1967). Society, politics, and economic development. Baltimore: John Hopkin University Press.Google Scholar
- Adelman, I., & Morris, C. T. (1973). Economic growth and social equity in developing countries. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
- ALdeeb, A., & Sami, Abu.-Sahlieh. (2006). Introduction à la société musulmane. Paris: Eyrolles Référence.Google Scholar
- Aoun, S. (2007). L’islam entre tradition et modernité, entretiens avec Jean-Frédéric Légaré-Tremblay, Québec, éditions VARIA.Google Scholar
- Austruy, J. (1960). Structure économique et civilisation, l’Egypte et le destin économique de l’islam. Paris: CEDES.Google Scholar
- Badie, B. (1986). Culture et politique. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
- Baechler, J. (1995). Le capitalisme, vol.1, Les Origines. Paris: Gallimard.Google Scholar
- Barro, R., & McCleary, R. (2003). Religion and economic growth across countries. American Sociological Review, 68(5), 760–781. doi: 10.2307/1519761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Berman, H. J. (1983). Law and revolution. The formation of the Western legal tradition. Harvard University Press. French translation (2002), Droit et révolution, Editions de la Librairie de l’Université d’Aix-en-Provence.Google Scholar
- Berman, H. J. (1998). The Western legal tradition: The interaction of revolutionary innovation and evolutionary growth. In M. E. Streit, R. Vaubel, & P. Bernolz (Eds.), Political competition innovation and growth (pp. 35–47). Berlin-New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- Bernholz, P., Streit, M. E., & Vaubel, R. (1998). Political competition, innovation and growth. Berlin-New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- Besley, T. (1995). Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana. The Journal of Political Economy, 103(5), 903–937. doi: 10.1086/262008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blum, U., & Dudley, L. (2001). Religion and economic growth: Was Weber right? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(2), 207–230. doi: 10.1007/PL00003862.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Borooah, V. K., & Paldam, M. (2007). Why is the world short of democracy? A cross-country analysis of barriers to representative government. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(3), 582–604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Boudon, R. (2000). Protestantisme et capitalisme. Bilan d’un controverse. Commentaires, 807–818.Google Scholar
- Brasseul, J. (2004). Le déclin du monde musulman à partir du moyen âge: une revue des explications. Revue région et développement, 19, 19–53.Google Scholar
- Braudel, F. (1979). Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme, XV–XVIII siècle, Armand Colin.Google Scholar
- Cavalcandi, T. V., Parente, S. L., & Zhao, R. (2007). Religion macroeconomics: A quantitative analysis of Weber’s thesis. Economic Theory, 32, 105–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Collins, R. (1986). Weberian sociological theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Colombatto, E. (2001). On the concept of transition. The Journal of Markets and Morality, 4(2), 269–288.Google Scholar
- Coulson, N. J. (1964). A history of Islamic law. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press. Translation in French (1995), Histoire du droit islamique, Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
- Dawson, J. W. (1998). Institutions, investment and growth: New cross-country and panel data evidence. Economic Inquiry, XXXVI, 603–619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- De Soto, H. (2005). Le Mystère du Capital. Pourquoi le capitalisme triomphe en Occident et échoue partout ailleurs? Flammarion (published in English in 2002).Google Scholar
- De Vanssay, X., Hildebrand, V., & Spindler, Z. A. (2005). Constitutional foundations of economic freedom: A time-series cross-section analysis. Constitutional Political Economy, 16, 327–346. doi: 10.1007/s10602-005-4314-z.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Demsetz, H. (1967). Towards a theory of property rights. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.Google Scholar
- Diamond, J. (1997). Guns, germs, and steel. The fates of human societies. New York: W.W. Norton. French translation, (2000). De l’inégalité parmi les sociétés. Essai sur l’homme et l’environnement dans l’histoire, nrf Gallimard, traduit de l’anglais par Pierre Emmanuel.Google Scholar
- Dauzat, & Dumézil, B. (2005). Les racines chrétiennes de l’Europe. Conversion et liberté dans les royaumes barbares V et VIII siècle. Paris: Fayard.Google Scholar
- Dumont, J. (1984). L’église au risque de l’histoire. Limoges: Criterion.Google Scholar
- Facchini, F. (2002). Complex individualism and legitimacy of absolute property right. European Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 35–47. doi: 10.1023/A:1013161808255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gendarme, R. (1959). “La résistance des facteurs socio-culturels au développement économique. L’exemple de l’Islam en Algérie. Revue économique, 10(2), 220–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Glahe, D., & Verhies, F. (1989). Religion, liberty and economic development: An empirical investigation. Public Choice, 62, 202–215. doi: 10.1007/BF02337742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Guiso, L. P., Sapienza, & Zinagles, L. (2003). People’s Opium? Religion and economic attitudes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 225–282. doi: 10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00202-7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Working Paper NBER, 11999, http://www.nber.org/papers/w1199.
- Habachy, S. (1962). Property, right, and contract in Muslim law. Columbia Law Review, 62(3), 450–473. doi: 10.2307/1120053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order. An inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. A. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty (Vol.1). Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
- Hayek, F. (1976). Law, legislation and liberty (Vol. 2). Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. French version 1981, coll. Libre échange. Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
- Hillman, A. L. (2007). Economic and security consequences of supreme values. Public Choice, 131, 259–280. doi: 10.1007/s11127-007-9167-8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Jomo, K. S. (1977). Islam and Weber: Rodinson on the implication of religion for capitalist development. The Developing Economies, 15(2), 240. doi: 10.1111/j.1746-1049.1977.tb00380.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Jones, E. L. (1987). The European miracle environments, economies, and geopolitics in the history of Europe and Asia (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Kant, E. (1784, 1963), History from a cosmopolitan point of view. In Perpetual peace and other essays. Trans. Ted Humphrey. Indianapolis: Hackett, 1983, pp. 29–49.Google Scholar
- Kennedy, P. (1988). The rise and fall of the great powers. Uwin Hyman Ltd London, 1989, 1991. French translation éditions Payot, Naissance et déclin des grandes puissances.Google Scholar
- Khadduri, M. (1946). Human rights in Islam. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 243, 77–81. doi: 10.1177/000271624624300115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kirzner, I. (1992). The meaning of market process: Essay in the development of modern Austrian economics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
- Kuran, T. (1997). Islam and underdevelopment: An old puzzle revisited. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 153(1), French translation in Journal des économistes et des etudes humaines vol. 8, numéro 1, mars 1998, pp. 27–60, L’Islam et le sousdéveloppement: un vieux puzzle revisité.Google Scholar
- Kuran, T. (2004). Why the Middle East is economically underdeveloped: Historical mechanism of institutional stagnation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 71–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lewis, W. A. (1955). The theory of economic growth. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
- Lewis, B. (2005). L’Islam, Gallimard, “Islam et démocratie”, first publication in French, Notes de la Fondation Saint-Simon, June 1993.Google Scholar
- Lewis, B. (2005). Ibid, “Le Langage politique de l’Islam”, initially published in English as The Political Language of Islam, The University of Chicago Press 1988, Gallimard for the French translation in 1988.Google Scholar
- Linant de Bellefonds, Y. (1959). Un problème de sociologie juridique: les terres communes, en pays d’Islam. Studia Islamica, 10, 111–136.Google Scholar
- Maila, J. (1991). Les droits de l’Homme sont-ils impensables dans le monde arabe?. Les Cahiers de l’Orient, 176–197.Google Scholar
- Marshall, P. A. (2008). Religious Freedom in the World. Rowman and Littlefield Publishers, INC.Google Scholar
- Mises, L. (1949). Human action: A treatise on economics. Chicago: Henry Regnery.Google Scholar
- Montgomery Watt, M. (1968). Islamic political thought. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University. Translation in French (1995), la pensée politique de l’islam. Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
- Moucannas-Mazen, R. (1996). Islam, droit et relations économiques internationales. Paris: L’Harmattan.Google Scholar
- Noland, M. (2007). Religions, islam et croissance économique. L’apport des analyses empiriques. Revue Française de Gestion, 171, 97–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Noland, M., & Pack, H. (2007). The Arab economies in a changing world. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
- North, D. C. (1994). The historical evolution of polities. International Review of Law and Economics, 14, 381–391. doi: 10.1016/0144-8188(94)90022-1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- North, D. C. (1998). The rise of the Western world. In P. Bernholz, M. E. Streit, & R. Vaubel (Eds.), Political competition, innovation and growth. Berlin-New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- North, D. C., & Denzau, A. (1994). Shared mental models: Ideologies and institutions. Kyklos, 47, 3–31.Google Scholar
- North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of Western world: A new economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Trad. fr. par J.M.Denis, L’essor du monde occidental: une nouvelle histoire économique, Flammarion, Paris, 1980.Google Scholar
- Norton, S. W. (2000). The cost of diversity: Endogenous property rights and growth. Constitutional Political Economy, 11, 319–337. doi: 10.1023/A:1026567305485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Novak, M. (1982). The spirit of democratic capitalism. Translation in French (1987), Une éthique économique. Les valeurs de l’économie de marché, cerf, Institut La Boétie, Paris.Google Scholar
- Paldam, M. (2007, 2008). An essay on the Muslim gap. Religiosity and the political system. In M. Ferrero & R. Wintrobe (eds.) The political economy of theocracy, in press.Google Scholar
- Pejovich, S. (1994). The market for institutions vs. capitalism by Fiat. Kyklos, 47(4), 519–529. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6435.1994.tb02064.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Pryor, F. (2007). The economic impact of Islam on developing countries. World Development, 35(11), 1815–1835. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2006.12.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ragab, I. A. (1980). Islam and development. World Development, 8(7–8), 513–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Renan, E. (1887, 1883). Discours et conférences, éd. C. Lévy, 1887, L’Islamisme et la Science (conférence prononcée à la Sorbonne, en 1883).Google Scholar
- Renoux-Zagamé, N.-F. (1987). Origines Théologiques du Concept Moderne de Propriété, Droz.Google Scholar
- Rodinson, M. (1966/1973). Islam and capitalism, trans. Brian Pearce, Pantheon Books, New York. Rodinson, M. (1966). Islam et capitalisme, éditions du Seuil. Paris.Google Scholar
- Rosenberg, N., & Birdzell, L. E. (1986). How the West grew rich: The economic transformation of the industrial world. New York: Basic books.Google Scholar
- Sala-I-Martin, X., Doppelhofer, G., & Miller, R. I. (2004). Determinants of long-term growth: A Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. American Economic Review, 94(4), 813–835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Schacht, J. (1964). An introduction to Islamic law. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Translation in French (1999), Introduction du droit musulman. Paris, Maisonneuve et Larose.Google Scholar
- Scully, G. W. (1987). The choice of law and extent of liberty. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 143(4), 595–615.Google Scholar
- Stark, R. (2005, 2007). Le triomphe de la raison. Pourquoi la réussite du modèle occidental est le fruit du christianisme, Presses de la renaissance, French translation, (2005). New York: The Random House Publishing Group.Google Scholar
- Stulz, R. M., & Williamson, R. (2003). Culture, openness and finance. Journal of Financial Economics, 70(3), 313–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Sutcliffe, C. R. (1975). Is Islam an obstacle to development? Ideal patterns of belief versus actual patterns of behaviour. Journal of Developing Areas, 10, 77–82.Google Scholar
- Tierney, B. (1982). Religion, Law and the Growth of Constitutional Thought (1150-1650), The Wiles Lectures, The Queen’s University of Belfast, Cambridge University Press. Translation in French (1993), Religion et droit dans le développement de la pensée constitutionnelle, coll. Léviathan, Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
- Tocqueville, A. (1840, 1986). De la Démocratie en Amérique. Paris: Robert Laffont, Bouquin.Google Scholar
- Vaubel, R. (1998). Comment on Dennis Mueller. In P. Bernholz, M. E. Streit, & R. Vaubel (Eds.), Political competition, innovation and growth. Berlin-New York: Springer.Google Scholar
- Voigt, S. (2005). Islam and the institutions of a free society. The Indenpendant Review, X(1), 59–82.Google Scholar
- Weber, M. (1930). The protestant ethics and the spirit of capitalism. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
- Weber, M. (1996). Sociologie des religions. Textes réunis, traduits et présentés par Jean-Pierre Grossein, nrf, Gallimard, Paris.Google Scholar