Advertisement

European Journal of Forest Research

, Volume 125, Issue 3, pp 303–315 | Cite as

Mixed forests and a flexible harvest policy: a problem for conventional risk analysis?

  • Thomas KnokeEmail author
  • Johannes Wurm
Original Paper

Abstract

The famous “Faustmann” equation, which allows for identifying the most profitable tree species on a given unstocked piece of land, assumes constant timber prices. In reality, timber prices may fluctuate dramatically. Several authors have proven for monocultures that waiting for an acceptable timber price (reservation price) before harvesting (flexible harvest policy) increases the net present value of forest management. The first part of this paper investigates how efficient a flexible harvest strategy may be applied in mixed forests and whether the optimal species mixture is changed under such harvest policy. Mixtures of the conifer Norway spruce [Picea abies (L.) Karst] and the broadleaf European beech (Fagus sylvatica L.) were investigated. In order to evaluate mixed forests, the risks and the correlation of risks between tree species as well as the attitude towards risk of the decision-maker (risk-aversion is assumed) were considered according to the classical theory of optimal portfolio selection. In the second part we took up a recent critique on modern financial theory by Mandelbrot. Whether or not the assumption of normally distributed financial flows, which are supposed to occur under risk, would be appropriate to evaluate the risk of forest management was investigated. Market and hazard risks as well as their correlation were integrated in the evaluation of mixed forests by means of Monte-Carlo simulations (MCS). The risk of the timber price fluctuation was combined with the natural hazard risk, caused mainly by insects, snow and wind. Applying the μ-σ-rule, the mean net present value (NPV) from 1,000 simulations and their standard deviation were used for the optimisation. Given a low-return, risk-free interest rate to assess potential species mixtures of the Norway spruce and European beech, optimal proportions of European beech increased according to the theory of optimum portfolio selection with growing risk aversion from 0 (ignorance of risk) to 60% (great risk-aversion). In relation to a fixed harvest policy, the net present value of both, Norway spruce and European beech, could be increased significantly. Since the hazard risks of European beech were substantially lower compared with the Norway spruce (relation of susceptibility 1:4) beech benefited more from the flexible harvest policy. A comparison of simulated frequency distributions of the NPV with the expected density functions under the assumption of a normal distribution revealed significant differences. Only in the case of European beech was the general shape of the simulated frequency distribution similar to a normal distribution (bell-shaped curve). However, the density of NPV close to the mean was much greater than expected under the assumption of a normal distribution. Consequently, the frequency of a negative NPV for a European beech forest was greatly overestimated when applying the normal distribution. Though the shape of the simulated frequency distribution was rather different from a normal distribution for Norway spruce the simulated part of negative NPV was quite well approximated by the normal distribution. Therefore the simulated and expected frequencies of negative NPV were similar in case of Norway spruce; only a slight underestimation was seen in the assumption of a normal distribution. It can be concluded that actually simulated frequencies of negative NPV seem to be better measures for risk than computed probabilities of negative NPV, which assume normal distribution. As the risk for European beech was greatly overestimated by the conventional assumption of a normal distribution, the optimal proportions of European beech were surely rather underestimated according to the theory of portfolio. MCS on optimum mixtures derived by the classical portfolio theory seems necessary to test the robustness of such mixtures.

Keywords

Mixed forest management Risk Risk-aversion Timber price-dependent harvest Risk quantification 

Notes

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank Mrs. Edith Lubitz for the language editing of the manuscript and two anonymous reviewers for valuable suggestions.

