Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Preference Heterogeneity in the Structural Estimation of Efficient Pigovian Incentives for Insecticide Spraying to Reduce Malaria

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper bridges the theoretical and empirical literatures on the role of preference heterogeneity in characterizing externalities related to disease transmission. We use a theoretical structure similar to locational sorting models, which characterize equilibria in terms of marginal individuals who are indifferent between locations. In our case, the ‘locations’ are binary, consisting of whether or not to take a discrete preventative action. Individual heterogeneity arises in this structure due to variation in the costs and disutility associated with prevention. We demonstrate application of this approach in the context of participation in insecticide-based indoor residual spraying programs for malaria control in northern Uganda. We identify the parameters of our theoretical model using a stated preference choice experiment combined with estimates from published epidemiological studies. The model implies that Pigovian subsidies for participation in this context should decrease household malaria risk by 19–25%. Our approach can be applied to other bioeconomic externalities with spillovers from discrete preventative actions, including agricultural pest management and the control of pest infestations and invasive species.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To see this, examine the second line of (2): \(\underline{\eta }=- \mathop {\overbrace{\theta }}\limits ^{\left( - \right) } \mathop {\overbrace{\left[ {\rho _1 -\rho _0 } \right] }}\limits ^{\left( - \right) } - \mathop {\overbrace{\alpha C}}\limits ^{\left( + \right) } <0\).

  2. To complete this calculation, first compute the partial derivative \(\frac{\partial Q}{\partial \underline{\eta }}=\frac{\partial \left[ {\int _ {\underline{\eta }}^\infty f\left( \eta \right) d\eta } \right] }{\partial \underline{\eta }}=-f\left( \underline{\eta }\right) \).

  3. Comparative statics of laissez faire and socially optimal equilibria \(Q^{*}\) and \(Q^{o}\) with respect to any model parameter then proceed using the Implicit Function Theorem applied to equation system (2) and (5) respectively, as shown in the supplementary material.

  4. While tangential to the focus of this paper, it should be noted that a rebel insurgency that began in the 1980s and persisted into the 2000s demolished much of the infrastructure in northern Uganda, and resulted in the displacement of a number of inhabitants in the north. These “internally displaced persons” (IDPs) were relocated into IDP camps. IRS was used extensively in these camps because the high population densities made it a relatively cost-effective control strategy. However, once the IDPs returned to their home-sites (a process that occupied a period between 2008 and 2009), IRS services continued intermittently, though their frequency was reduced due to increased cost of accessing the more remote locations.

  5. This information is based on an in-person interview with a field manager of the USAID-funded spray teams in 2009.

  6. The algorithm was implemented by the author by pre-defining the levels for the relevant attributes and maximizing the determinant of the Fischer information matrix assuming a multinomial probit model estimated on the set of 30 choice tasks, and subject to the constraint that in each choice task IRS alternatives were always associated with a lower level of malaria risk than in the money-only option. While the probit model was not an ideal choice for this procedure, this does not threaten the consistency of the econometric estimates (since respondents were randomly assigned to one of the ten versions of the questionnaire), only their efficiency.

  7. See Annex for additional econometric specifications with estimates. In general, respondent characteristics were not significant in any estimations (with the exception of the variables included above), and most importantly the estimated coefficients on the attributes were robust to the inclusion of respondent characteristics.

  8. Without any commitment mechanism to bind households to multiple spray rounds, our theoretical formulation seems most suitable for the research aim of identifying efficient per-round Pigovian incentives for disease exteranalities.

  9. A derivation of this formula is available on request from the authors.

  10. Oster hence argues that an effective behavioral intervention to increase vaccination would be to more widely publicize recent outbreaks. While intuitive, such an approach seems inherently inadequate for preventing outbreaks. The model presented above suggests that Pigovian subsidies combined with educational campaigns informing respondents about actual disease risks may provide a more effective preventative intervention.

References

  • Althouse BM, Bergstrom TC et al (2010) A public choice framework for controlling transmissible and evolving diseases. In: Proceedings of the National Academies of Science

  • Balcombe K, Chalak A et al (2009) Model selection for the mixed logit with Bayesian estimation. J Environ Econ Manag 57(2):226–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer M, Chytilová J (2010) The impact of education on subjective discount rate in ugandan villages. Econ Dev Cult Change 58(4):643–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayer P, Keohane N et al (2009) Migration and hedonic valuation: the case of air quality. J Environ Econ Manag 58(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayer P, Timmins C (2005) On the equilibrium properties of locational sorting models. J Urban Econ 57(3):462–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouwman H, van den Berg H et al (2011) DDT and malaria prevention: address the paradox (commentary). Environ Health Perspect 119:744–747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brito DL, Sheshinski E et al (1991) Externalities and compulsary vaccinations. J Public Econ 45(1):69–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock WA, Durlauf SN (2001) Discrete choice with social interactions. Rev Econ Stud 68(2):235–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown ZS, Dickinson KL et al (2013) Insecticide resistance and malaria vector control: the importance of fitness cost mechanisms in determining economically optimal control trajectories. J Econ Entomol 106(1):366–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callan T, Lyons S et al (2009) The distributional implications of a carbon tax in Ireland. Energy Policy 37(2):407–412. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2008.08.034

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson R (1962) Silent spring, Houghton Mifflin Harcourt

  • Chalak A, Balcombe K et al (2008) Pesticides, preference heterogeneity and environmental taxes. J Agric Econ 59(3):537–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chitnis N, Schapira A et al (2010) Comparing the effectiveness of malaria vector-control interventions through a mathematical model. Am J Trop Med Hyg 83(2):230–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook J, Jeuland M et al (2009) Using private demand studies to calculate socially optimal vaccine subsidies in developing countries. J Policy Anal Manag 28(1):6–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delavande A, Giné X et al (2011) Measuring subjective expectations in developing countries: a critical review and new evidence. J Dev Econ 94(2):151–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson J, Mattsson L-G (2006) Equity effects of congestion pricing: quantitative methodology and a case study for Stockholm. Trans Res A Policy Pract 40(7):602–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel EP, Castillo-Chavez C et al (2011) Adaptive human behavior in epidemiological models. Proc Nat Acad Sci 108(15):6306–6311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ, Miranda JJ (2013) Heterogeneous treatment effects and mechanisms in information-based environmental policies: evidence from a large-scale field experiment. Resour Energy Econ 35(3):356–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florax RJ, Travisi CM et al (2005) A meta-analysis of the willingness to pay for reductions in pesticide risk exposure. Eur Rev Agric Econ 32(4):441–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis PJ (1997) Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccinations. J Public Econ 63(3):383–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersovitz M, Hammer JS (2004) The economical control of infectious diseases. Econ J 114:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersovitz M, Hammer JS (2004) Tax/subsidy policies toward vector-borne infectious diseases. J Public Econ 89(4):647–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin JT, Hollingsworth TD et al (2010) Reducing Plasmodium falciparum malaria transmission in Africa: a model-based evaluation of intervention strategies. PLoS Med 7(8):e1000324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann M, Gaudet G (2009) The economic dynamics of antibiotic efficacy under open access. J Environ Econ Manag 57(3):334–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hole AR (2007) Estimating mixed logit models using maximum simulated likelihood. Stata J 7(3):388–401

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes TP, Bell KP et al (2008) Economic aspects of invasive forest pest management. The economics of forest disturbances. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchison W, Burkness E et al (2010) Areawide suppression of European corn borer with Bt maize reaps savings to non-Bt maize growers. Science 330(6001):222–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–292. doi:10.2307/1914185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramer RA, Dickinson KL et al (2009) Using decision analysis to improve malaria control policy making. Health Policy 92(2):133–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kron J (2011) As an insecticide makes a comeback. Uganda must weigh its costs. New York Times, Atek, Uganda

  • Kuminoff NV, Smith VK et al (2013) The new economics of equilibrium sorting and policy evaluation using housing markets. J Econ Lit 51(4):1007–1062

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomes G (1991) Evidence of a new violation of the independence axiom. J Risk Uncertain 4:91–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Louviere JJ, Hensher DA et al (2000) Stated choice methods: analysis and application. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Okello PE, van Bortel W et al (2006) Variation in malaria transmission intensity in seven sites throughout Uganda. Am J Trop Med Hyg 75(2):219–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Oster E (2016) Does disease cause vaccination? Disease outbreaks and vaccination response. NBER working paper no. 22464. http://www.nber.org/papers/w22464

  • Pedercini M, Blanco SM et al (2011) Application of the malaria management model to the analysis of costs and benefits of DDT versus non-DDT malaria control. PLoS ONE 6(11):e27771

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perrings C, Williamson M et al (2002) Biological invasion risks and the public good: an economic perspective. Conserv Ecol 6(1):1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • PMI (2009) Malaria operational plan. President’s Malaria Initiative Uganda, United States Agency for International Development

  • Revelt D, Train K (1998) Mixed logit with repeated choices: households’ choices of appliance efficiency level. Rev Econ Stat 80(4):647–657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling TC (1969) Models of segregation. Am Econ Rev 59(2):488–493

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling TC (1971) Dynamic models of segregation. J Math Sociol 1(2):143–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinhardt LC, Yeka A, Nasr S, Wiegand RE, Rubahika D, Sserwanga A, Wanzira H, Lavoy G, Kamya M, Dorsey G, Filler S (2013) The effect of indoor residual spraying on malaria and anemia in a high-transmission area of Northern Uganda. Am J Trop Med Hyg 88(5):855–861. doi:10.4269/ajtmh.12-0747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stockhom Convention (2009) Decision SC-4/2: DDT. http://chm.pops.int/Convention/COP/COPDecisions/tabid/208/Default.aspx

  • Temu EA, Coleman M et al (2012) High prevalence of malaria in Zambezia, Mozambique: the protective effect of IRS versus increased risks due to pig-keeping and house construction. PLoS ONE 7(2):e31409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmins C, Murdock J (2007) A revealed preference approach to the measurement of congestion in travel cost models. J Environ Econ Manag 53(2):230–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train KE (2003) Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Tren R, Roberts D (2010) DDT and malaria prevention (correspondence). Environ Health Perspect 118(1):A14–A15

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker K (2000) Cost-comparison of DDT and alternative insecticides for malaria control. Med Vet Entomol 14(4):345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein MC, Siegel JE et al (1996) Recommendations of the panel on cost-effectiveness in health and medicine. JAMA 276(15):1253–1258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WHO (2009) WHO recommended insecticides for indoor residual spraying against malaria vectors. http://www.who.int/whopes/Insecticides_IRS_Malaria_09.pdf

  • WHO (2011) Global insecticide use for vector-borne disease control: a 10-year assessment (2000–2009). World Health Organization Pesticide Evaluation Scheme (WHOPES)

  • Zhang J, Smith MD (2011) Heterogeneous response to marine reserve formation: a sorting model approach. Environ Resour Econ 49(3):311–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou G, Githeko AK et al (2010) Community-wide benefits of targeted indoor residual spray for malaria control in the Western Kenya Highland. Malar J 9:67

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zachary S. Brown.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 1095 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brown, Z.S., Kramer, R.A. Preference Heterogeneity in the Structural Estimation of Efficient Pigovian Incentives for Insecticide Spraying to Reduce Malaria. Environ Resource Econ 70, 169–190 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0115-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0115-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation