Advertisement

De Economist

, Volume 155, Issue 4, pp 449–468 | Cite as

Social Returns to Education: Macro-Evidence

  • Erik Canton
Article

Summary

This paper presents new evidence on the social returns to education within a macroeconomic growth regression framework. I use improved schooling data and a macro version of the Mincer relationship between education and wages for individual workers. The results suggest that an increase by one year of the average education level of the labor force would increase labor productivity by 7–10% in the short run and by 11–15% in the long run. Some evidence is found for the presence of dynamic human capital spillovers: the human capital stock increases prospective economic growth. The empirical results are used to quantify the macroeconomic impact of skill upgrading as agreed upon in the European Union’s Lisbon strategy for growth and jobs. Finally, the paper discusses discrepancies between private and social returns to education.

Keywords

economic growth panel data returns to education 

JEL Code(s):

C33 I20 O40 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Acemoglu D., Angrist J. (2001) ‘How Large are Human-Capital Externalities? Evidence from Compulsory-Schooling Laws’. In: Bernanke B.S., Rogoff K.(eds) NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, pp 9–58Google Scholar
  2. Barro R.J., Lee J.W. (1993) ‘International Comparisons of Educational Attainment’. Journal of Monetary Economics 32(3): 363–394CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Barro R.J., Lee J.W. (1996) ‘International Measures of Schooling Years and Schooling Quality’. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 86(2): 218–223Google Scholar
  4. Barro R.J., Lee J.W. (2001) ‘International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications’. Oxford Economic Papers 53(3): 541–563CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bassanini, A. and S. Scarpetta (2001), ‘Does Human Capital Matter for Growth in OECD countries? ’ Evidence from Pooled Mean-Group Estimates,’OECD EconomicsDepartment, working paper nr. 282, Paris.Google Scholar
  6. Becker G.S. (1964) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education. New York, NBERGoogle Scholar
  7. Benhabib J., Spiegel M.M. (1994) ‘The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data’. Journal of Monetary Economics 34(2): 143–173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Benhabib J., Spiegel M.M. (2005) ‘Human Capital and Technology Diffusion’. In: Aghion P., Durlauf S. (eds) Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam, ElsevierGoogle Scholar
  9. Card, D. (1999), ‘The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings,’ in: O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A, Amsterdam, Elsevier, pp. 1801–1863.Google Scholar
  10. Ciccone A., Peri G. (2006) ‘Identifying Human Capital Externalities: Theory with Applications’. Review of Economic Studies 73(2): 381–412CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cohen, D. and M. Soto (2001), ‘Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results,’ OECD Development Centre, technical paper nr. 179, Paris.Google Scholar
  12. De la Fuente, A. (2007), ‘Human Capital and Growth: Some Results for the OECD,’ Paper presented at the 35th Economics Conference of the Austrian National Bank.Google Scholar
  13. De la Fuente A., Doménech R. (2006) ‘Human Capital in Growth Regressions: How Much Difference does Data Quality Make?’ Journal of the European Economic Association 4(1): 1–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Gelauff, M.M. and A.M. Lejour (2006), ‘Five Lisbon Highlights: The Economic Impact of Reaching these Targets,’ CPB Document nr. 104, The Hague.Google Scholar
  15. Giles J., Park A., Zhang J. (2003) ‘Use of Education Disruptions to Identify Heterogeneous Returns to Schooling in Urban China: The Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution as an Instrument’. Mimeo, University of MichiganGoogle Scholar
  16. Hall R.E., Jones C.I. (1999) ‘Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hanushek E.A., Kimko D. (2000) ‘Schooling, Labor-Force Quality, and the Growth of Nations’. American Economic Review 90(5): 1184–1208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hanushek, E.A. and L. Wößmann (2007), ‘The Role of School Improvement in Economic Development,’ NBER working paper nr. 12832.Google Scholar
  19. Harmon C., Oosterbeek H., Walker I. (2003) ‘The Returns to Education: Microeconomics’. Journal of Economic Surveys 17(2): 115–156CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Islam N. (1995) ‘Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(4): 1127–1170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Jacobs, B. (2005), ‘Simulating the Lisbon Skills Targets in WorldScan,’ CPB Memorandum nr. 135, The Hague.Google Scholar
  22. Jamison, E.A., D.T. Jamison and E.A. Hanushek (2006), ‘The Effects of Education Quality on Income Growth and Mortality Decline,’ NBER working paper nr. 12652.Google Scholar
  23. Krueger, A.B. and M. Lindahl (2001), ‘Education for Growth: Why and for Whom?,’ Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), pp. 1101–1136.Google Scholar
  24. Lindahl M., Canton E. (2007) ‘The Social Returns to Education’. In: Hartog J., Maassen van den Brink H. (eds) Human Capital: Advances in Theory and Evidence. Cambridge (UK), Cambridge University Press, pp 21–37Google Scholar
  25. Lucas R.E. (1988) ‘On the Mechanics of Economic Development’. Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1): 3–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Mankiw N.G., Romer D., Weil D.N. (1992) ‘A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2): 407–437CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Mincer J. (1974) Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York, NBER PressGoogle Scholar
  28. Nelson R., Phelps E. (1966) ‘Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion, and Economic Growth’. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 56(1/2): 69–75Google Scholar
  29. Portela, M., R. Alessie and C. Teulings (2004), ‘Measurement Error in Education and Growth Regressions,’ CEPR discussion paper nr. 4637, London.Google Scholar
  30. Psacharopoulos G. (1994) ‘Returns to Investment in Education: A Global Update’. World Development 22(9): 1325–1343CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Psacharopoulos G., Patrinos H.A. (2004) ‘Returns to Investment in Education: A Further Update’. Education Economics 12(2): 111–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Rauch J., (1993) ‘Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from Cities’. Journal of Urban Economics 34(3): 380–400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Schultz T.W. (1961) ‘Investment in Human Capital’. American Economic Review 51(1): 1–17Google Scholar
  34. Soto, M. (2002), ‘Rediscovering Education,’ OECD Development Centre, working paper nr. 202, Paris.Google Scholar
  35. Temple J.R.W. (1999) ‘A Positive Effect of Human Capital on Growth’. Economics Letters 65(1): 131–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Vandenbussche J., Aghion P., Meghir C. (2006) ‘Growth, Distance to Frontier and Composition of Human Capital’. Journal of Economic Growth 11(2):97–127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Webbink D. (2005) ‘Causal Effects in Education’. Journal of Economic Surveys 19(4): 535–560CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Wößmann, L. (2000), ‘Specifying Human Capital: A Review, Some Extensions, and Development Effects,’ Kiel Institute of World Economics, working paper nr. 1007.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.European Commission, Enterprise and Industry Directorate-General,Unit B2 Competitiveness and Economic ReformsBruxellesBelgium
  2. 2.CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy AnalysisThe HagueThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations