Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal Influence Strategies in Social Networks

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper suggests a modeling framework to investigate the optimal strategy followed by a monopolistic firm aiming to manipulate the process of opinion formation in a social network. The monopolist and a set of consumers communicate to form their beliefs about the underlying product quality. Since the firm’s associated optimization problem can be analytically solved only under specific assumptions, we rely on the sequential quadratic programming computational approach to characterize the equilibrium. When consumers’ initial beliefs are uniform, the firm’s optimal influence strategy always involves targeting the most influential consumer. For the case of non-uniform initial beliefs, the monopolist might target the less influential consumer if the latter’s initial opinion is low enough. The probability of investing more in the consumer with the lower influence increases with the distance between consumers’ initial beliefs and with the degree of trust attributed on consumers by the firm. The firm’s profit is minimized when consumers’ influences become equal, implying that the firm benefits from the presence of consumers with divergent strategic locations in the network. In the absence of a binding constraint on total investment, the monopolist’s incentives to manipulate the network decrease with consumers’ initial beliefs and might either increase or decrease with the trust put in consumers’ opinion by the firm. Finally, the firm’s strategic motivation to communicate persistently high beliefs during the opinion formation process is positively associated with the market size, with the available budget and with the direct influence of the most influential consumer on the other but negatively associated with consumers’ initial valuation of the good.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17
Fig. 18
Fig. 19
Fig. 20
Fig. 21
Fig. 22
Fig. 23
Fig. 24
Fig. 25
Fig. 26
Fig. 27
Fig. 28
Fig. 29
Fig. 30
Fig. 31
Fig. 32
Fig. 33
Fig. 34
Fig. 35
Fig. 36
Fig. 37
Fig. 38
Fig. 39
Fig. 40
Fig. 41
Fig. 42
Fig. 43
Fig. 44
Fig. 45
Fig. 46

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a similar spirit, Coleman (1988, 2000) has stressed the importance of closure as a structural property of social networks which facilitates the process of communication and enables a set of agents to reach a consensus about various issues. This consensus might imply the emergence of effective social norms or trust allowing the establishment of common expectations as forms of social capital within a population of agents.

  2. A further set of experiments shows that the critical interval \(\Delta \theta \) again increases with the difference between consumers’ initial beliefs and does not vary with the direct influence exerted by one consumer on the other (as claimed in Proposition 5).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Dahleh, M. A., Lobel, I., & Ozdaglar, A. (2011). Bayesian learning in social networks. The Review of Economic Studies, 78(4), 1201–1236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballester, C., Calvó-Armengol, A., & Zenou, Y. (2006). Who’s who in networks. Wanted: The key player. Econometrica, 74(5), 1403–1417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biggs, M. (1973). Constrained minimisation using recursive quadratic programming: Some alternative subproblem formulations. Hatfield Polytechnic. Numerical Optimisation Centre.

  • Borgatti, S. P. (2006). Identifying sets of key players in a social network. Computational & Mathematical Organization Theory, 12(1), 21–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (2000). Foundations of social theory (3rd ed.). Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN: 0674312260.

  • Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95–S120. ISSN: 00029602. doi:10.2307/2780243.

  • DeGroot, M. H. (1974). Reaching a consensus. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 69(345), 118–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dodds, P. S., & Watts, D. J. (2004). Universal behavior in a generalized model of contagion. Physical review letters, 92(21), 218701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fletcher, R. (2013). Practical methods of optimization. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galeotti, A., & Goyal, S. (2009). Influencing the influencers: A theory of strategic diffusion. The RAND Journal of Economics, 40(3), 509–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, P. E., Murray, W., & Wright, M. H. (1981). Practical optimization. Cambridge: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gladwell, M. (2006). The tipping point: How little things can make a big difference. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golub, B., & Jacksonm, M. O. (2010). Naive learning in social networks and the wisdom of crowds. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2, 112–149.

  • Golub, B., & Jackson, M. O. (2012). How homophily affects the speed of learning and best response dynamics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3), 1287–1338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, S.-P. (1977). A globally convergent method for nonlinear programming. Journal of optimization theory and applications, 22(3), 297–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinz, O., & Spann, M. (2008). The impact of information diffusion on bidding behavior in secret reserve price auctions. Information Systems Research, 19(3), 351–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinz, O., Skiera, B., Barrot, C., & Becker, J. U. (2011). Seeding strategies for viral marketing: An empirical comparison. Journal of Marketing, 75(6), 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinz, O., Schulze, C., & Takac, C. (2014). New product adoption in social networks: Why direction matters. Journal of Business Research, 67(1), 2836–2844.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, R., Van den Bulte, C., & Valente, T. W. (2011). Opinion leadership and social contagion in new product diffusion. Marketing Science, 30(2), 195–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O., et al. (2008). Social and economic networks (Vol. 3). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, E., & Lazarsfeld, P. F. (1955). Personal influence, the part played by people in the flow of mass communications. Piscataway: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • McPherson, M., Smith-Lovin, L., & Cook, J. M. (2001). Birds of a feather: Homophily in social networks. Annual Review of Sociology, 27, 415–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, M. J. D. (1978a). The convergence of variable metric methods for non-linearly constrained optimization calculations. In O. L. Mangasarian, R. R. Meyer & S. M. Robinson (Eds.), Nonlinear programming (vol. 3, pp. 27–63). New York: Academic Press.

  • Powell, M. J. D. (1978b). A fast algorithm for nonlinearly constrained optimization calculations. In G. A. Waston (Ed.), Numerical analysis (pp. 144–157). Berlin: Springer.

  • Powell, M. J. D. (1983). Variable metric methods for constrained optimization. In A. Bachem, M. Grotschel & B. Korte (Eds.), Mathematical programming the state of the art (pp. 288–311). Berlin: Springer.

  • Richardson, M., Domingos, P. (2002). Mining knowledge-sharing sites for viral marketing. In Proceedings of the eighth ACM SIGKDD international conference on knowledge discovery and data mining (pp. 61–70). New York: ACM.

  • Schittkowski, K. (1986). Nlpql: A fortran subroutine solving constrained nonlinear programming problems. Annals of Operations Research, 5(2), 485–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt, P., Skiera, B., & Van den Bulte, C. (2011). Referral programs and customer value. Journal of Marketing, 75(1), 46–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watts, D. J., & Dodds, P. S. (2007). Influentials, networks, and public opinion formation. Journal of Consumer Research, 34(4), 441–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research has been co-financed by the European Union (European Social Fund—ESF) and Greek national funds through the Operational Program “Education and Lifelong Learning” of the National Strategic Reference Framework (NSRF)—Research Funding Program: Aristeia, SocioMine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dionisios N. Sotiropoulos.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bilanakos, C., Sotiropoulos, D.N., Georgoula, I. et al. Optimal Influence Strategies in Social Networks. Comput Econ 49, 517–561 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-016-9568-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-016-9568-1

Keywords

Navigation