1 Introduction

International trade, while recently beleaguered by protectionism and trade wars, is established in economics as an engine of growth, welfare and progress. Its potential for division of labour, specialisation and efficient use of capital is unmatched by any domestic policy, which would inevitably be faced with rigidities and restrictions in these factors. Nonetheless, the intensity of international trade has been stagnant below assumed efficient levels even before the protectionist trends of the present. The causes for these so-called “dark” trade costs partly remain unknown, preventing both a solution and a more optimal outcome.

In response to these anomalies, the trade literature has expanded the concept of economic gravity, based on market size, output and “hard” barriers—i.e. geographic distance and tariffs—by “soft” barriers such as cultural factors. These are based on persistent differences and similarities across countries, ranging from language or colonial history to shared values and even genetic distance. The proposed underlying mechanisms include facilitated communication, reduced informational frictions or historically established ties, but also even less tangible aspects such as shared beliefs and norms, that could foster bilateral trust, for example.

By linking data and insights from behavioural economics to the trade context, this paper proposes novel additional mechanisms connecting culture with trade outcomes. To this end, term (patience) and risk preferences as well as reciprocal behaviour are incorporated into a gravity analysis using the novel GPS preference data by Falk et al. (2018). These preferences, likely shaped by culture and society within a given country, might affect negotiations between firms and agents of different nations. They inform their time horizons, influencing discounted values of a deal, their willingness to risk investment into a trade relationship and their responses to (non-)cooperative behaviour. Each of these four aspects could help explain trade outcomes and anomalies in volume between economically similar country pairs.

Analytically, this paper is the first—to the best of the authors’ knowledge—to join the gravity model for trade with specific data on such behavioural preferences at the population level. That is, the observed preferences directly relate to economic decisions in the realm of contract theory and incomplete contracts. The paper expands the gravity model by a new dimension of soft barriers, which also provide a possible explanation for the effect of cultural distances on trade outcomes and for “missing trade” as well as “dark trade costs”.

Preferences are integrated into the gravity framework using a two-step approach: Distances in preferences across countries are incorporated into a standard gravity model to measure the effects of bilateral differences in reciprocity as well as term and risk transformation considerations. The national preference levels, meanwhile, are analysed by decomposing the multilateral resistance terms of the gravity equation, a country’s overall propensity towards trade, thus discerning potential shifts in trade inclination associated with specific national preference leanings. The GPS is particularly well-suited to this analysis because of its broad scope and quality, covering 76 countries through nationally representative surveys on these preferences and experimental validations for them.

This analysis finds that the distance in reciprocity between countries and term and risk orientation levels of a given country affect trade outcomes. Specifically, a distance in negative reciprocity between countries, i.e. the willingness to engage in costly punishment, is detrimental to export volumes by introducing unexpected costs in case of transaction issues.

The national level of long-term orientation and higher levels of risk aversion, meanwhile, lower the average trade barriers for differentiated goods, while raising them for non-differentiated ones. Less risk aversion and shorter term orientation have the opposite effects. This reflects term and risk transformation concerns by national players, wherein a product mix is selected whose trade and contract conditions reflect term and risk profiles. That is, the longer the term orientation the more complex and differentiated the product mix, and: the more risk-averse a country, the less volatile and more differentiated the produced goods. Lastly, preference effects are overall stronger for exporters, differentiated goods and OECD-countries, indicating the link between preferences and negotiation intensity as well as the financial risks being placed on the exporter.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 relates the paper to the existing literature, leading into Sect. 3 which summarizes the hypotheses of the analysis. Section 4 introduces the data and the empirical strategy, whose results are reported in Sect. 5. Section 6 discusses a set of robustness checks and their results. Finally, Sect. 7 concludes with a short discussion on the results and considerations for further research.

2 Related literature

This paper aims to link two fields of economic literature: the analysis of trade flows, especially on soft barriers to trade, and the literature on behavioural economics. Contract theory is utilised as the mechanism for this conjunction.

Our analysis builds on previous analyses of trade finance and the incomplete contracts governing trade, which have touched upon the behavioural considerations at the core of this paper. Trade finance explicitly deals with the management of risk in a trade context. Therein, risk is often placed primarily on the exporter given the wide prevalence of Open Account (OA) arrangements, i.e. the importer paying only after having received the goods (Ahn 2011; Antras 2003). Given these risks and uncertainties, it is unsurprising that complex, but (still) incomplete contracts govern the actual trade interactions. In addressing these complex contracts and their dynamic nature, Defever et al. (2016) and Kukharskyy (2016) have shown that only sufficiently patient firms may establish efficient long-term supplier collaborations. Findings by Araujo et al. (2016); Aeberhardt et al. (2014) and Rauch and Watson (2003) point to relationships being developed slowly, starting with small test orders until a relationship is established, reflecting reciprocity considerations. We build upon both of these relationships by attempting to investigate their more abstract, global effects using the GPS.

In regard to the broader trade literature, we contribute to the shift in discussion from conventional drivers like size and transportation costs to “missing trade” (Trefler 1995) and “dark” trade costs (Head and Mayer 2013) by proposing a novel influence in the form of national preference leanings and a simple mechanism by which its influence would occur. Closest to our analysis are Frank (2018) and Jaeggi et al. (2018) who analyse cultural attitudes as factors for overall economic development. These are future orientation and other measures from the GLOBE survey in the former and a dyadic values distance measure computed using the World Values Survey in the latter case. Genetic and values distances are consequently used as robustness checks in this analysis. However, we differ from their approaches in two ways: by also considering potential positive effects of such divergence and by proposing a channel for these effects by introducing behavioural concepts and contract theory. We follow previous analyses on cultural differences such as Melitz and Toubal (2014), who analysed the effects of a shared language and revealed a channel of shared ethnicity in the process. Another example would be Lameli et al. (2015), who discovered a trade-boosting effect between German regions sharing similar dialects. Similarly, Felbermayr and Toubal (2010) have investigated a proxy for cultural proximity as a determinant of trade flows and Fensore et al. (2017) have introduced genetic distance as a measure to this end as well.Footnote 1 Lastly, bilateral trust, which could also be considered a preference, has been extensively studied in the trade context, for example by Guiso et al. (2009) or Yu et al. (2015), who find positive effects of trust on trade activity.

Naturally, our analysis also connects to the behavioural economics literature leading up to the GPS study itself (Falk et al. 2016, 2018) and to research by Dohmen et al. (2016) linking patience with national economic development. Thereby, we also relate to a broader literature linking the preferences also measured in the GPS to individual outcomes. This includes Sutter et al. (2013) who link time and risk preferences to saving and smoking decisions, Kihlstrom and Laffont (1979) who investigate entrepreneurial activity with regards to the risk preferences of the players, and Fehr et al. (1997); Fehr and Gächter (2000, 2002) and Nikiforakis (2008) who all investigate the effects of reciprocity preferences on collective action and their outcomes. Here, we contribute to the literature by observing expressions of these individual decisions and outcomes at the aggregate level.

3 Hypotheses

In this section, the hypothetical mechanisms by which preferences might affect trade outcomes are presented and their directions summarised. For each of the four GPS dimensions patience, risk, positive and negative reciprocity, two effects are considered: the level of a given country and bilateral differences across countries. That is, a preference could matter unilaterally and shift a country’s general attitude towards trade or it could matter only in contrast to the partner’s preference distributions. The resulting dimensions and their proposed effect directions are displayed in Table 1 at the end of this section.

As a simple guiding structure, a Home producer looking to export to a Foreign distributor is considered. Alternative settings, e.g. a Home firm looking for a supplier or the viewpoint of the Foreign firm, could be conceived analogously, but the prevalence of Open Account (OA) contracts usually burdens the risk on the exporter.Footnote 2 Thus, it is the Home producer who has the largest incentives to carefully consider his trade relationships, implying a potentially larger role of exporter’s preferences, as well.

In this setting, producers and distributors have to choose between domestic and international relationships, wherein the latter are associated with greater uncertainties due to a - typically - lower knowledge of these partners and their markets. These uncertainties include the timing of payments as well as default and recoupment risks, for which the players would formulate expectations and, in a next step, expected values for a given trade relationship. These calculations and thus the outcomes might be shaped or influenced by the preference leanings of the players involved. In the following, the rationale for each of the four dimensions investigated in this analysis is provided.


Patience Patience measures the willingness to forego short-term profits for higher gains in the long-run and therefore factors into the evaluation of the timing of payments in the setting outlined above. Higher levels of patience should imply a lower discount (higher interest) rate, i.e. a higher tolerance for delayed payments, and consequently benefit trade volumes and intensity by raising the expected value of trade.

Another rationale for this hypothesis is the understanding of trade as a means to achieve efficiency gains by constructing international supply and distribution networks, allowing greater specialization. Since the construction of these networks, from contract negotiations to physical construction and transport times, requires time and effort, more patient agents would be more likely to engage in these activities than impatient agents. Conversely, impatient agents would be more likely to engage with local partners despite a potential long-term disadvantage.

This mechanism could also be interpreted as a form of comparative advantage, in which the opportunity costs for production are lowest for those goods which best fit a country’s level of patience by avoiding costly term transformations, inviting specialization into these goods. The gains from that specialization would manifest best between differently patient players exploiting their respective comparative advantages. Hence, these gains would define the effect of distances in patience on trade and should be positive. However, the more pronounced effect of a comparative advantage is the change in the composition and structure of trade, which might overshadow a potential bilateral increase in volumes.


Risk-taking The GPS risk preference can be understood as an inverse measure of the average risk premium a given population is willing to pay. For highly risk-tolerant societies, this measure can take a negative value, while it is positive for the average population. With regards to trade outcomes, less risk-aversion should facilitate the formation of trade relations as it would heighten the tolerance for trade-associated risks and uncertainties such as defaults on payments. For exporters in particular, this tolerance would be required so as to compensate for the risks placed on them by the structure of trade finance.

However, considering the greater picture of trade, it might be risk-minimising to diversify into a multitude of international relationships, lowering the exposure to local shocks and individual contracts. Note that this diversification argument applies to both securing access to inputs and to maintaining steady sales and cashflows. Hence, the effect of unilateral national risk-taking levels on trade outcomes is unclear ex ante.

On the other hand, the effect of bilateral distances in risk attitudes on trade should be positive. A divergence in risk perceptions should allow for forms of arbitrage and for risk transformation, similar to the hypothesis for patience, with regards to the product mix of the players of a given country pair. This, too, can be viewed as a form of comparative advantage, wherein less risk-averse players have lower opportunity costs in producing goods with a higher perceived commercial risk and vice-versa. Trade then generates efficiency gains by reducing the amount of risk premia needed to facilitate overall production.


Positive reciprocity Positive reciprocity is the willingness to reward cooperative behaviour and positive actions, i.e. a propensity to “return a favour”. In general, the presence of a more positively reciprocal player should stabilize commercial agreements by inducing cooperation. This can be achieved through positive feedback loops caused by reliable and timely deliveries and payments, which would build up goodwill on both sides of the relationship.Footnote 3 In contract terms, positively reciprocal actions could lower the perceived risk of defaults or assume the shape of more accommodating terms of payment within an active and ongoing relationship, thus lowering costs and building trust.

Consequently, the distance in positive reciprocity should have a positive effect due to the implied presence of one highly positively reciprocal partner. In such a relationship, the reciprocal behaviour of that partner would be viewed akin to a standard gift exchange (cf. Akerlof 1982) and thus strengthen the relationship between the players. Moreover, the effect of positive reciprocity can only manifest within existing relationships. Hence, it would neither shift the overall approach to trade nor the extensive margin of trade, defined here as the number of bilateral non-zero trade flows on the three-digit SITC industry level.


Negative reciprocity Negative reciprocity describes a willingness to conduct costly punishment of non-cooperative behaviour and negative actions. A hypothesis on its effects is complicated. On one hand, higher levels imply a willingness to punish deviation from contracts and agreements—even beyond a monetarily rational level—,thus raising the cost of a breach of contract once it has been established. While this might partially deter some initial agreements in the first place, the prospect of a more credible punishment could help to prevent deviation by raising the costs to the partner deviating from the contract. In this way, it may foster the establishment of persistent trade relationships. Dohmen et al. (2008), for example, highlight this ability to make credible threats as a potential bargaining advantage.

However, this seems to hold true for milder forms of negative reciprocity only. In its strongest forms—decisively taking revenge and anti-social punishment—, negative reciprocity may actually hinder coordination and cooperation (Gächter and Herrmann 2009; Herrmann et al. 2008). In a contract framework, the risks associated with the threat of punishment could become higher than the prospective gains from trade, causing a rational player to abstain from the deal. As an example for this perspective, Caliendo et al. (2012) observe that a propensity to take revenge negatively affects the probability of staying in entrepreneurship, suggesting that high levels of negative reciprocity reflect non-cooperation and reduce one’s own profits.

More importantly, if partners differ in negative reciprocity, the actions of the more negatively reciprocal partner might antagonize or alarm the less reciprocal partner. Thus, larger distances in negative reciprocity are expected to reduce bilateral trade. For the level effect, no clear prognosis is possible.


Overall Bilateral Distance Following the literature on shared characteristics in trade such as language, ethnicity and culture, the effect of overall preference distances between two countries is also analysed. This serves two purposes. First, it allows a comparison to studies regarding such shared characteristics and to control for a potential correlation with them. Second, it allows for testing the hypothesis that partners with more similar preference sets would be more likely to trade with one another solely on account of that greater similarity causing affinity. Given the diverging proposed directions for the preference dimensions specified above, such an effect is unlikely to emerge at the overall level.

Table 1 Summary of the hypotheses for preferences

4 Data and empirical strategy

Mapping and isolating the potential impact of preferences on trade requires a comprehensive, three-part data set consisting of the GPS’ preference data, the corresponding trade data and a set of cultural and institutional controls. The following subsections will be dedicated to describing the data used and the empirical strategy.

4.1 Data

Preference Data The main variables of interest are the GPS’ results detailing a four-dimensional preference structure for 76 countries: patience, risktaking, positive and negative reciprocity. Patience is therein understood as a broader measure of term orientation or time discount considerations, whereas risk assesses the average risk premium of a given population. Positive reciprocity is the willingness to reward cooperative behaviour and, consequently, negative reciprocity the willingness to conduct costly punishment of non-cooperative or deviant behaviour.Footnote 4 All preferences are considered to be persistent, underlying convictions or notions, related to upbringing, education, norms and other societal trends.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Preference structure and trade volume. Notes: Relationship between the export values, normalised by GDP, and GPS preference values for all countries in the GPS for which trade volumes can be computed

The GPS was conducted alongside the 2012 Gallup World Poll, utilising the infrastructure and scope of that survey to gain both coverage and size. The Gallup World Poll interviewed representative samples of at least 1000 persons per covered country and uses tried weighting techniques for these samples to match a nation’s population. The GPS’ data covers all important global economies with the possible exception of Africa. Around ninety percent of world population and GDP lie within the sample borders. Africa’s coverage is less dense than for the other continents, but both Sub-Saharan and North African countries are included, which permits their use without disregarding the structural differences imposed by the Sahara desert (see Falk et al. 2018). This scope permits conclusions beyond the traditionally available data from more developed countries only. This size and the World Poll’s methodology elevate the GPS above previously available measures.

Additionally, the survey items—except for negative reciprocity—are experimentally validated (see Falk et al. 2018), in that incentivized experiments were conducted to evaluate the fit between survey answers and revealed preferences in the experiment. This factor differentiates the GPS from other typically questionnaire-only surveys of similar intent by contextualizing the preferences as economic. The focus is shifted from abstract cultural measures and perceptions to their role in decision-making. Via that channel, these preferences inform negotiations, defining term and risk profiles and behaviour in interaction.

As for the preferences themselves, they are provided in a normalized distribution, calculated in a three-step procedure. First, individual-level data on the experimental and survey data is combined using weights obtained by OLS regression on behavior observed in the experimental validation study conducted beforehand (see Falk et al. 2016). Secondly, these measures are standardized with regard to the full sample of around 80,000 individuals from all 76 countries. Hence, each preference is, by design, of mean zero and standard deviation one on individual levels. Third—and lastly—, individual-level data of each country is aggregated to the national average using Gallup World Poll sampling weights. As a result, the national averages are representative of a respective country’s population and similarly have means close to zero. Their standard deviations lie between 0.27 and .37, with explicit minima and maxima diverging from symmetry (see Table 2). Figure 1 relates GPS values to national export volumes (relative to GDP), providing an overview of the country’s preference distributions.Footnote 5

Table 2 Descriptive statistics of the GPS variables

Culture, Politics and Institutions Preferences might be correlated with other cultural variables. They could also interact with institutional settings, as has been found for trust and rule of law (Yu et al. 2015), or the overall economic situation. To account for these potential biases, a broad range of cultural, historic, political or economic indicators supplements the preference data. This includes population, GDP and other national characteristics from the CEPII (Head et al. 2010; Head and Mayer 2014) as well as information on geography and colonial history (Mayer and Zignago 2011).Footnote 6 Information on regional trade agreements is extracted from Egger and Larch (2008).

Data on linguistic similarities is integrated using data from Melitz and Toubal (2014), who provide and compare multiple measurements for the resulting ease of communication. In the same vein, information regarding cultural, religious and genetic distance from Spolaore and Wacziarg (2016, 2018) is used to account for the more general effects of alien- or likeness. The Dyadic Values Distance measure created by Jaeggi et al. (2018) and drawn from the World Values Survey is included for contrast and comparison; as are the Hofstede dimensions (see Hofstede et al. 2010).

For political and institutional influences, the Polity scores (2018), Freedom House indices (2018), and Worldwide Governance Indicators (Kaufmann et al. 2009) are used. These assess democratic or autocratic leanings and civil liberties as well as issues of politic representation, respectively. Thus, the measures can be used as proxies for legal rights and personal freedom, which might both impact negotiation behavior and outcomes.


Trade Data The trade data used in the analysis is obtained from UN Comtrade for 2012, the year in which the GPS had been conducted, at the 3-digit industry level (SITC, Rev. 4). Flows are measured using import data, which is considered more accurate due to customs and tariff requirements of the receiving country. All 240 goods categories are observed for 68 countries of the GPS. The disaggregated data is used to divide trade flows into listed, reference priced and differentiated goods according to Rauch (1999), as these groups might respond differently.

A subset of ten nations available in the GPS—Afghanistan, Botswana, Cameroon, Haiti, Iran, Iraq, Kenya, Morocco, Philippines and Venezuela—, have not yet reported for 2012. Their flows are calculated using export data from their 66 partner countriesFootnote 7. Additionally, Bosnia-Herzegovina and Serbia are dropped due to the risk of confounding with Yugoslavia for several cultural variables, while Afghanistan is dropped due to a general lack in controls.

Given these corrections, the final dataset contains 73 countries from all continents, yielding 5256 exporter-importer pairs and 1,261,440 bilateral good-specific trade flows. Of these, 35.8 percent are non-zero, whereas the average value of a bilateral good-specific trade flow amounts to 8.9 million US-Dollar. The average country trades with 67 out of 72 potential partners and in 86 out of 240 goods categories.Footnote 8

4.2 The model

The analysis is built upon the Gravity framework by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and its expansions by Head and Mayer (2014); Yotov et al. (2016) and Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006); Santos Silva et al. (2014). Therein, international trade \(x_{ij}\), between exporter \(i = 1, ... , I\) and importer \(j = 1, ..., J\), is modeled as:

$$\begin{aligned} x_{ij} = \underbrace{\dfrac{Y_i}{\varOmega _i}}_{S_i} \underbrace{\dfrac{X_j}{\varPhi _j}}_{M_j} \phi _{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

\(Y_i\) and \(X_j\) are the total values of exporter production and importer expenditure, respectively, and \(\phi _{ij}\) describes the bilateral trade costs between i and j, which are assumed to be symmetric. \(\varOmega _i\) and \(\varPhi _j\) represent the multilateral resistance terms, a representation of the average trade barriers faced by exporters. These terms can be defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \varOmega _i = \sum _{l}^{} \dfrac{\phi _{il} X_l}{\varPhi _l} ~ \text { and } ~ \varPhi _j = \sum _{l}^{} \dfrac{\phi _{lj} Y_l}{\varOmega _l} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

\(\varOmega _i\) is the expression of an exporter i’s average cost of exporting to any other country, and \(\varPhi _j\) correspondingly the average cost of importing into country j.Footnote 9 An alternative designation is that of outward and inward multilateral resistance term, respectively (see Donaubauer et al. 2018). With the Gravity framework’s three cost parameters, \(\phi _{ij}\), \(\varOmega _i\) and \(\varPhi _i\), the potential effects of GPS preferences can be studied. Differences between them could influence transaction costs by affecting negotiations through aligning term and risk transformation objectives or reciprocal gestures. These preference distances thus constitute a bilateral cost parameter (\(\phi _{ij}\)), which also permits comparison with the similarly modelled cultural differences. Preference leanings, meanwhile, could influence the overall openness to trade of a given population by defining its outlook. They can be analysed only akin to unilateral economic variables, i.e. as part of the resistence terms \(\varOmega _i\) and \(\varPhi _j\).

Intensive Margin Both multilateral resistance terms are typically modelled as fixed effects, \(S_i\) and \(M_j\) (see Eq. 1), due to computational and information restrictions. This method also accounts for unobserved heterogeneity in trade determinants. Given the assumption of persistence for preferences, a country’s preference leanings would be subsumed under the fixed effects. However, these fixed effects and its components can be analysed in a two-step approach using a Gravity specification first and OLS on the estimated fixed effects second (cf. Donaubauer et al. 2018; Head and Mayer 2014). Thus, unilateral preference levels can be analysed in this trade context. In accordance with the wider literature, that specification is estimated using Pseudo Poisson Maximum Likelihood (PPML) for consistency in the presence of heteroskedasticity and zero trade flows (Santos Silva and Tenreyro 2006). The first step estimator is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} x_{ij} = exp \left( \left| \varvec{z_i} - \varvec{z_j}\right| \varvec{\beta } + S_i + M_j + \varvec{\phi _{ij}'} \varvec{\gamma } \right) + \epsilon _{ij}, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(S_i\) and \(M_j\) are the exporter and importer fixed effects—or average trade barriers—, including preference levels.\(\varvec{\phi _{ij}}\) is a vector of bilateral (dyadic) trade cost variables. \(x_{ij}\) is the volume of exports from country i to country j, the intensive margin of trade. \(\left| \varvec{z_i} - \varvec{z_j}\right|\) is a vector of the preference distances between a country pair. Each of the four preferences patience, risk, positive and negative reciprocity is included separately. The use of absolute distances serves three purposes. First, it distinguishes the distances from the unilateral levels (leanings), allowing effect decomposition. Second, it abstracts from the direction of distances, which might conflate effects otherwise due to its correlation with the levelsFootnote 10. Third, it is necessary as the provided GPS variables are normalized, for which reason normal differences cannot be estimated.Footnote 11

The gravity equations are applied to both the total bilateral trade volumes and separate volumes for differentiated and non-differentiated goods. This split accounts for the fact that negotiations, the effect channel, would play a more important role for differentiated goods than for listed or reference-priced commodities. The more goods diverge from a global standard, the more details need to be covered in the bilateral negotiations and the less can be relied on that standard to assure an effective contract and relationship. This split is achieved using the Rauch (1999) classifications for three-digit SITC 4 commodity classes, yielding 240 separate potential bilateral flows per country pair. In a second step, those are aggregated into two export volumes, one for each group.

In the second step, the estimated exporter and importer fixed effects are each regressed on their respective preference measures \(\varvec{z_i}\) and country-specific variables \(\varvec{C_i}\) such as GDP per capita, population and internal distance:

$$\begin{aligned} S_i = \alpha _0 + \alpha _1 \overline{\phi _i} + \varvec{C_i}' \varvec{\delta } + \varvec{z_i}' \varvec{\eta } + v_i ~~ and ~~ M_i = \alpha _0 + \alpha _1 \overline{\phi _i} + \varvec{C_i}' \varvec{\delta } + \varvec{z_i}' \varvec{\eta } + v_i, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(\overline{\phi _i}\) is the weighted average over the dyadic characteristics of each country \(\overline{\phi _i} = \sum _{j}{\varvec{\phi _{ij}' {\hat{\gamma }}}}\).Footnote 12

National preference leanings and bilateral differences are thus analysed separately: The parameters in the gravity equation measure only the impact of differences in preferences, a dimensionless discrepancy in outlook. Meanwhile, the fixed effects decomposition informs on the change in the willingness to trade implied by high and low national preference measures.


Extensive Margin So far, the impact of preferences has been modeled as one of repeated interactions within existing commercial relationships, that is: the intensive margin, the volume of trade flows. Yet negotiations and other communication also take place during the inception of trade, that is: the change from a zero flow to a non-zero one—the extensive margin. While it is impossible to capture the exact moment in time when a contract between firms for a country pair and specific good is first formed, an average over these events can be approximated via the number of traded goods categories. This limitation conveniently matches the GPS’ own of being representative only at the country-level. Contextually, it allows insight into how the composition of trade—i.e. whether a bilateral relationship is diversified over several goods classes or restricted to only a few—is affected by preference levels of a given country or their bilateral distances.

For these purposes—and to retain coherence with the intensive margin estimates—the extensive margin is defined as a count variable of bilateral non-zero trade flows on the three-digit SITC industry level c: \(T_{ij} = \sum _{c}{} t_{cij} ~~, \text {with: } t_{cij} = 1 ~, \text {if: } X_{cij} > 0\). \(T_{ij}\) thus has a lower bound of 0 and an upper bound of 240, the amount of three-digit industry classifications. As with its intensive margin counterpart, the extensive goods margin is estimated at the aggregate level, for differentiated and for non-differentiated goods classes. In all cases, PPML is used in specifications otherwise identical to those for the intensive margin:Footnote 13

$$\begin{aligned} T_{ij} = exp \left( \left| \varvec{z_i} - \varvec{z_j}\right| \varvec{\zeta } + S_i + M_j + \varvec{\phi _{ij}'} \varvec{\theta } \right) + \nu _{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(5)

5 Results

5.1 Standard gravity

The results from estimating the intensive margin of trade via PPML are reported in Table 3. Specification (1) is a conventional gravity equation regressing bilateral exports on distanceFootnote 14, contiguity, colonial relationships, existing regional trade agreements, a shared language and country fixed effects. With the exception of common language (lng) the coefficients have the expected directions and are significant at least at the one percent level. The non-significane of common language does not change when using native and spoken language dummies. This result is in line with Melitz and Toubal (2014), who likewise find insignificant language effects when using PPML estimatorsFootnote 15 and whose language data is used in this analysis.

Table 3 Estimation of aggregated bilateral exports
Table 4 Estimation of goods category-specific exports

Specifications (2) and (3) incorporate a bilateral distance in preferences measure similar to Jaeggi et al. (2018) or Spolaore and Wacziarg (2018) regarding values and genetics. This variable is defined as the unweighted average of the l single preference distances: \(\text {dpref} = \dfrac{1}{l} \sum _{k}^{l}(\left| \varvec{z_{ki}} - \varvec{z_{kj}})\right|\). It measures whether preferences affect outcomes simply by being different between partners, which would speak for the overall preferences reflecting or proxying for a simple cultural (dis-)similarity. Such an outcome is not observed as dpref is non-significant in both models. Its inclusion does not alter conventional gravity parameters, implying little correlation between these variables and the preferences, given fixed effects.

In specifications (4) and (5), single preference distances across countries are included. Specification (5) also incorporates measures for distance in legal system quality leg.qltFootnote 16 and comleg, a dummy indicating whether a pair shares the same legal tradition. These are added to insure that the effect of reciprocity is not related to non-performing legal systems which might be conducive to punishing behaviour as a means to compensate for the lack of legal recourse (cf. Herrmann et al. 2008).Footnote 17 This separation reveals a highly significant effect of distances in negative reciprocity on the volume of goods exports. A one standard deviation 0.236)Footnote 18 increase—e.g. the distance between Czechia and Lithuania—, would decrease the respective trade volume by 12.5% when accounting for legal systems and 14.87% when not.

This result reflects the hypothesis that a distance in negative reciprocity might deter the less negatively reciprocal partner from engaging with a highly negatively reciprocal partner due to the latter’s insistence on credible and strong punishment. These punishments—especially if unexpected—would raise the risks of a contract from the perspective of the less negatively reciprocal partner and drive him to limit his exposure to that partner. If punishment has occured already, it might motivate him to end that contract. In the same vein, the negatively reciprocal partner might execute a “grim trigger”-like strategy and thus end the relationship permanently. Regarding our hypotheses, these adverse effects appear to outmatch the potential commitment effect (or: reduced incentive to deviate) caused by a higher willingness to commit costly punishment.Footnote 19

The distance in risk is also significant, albeit only at the 10% level, with an effect similar in size to that of dnegrec when accounting for legal systems.Footnote 20 This corresponds to the diversification or risk transformation hypothesis, in that more risk-averse countries would outsource riskier enterprises, preferring to import their produce—and vice versa. This particular match of a more risk-averse and a risk-tolerant partner may facilitate agreement on the form of trade finance contracts because both partners could agree on allocating risk to the less risk-averse side. Given the significance and robustness issues with this result, it needs to be treated with caution.