References

  1. Bamberg G, Coenenberg AG (1992) Betriebswirtschaftliche Entscheidungslehre. Vahlen, MünchenGoogle Scholar
  2. Baumgarten M, Teuffel K von (2005) Nachhaltige Waldwirtschaft in Deutschland. In: Teuffel K von, et al (eds) Waldumbau. Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp 1–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Bavarian State Forest Service (2001) Jahresbericht 2001. Bavarian State Ministry of Agriculture and Forests, MunichGoogle Scholar
  4. Brazee R, Mendelsohn R (1988) Timber Harvesting with Fluctuating Prices. For Sci 34:359–372Google Scholar
  5. Deegen P, Hung BC, Mixdorf U (1997) Ökonomische Modellierung der Baumartenwahl bei Unsicherheit der zukünftigen Temperaturentwicklung. Forstarchiv 68:194–205Google Scholar
  6. Dieter M (1997) Berücksichtigung von Risiko bei forstbetrieblichen Entscheidungen. Schriften zur Forstökonomie Bd. 16. Frankfurt/Main: J.D. Sauerländer’sGoogle Scholar
  7. Dieter M (2001) Land expectation values for spruce and beech calculated with Monte Carlo modelling techniques. For Policy Econ 2:157–166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Elton EJ, Gruber MJ (1995) Modern portfolio theory and investment analysis, 5th edn. Chichester, Wiley, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  9. Gerber HU, Pafumi G (1998) Utility functions: from risk theory to finance. North Am Actuarial J 2:74–100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Gong P (1998) Risk preferences and adaptive harvest policies for even-aged stand management. For Sci 44:496–506Google Scholar
  11. Haight RG (1990) Feedback thinning policies for uneven-aged stand management with stochastic prices. For Sci 36:1015–1031Google Scholar
  12. Hanewinkel M, Holcey J (2005) Quantifizierung von Risiko durch altersstufenweise Ermittlung von Übergangswahrscheinlichkeiten mit Hilfe von digitalisierten Forstkarten. In: Teuffel K von, et al (eds) Waldumbau. Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp 269–277Google Scholar
  13. Knoke T (2002) Value of perfect information on red heartwood formation in beech (Fagus sylvatica L.). Silva Fennica 36:841–851CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Knoke T, Moog M, Plusczyk N (2001) On the effect of volatile stumpage prices on the economic attractiveness of a silvicultural transformation strategy. ForPolicy Econ 2:229–240CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Knoke T, Stimm B, Ammer C, Moog M (2005) Mixed forests reconsidered: a forest economics contribution to the discussion on natural diversity. For Ecol Manag 213:102–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kouba J (2002) Das Leben des Waldes und seine Lebensunsicherheit. Forstwissenschaftliches Centralblatt 121:211–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Lohmander P (1993) Economic two stage multi species management in a stochastic environment: the value of selective thinning options and stochastic growth parameters. Syst Anal-Model-Simul 11:287–302Google Scholar
  18. Lüpke B, Spellmann H (1999) Aspects of stability, growth and natural regeneration in mixed Norway spruce-European beech stands as a basis of silviculture decisions. In: Olsthoorn AFM et al. (eds). Management of mixed-species forests: silviculture and economics. Wageningen: IBN-DLO Scientific contributions, pp 245–267 Google Scholar
  19. Mandelbrot BB, Hudson RL (2005) Fraktale und Finanzen: Märkte zwischen Risiko, Rendite und Ruin. Piper, MünchenGoogle Scholar
  20. Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Finance 7:77–91Google Scholar
  21. Möhring B (1986) Dynamische Betriebsklassensimulation – Ein Hilfsmittel für die Waldschadensbewertung und Entscheidungsfindung im Forstbetrieb. Berichte des Forschungszentrums Waldökosysteme-Waldsterben der Universität Göttingen Band 20Google Scholar
  22. Möhring B (2004) Betriebswirtschaftliche Analyse des Waldumbaus. Forst Holz 59:523–530Google Scholar
  23. Penttinen M, Lausti A (2004) The competitiveness and return components of NIPF ownership in Finland. Finnish J Business Econ, Spl Edn 2/2004 Google Scholar
  24. Pflaumer P (1992) Investitionsrechnung. Oldenburg Verlag, München, WienGoogle Scholar
  25. Pretzsch H (2005) Diversity and productivity in forests: evidence from long-term experimental plots. In: Scherer-Lorenzen et al. (eds) Forest diversity and function: temperate and boreal systems. Ecological studies, vol 176. Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp41–64Google Scholar
  26. Reed WJ (1996) Predicting the present value distribution of a forest plantation investment. For Sci 42:378–387Google Scholar
  27. Runzheimer B (1999) Operations research. Gabler, WiesbadenCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 14:425–442Google Scholar
  29. Spellmann H (2005) Produziert der Waldbau am Markt vorbei? Allg. Forstzeitschrift/Der Wald 60:454–459Google Scholar
  30. Spremann K (1996) Wirtschaft, Investition und Finanzierung. 5., vollständig überarbeitete, ergänzte und aktualisierte Auflage. Oldenbourg: München und WienGoogle Scholar
  31. Teeter LD, Caulfield JP (1991) Stand density management under risk: effects of stochastic prices. Can J For Res 21:1373–1379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Thomson TA (1991) Efficient combinations of timber and financial market investments in single-period and multiperiod portfolios. For Sci 37:461–480Google Scholar
  33. Valkonen S, Valsta L (2001) Productivity and economics of mixed two-storied spruce and birch stands in Southern Finland simulated with empirical models. For Ecol Manag 140:133–149CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Wagner JE, Rideout DB (1991) Evaluating forest management investments: the capital asset pricing model and the income growth model. For Sci 37:1591–1604Google Scholar
  35. Wagner JE, Rideout DB (1992) The stability of the capital asset pricing model’s parameters in analysing forest investments. Can J For Res 22:1639–1645CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Waller LA, Smith D, Childs JE, Leslie AR (2003) Monte Carlo assessment of goodness-of-fit for ecological simulation models. Ecol Model 164:49–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Weber M-W (2002) Portefeuille- und Optionspreis-Theorie und forstliche Entscheidungen. Schriften zur Forstökonomie Band 23. Sauerländer’s, Frankfurt a.MGoogle Scholar
  38. Wippermann Ch, Möhring B (2001) Exemplarische Anwendung der Portefeuilletheorie zur Analyse eines forstlichen Investments. Forst Holz 56:267–272Google Scholar
  39. Yool A (1999) Comments on the paper: on repeated parameter sampling in Monte Carlo simulations. Ecol Model 115:95–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Zinkhan FC, Cubbage FW (2003) Financial analysis of timber investments. In: Sills EO, Abt KL (eds) Forests in a market economy. Forestry sciences, vol 72. Kluwer, Dordrecht, Boston, London, pp 77–95Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Institute of Forest ManagementTechnische Universität MünchenFreisingGermany
  2. 2.Fachgebiet für Waldinventur und nachhaltige NutzungTU MünchenFreisingGermany

Personalised recommendations