Advertisement

Environmental and Resource Economics

, Volume 39, Issue 3, pp 265–282 | Cite as

The optimal initial allocation of pollution permits: a relative performance approach

  • Ian A. Mackenzie
  • Nick Hanley
  • Tatiana Kornienko
Original Paper

Abstract

The initial allocation of pollution permits is an important aspect of emissions trading schemes. We generalize the analysis of Böhringer and Lange (2005, Eur Econ Rev 49(8): 2041–2055) to initial allocation mechanisms that are based on inter-firm relative performance comparisons (including grandfathering and auctions, as well as novel mechanisms). We show that using firms’ historical output for allocating permits is never optimal in a dynamic permit market setting, while using firms’ historical emissions is optimal only in closed trading systems and only for a narrow class of allocation mechanisms. Instead, it is possible to achieve social optimality by allocating permits based only on an external factor, which is independent of output and emissions. We then outline sufficient conditions for a socially optimal relative performance mechanism.

Keywords

Relative performance Initial allocation Pollution permits Auctions Rank-order contests 

JEL Classification

Q53 Q58 C72 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Bergland H, Clark DJ, Pedersen PA (2002). Rent seeking and the regulation of a natural resource. Mar Resour Econ 16(3): 219–233 Google Scholar
  2. Bode S (2005) Emissions trading schemes in Europe: linking the EU emissions trading scheme with national programs. In: Hansjürgen B (ed). Emissions trading for climate policy: US and European perspectives Cambridge University Press, pp 199–221Google Scholar
  3. Bode S (2006). Multi-period emissions trading in the electricity sector–winners and loser. Energy Policy 34(6): 680–691 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Böhringer C, Lange A (2005). On the design of optimal grandfathering schemes for emission allowances. Eur Econ Rev 49(8): 2041–2055 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Cramton P, Kerr S (2002). Tradeable carbon permit auctions: how and why to auction not grandfather. Energy Policy 30(4): 333–345 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Cronshaw MB, Kruse JB (1996). Regulated firms in pollution permit markets with banking. J Regul Econ 9(2): 179–189 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Ellerman AD, Wing IS (2003). Absolute versus intensity-based emissions caps. Climate Policy 3(S2): S7–S20 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Fischer C (2001) Rebating environmental policy revenues: output-based allocations and tradable performance standards. Resources for the future. Discussion Paper 01–22, Washington DC.Google Scholar
  9. Fischer C (2003). Combining rate-based and cap-and-trade emissions policies. Climate Policy 3(S2): S89–S103 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Franciosi R, Isaac M, Pingry D, Reynolds S (1993). An experimental investigation of the Hahn–Noll revenue neutral auction for emissions licenses. J Environ Econ Manage 24(1): 1–24 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Franckx L, D’Amato A, Brose I (2005) Multi-pollutant yardstick schemes as environmental policy tools.. 14th annual meeting of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (EAERE), Bremen, GermanyGoogle Scholar
  12. Freixas X, Guesnerie R, Tirole J (1985). Planning under incomplete information and the Ratchet effect. Rev Econ Stud 52(2): 173–191 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Goulder LH, Parry I, Burtaw D (1997). Revenue-raising versus other approaches to environmental protection: the critical significance of preexisting tax distortions. RAND J Econ 28(4): 708–731 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Govindasamy R, Herriges JA, Shogren JF (1994) Nonpoint tournaments. In: Tomasi T, Dosi C (eds) Nonpoint-source pollution regulation: issues and analysis. Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp 87–105Google Scholar
  15. Green JR, Stokey NL (1983). A comparison of tournaments and contracts. J Polit Econ 91(3): 349–364 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Groenenberg H, Blok K (2002). Benchmark-based emission allocation in a cap-and trade system. Climate Policy 2(1): 105–109 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hahn R, Noll R (1982) Designing a market for tradeable emissions permits. In Magat WA (ed) Reform of environmental regulation. Ballinger, Cambridge, Massachusetts, pp 119–146Google Scholar
  18. Hahn RW (1988). Promoting efficiency and equity through institutional design. Policy Sci 21(1): 41–66 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Holmström B (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell J Econ 13(2): 324–340 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Jensen J, Rasmussen TN (2000). Allocation of CO2 emissions permits: a general equilibrium analysis of policy instruments. J Environ Econ Manage 40(2): 111–136 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Kling C, Rubin J (1997). Bankable permits for the control of environmental pollution. J Public Econ 64(1): 101–115 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kolstad CD (2005) Climate change policy viewed from the USA and the role of intensity targets. In Hansjürgen B (ed) Emissions trading for climate policy: US and European perspectives. Cambridge University Press, pp 96–113Google Scholar
  23. Kuik O, Mulder M (2004). Emissions trading and competitiveness: pros and cons of relative and absolute schemes. Energy Policy 32(6): 737–745 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Lazear EP, Rosen S (1981). Rank order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. J Polit Econ 89(5): 841–864 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Leiby P, Rubin J (2001). Intertemporal permit trading for the control of greenhouse gas emissions. Environ Resour Econ 19(3): 229–256 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Lyon RM (1982). Auctions and alternative procedures for allocating pollution rights. Land Econ 58(1): 16–32 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Lyon RM (1986). Equilibrium properties of auctions and alternative procedures for allocation transferable permits. J Environ Econ Manage 13(2): 129–152 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Malueg DA, Yates AJ (2006). Citizen participation in pollution permit markets. J Environ Econ Manage 51(2): 205–217 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Mellers BA (1982). Equity judgment: a revision of Aristotelian views. J Exp Psychol General 111: 242–270 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Mellers BA (1986). “Fair” allocations of salaries and taxes. J Exp Psychol: Human Perception Performance 12: 80–91 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Milliman SR, Prince R (1989). Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control. J Environ Econ Manag 17(3): 247–265 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Moldovanu B, Sela A (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. Am Econ Rev 91(3): 542–558 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Moldovanu B, Sela A (2006). Contest architecture. J Econ Theory 126(1): 70–96 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Mookherjee D (1984). Optimal incentive schemes with many agents. Rev Econ Stud 51(3): 433–446 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Nalebuff BJ, Stiglitz JE (1983). Information, competition and markets. Am Econ Rev 73(2): 278–283 Google Scholar
  36. Nalebuff BJ, Stiglitz JE (1983). Prizes and incentives: towards a general theory of compensation and competition. Bell J Econ 14(1): 21–43 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Newell RG, Pizer W (2006) Indexed regulation. Discussion Paper 06–32, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.Google Scholar
  38. Oehmke J (1987). The allocation of pollutant discharge permits by competitive auction. Resour Energy 9(2): 153–162 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Parry IWH (1995). Pollution taxes and revenue recycling. J Environ Econ Manage 29(3): S-64–S-77 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Parry IWH (1997). Environmental taxes and quotas in the presence of distorting taxes in factor markets. Resour Energy Econ 19(3): 203–220 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Parry I, Williams RC, Goulder L (1999). When can carbon abatement policies increase welfare? The fundamental role of distorted factor markets. J Environ Econ Manage 37(1): 52–84 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Pizer W (2005) The case for intensity targets. Discussion Paper 05-02, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.Google Scholar
  43. Requate T, Unold W (2003). Environmental policy incentives to adopt advanced abatement technology: will the true ranking please stand up?. Eur Econ Rev 47(1): 125–146 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Rubin J (1996). A model of intertemporal emission trading, banking and borrowing. J Environ Econ Manage 31(3): 269–286 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Skaperdas S (1996). Contest Success Functions. Econ Theory 7(2): 283–290 Google Scholar
  46. Schennach SM (2000). The economics of pollution permit banking in the context of Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. J Environ Econ Manage 40(3): 189–210 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Schmalensee R, Joskow PR, Ellerman AD, Montero J-P, Bailey EM (1998). An interim evaluation of sulphur dioxide emissions trading. J Econ Perspect 12(3): 53–68 Google Scholar
  48. Shleifer A (1985). A theory of yardstick competition. RAND J Econ 16(3): 319–327 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Stavins RN (1998). What can we learn from the grand policy experiment? Lessons from SO2 allowance trading. J Econ Perspect 12(3): 69–88 Google Scholar
  50. Tietenberg T (1985). Emissions trading: an exercise in reforming pollution policy. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC Google Scholar
  51. Van Dyke B (1991). Emissions trading to reduce acid deposition. Yale Law J 100: 2707–2726 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Weitzman M (1980). The ‘Ratchet principle’ and performance incentives. Bell J Econ 11(1): 302–308 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Yates AJ, Cronshaw MB (2001). Pollution permit markets with intertemporal trading and asymmetric information. J Environ Econ Manage 42(1): 104–118 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  • Ian A. Mackenzie
    • 1
  • Nick Hanley
    • 1
  • Tatiana Kornienko
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of StirlingStirlingUK

Personalised recommendations