Computational Economics

, Volume 31, Issue 3, pp 289–306 | Cite as

The Impact of Interaction and Social Learning on Aggregate Expectations

Article

Abstract

We examine the effect of information sharing within small world networks. Agents receive a signal correlated with the state of the world (SoW) which is adjusted following discussions with neighbours. If one agent in the network, referred to as an expert, does not engage in social learning (that is they always follow their own signal) then all agents learn the SoW. It is found that volatility in the mean level of expectations varies with changes in the number of experts and the network structure. A trade-off emerges between the level of volatility and the speed at which agents learn of changes to the SoW. A second finding is that certain network structures lead to information cascades.

Keywords

Social learning Expectations formation Network economics Information contagion Volatility 

JEL Classification

D82 D83 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Ahn I., Suominen M. (2001). Word-of-mouth communication and community enforcement. International Economic Review, 42(2): 399–415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bala V., Goyal S. (1998). Learning from neighbours. Review of Economic Studies, 65(3):595–621CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Banerjee A. (1992). A simple model of herd behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(3):797–817CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Banerjee A., Fudenberg D. (2004). Word-of-mouth learning. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(1):1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bikhchandani S., Hirshleifer D., Welch I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change in informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100(5):992–1026CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Calvo-Armengol A., Zenou Y. (2005). Job matching, social network and word-of-mouth communication. Journal of Urban Economics, 57(3):500–522CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Chevalier, J. A., & Mayzlin, D. (2003). The effect of word of mouth on sales: Online book reviews. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc., NBER Working Papers 10148.Google Scholar
  8. Cowan R., Jonard N. (2004). Network structure and the diffusion of knowledge. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28(8): 1557–1575CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ellison G., Fudenberg D. (1995). Word-of-mouth communication and social learning. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1): 93–125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Flieth B., Foster J. (2002). Interactive expectations. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12(4):375–395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Foster J. (2000). Competitive selection, self-organisation and Joseph A. Schumpeter. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(3):311–328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Gaio L., Kaniovski Y.M., Zaninotto E. (2002). On bubbling dynamics generated by a stochastic model of herd behavior. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12(5):525–538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Gale D., Kariv S. (2003). Bayesian learning in social networks. Games and Economic Behavior, 45(2):329–346CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Godes D., Mayzlin D. (2004). Using online conversations to study word-of-mouth communication. Marketing Science, 23(4): 545–560CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Goyal S., van der Leij M. J., Moraga-Gonzalez J.L. (2006). Economics: An emerging small world. Journal of Political Economy, 114(2):403–412CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Hong H., Kubik J.D., Stein J.C. (2004). Social interaction and stock-market participation. Journal of Finance, 59(1):137–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Ivkovich, Z., & Weisbenner, S. (2004). Information diffusion effects in individual investors’ common stock purchases: Covet thy neighbors’ investment choices. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc., NBER Working Papers 10436.Google Scholar
  18. Jackson M.O., Rogers B.W. (2005). The economics of small worlds. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3): 617–627Google Scholar
  19. Kijima M., Uchida Y. (2005). A Markov model for valuing asset prices in a dynamic bargaining market. Quantitative Finance, 5(3): 277–288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Lux T. (1998). The socio-economic dynamics of speculative markets: Interacting agents, chaos, and the fat tails of return distributions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 33(2): 143–165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Miller J., Page S. (2004). The standing ovation problem. Complexity, 9(5): 8–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Money R.B. (2000). Word-of-mouth referral sources for buyers of international corporate financial services. Journal of World Business, 35(3): 314–329CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Orlean A. (1995). Bayesian interactions and collective dynamics of opinion: Herd behavior and mimetic contagion. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28(2): 257–274CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Tesfatsion, L. (2006). Agent-based computational economics: A constructive approach to economic theory. In L. Tesfatsion & K. L. Judd (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics vol. 2: Agent-based computational economics. Elsevier, North-Holland.Google Scholar
  25. Veldkamp L. (2006). Media frenzies in the market for financial information. American Economic Review, 96(3): 577–601CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Watts D.J. (1999). Small worlds: The dynamics of networks between order and randomness. Princeton University Press, New JerseyGoogle Scholar
  27. Watts D., Strogatz S. (1998). Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature, 393, 440–442CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.School of EconomicsUniversity of QueenslandBrisbaneAustralia

Personalised recommendations