5.2 Differentiated and non-differentiated goods

Expanding on the aggregated results, specification (5) of Table 3 is used for an analysis on differentiated and non-differentiated goods, according to the Rauch (1999) specifications at the 3-digit level. That separation yields two sets of comparable trade volumes and produces reasonable results for conventional variables. Most notably, distance matters significantly more for non-differentiated goods. The other conventional variables are comparable across the subsets and specifications. Legal quality continues to matter, though a common legal system appears insignificant for non-differentiated goods. The latter is likely a result of the more formalized exchanges governing non-differentiated goods trade, which reduce the importance of legal recourse. Also, as in the aggregated specification, the overall preference dimensions remain non-significant.

In general, preferences appear to matter less for non-differentiated goods, which can likely also be attributed to the more formalized exchanges in play. Of the GPS dimensions, only bilateral distances in negative reciprocity matter for non-differentiated goods and their significance is also diminished compared to the aggregate or the differentiated cases. For differentiated goods, the results for bilateral distances in negative reciprocity remain similar to the aggregated results.Footnote 21

Distance in risk is still significant at the 10%-level only, but solely for differentiated goods. This fits the risk transformation hypothesis as transformation can only occur with different risk profiles. If risk-averse players self-select into the less volatile differentiated goods, their export markets must be less risk-averse, or else they would have the same production profile. On the other hand, more risk-tolerant players benefit from trading with more risk-averse partners willing to pay a premium for the risk avoidance. Hence, the effect is positive. Secondly, non-differentiated goods can be traded on exchanges, thus reducing the options for less risk-averse players to strike direct bilateral agreements for risk transformation purposesFootnote 22.

Table 5 Estimation of fixed effects composition

Distances between countries in positive reciprocity have a weakly significant, positive effect on trade volumes for differentiated goods (specification (2) of Table 4 in the Appendix), whereas there is no significant effect for non-differentiated goods. The coefficient corresponds to a 9.2% increase in trade per standard deviation (0.31; equal the distance between Austria and the Netherlands). This positive effect, if robust, likely reflects the stabilising effect of rewards by the more positively reciprocal player towards his partner, for whom this behaviour would be unexpected given his different reciprocity profile, but beneficial. In this dimension, cultural distance appears to have a positive effect on the intensity of trade. This further highlights why the overall distance in preferences is not significant and presents a case wherein contrasting values or preferences might be beneficial to economic exchange.

5.3 Impact on average barriers

The fixed effects, i.e. the average trade barriers, are extracted from the single preference specifications (2) and (4) of Sect. 5.2, Table 4, to decompose the effects of GPS preferences on trade outcomes. The effects from the separate sets are used due to the substantial observed differences in coefficients between the goods classes.Footnote 23 Exporter and importer fixed effects of the two goods specifications are each regressed on average bilateral characteristics relating to the country in question, population and per-capita GDP, a landlocked dummy and the single preferences in their levels. Population pop and per-capita GDP gdpcap are significant and have the expected positive signs for importers and exporters alike. Being landlocked has an expected negative effect, signalling the higher transport costs arising from lacking ocean access. Average bilateral characteristics are included for consistency in accordance with Head and Mayer (2014) only and cannot be interpreted on their own. The results are shown in Table 5.

As mentioned in Sect. 3, it is usually the exporter who faces a delay in payment and the risk of default due to the prevalence of open account (OA) payment forms.Footnote 24 Indeed, our results suggest that preferences only seem to matter for exporters—displayed in specifications (1) & (3).Footnote 25

Reasonably then, risk-taking is also the dominant preference. The more risk-averse a population is on averageFootnote 26, the more differentiated goods it exports but also the less non-differentiated ones. However, the effect on differentiated goods is stronger. For differentiated goods, a one standard deviation change in risk-taking (0.302) would lower the average fixed effect (21.7) by 3.35%. This corresponds to a decrease in exports of approximately equal size and a jump from Brazil’s risk attitude to Sweden’s. The same change implies an increase of 2.28% for non-differentiated goods.Footnote 27

According to these results, higher risk-aversion implies a comparative advantage for and correspondingly a product mix heavy in differentiated goods, whereas a higher risk tolerance yields a product mix intensive in non-differentiated goods. This corroborates the risk transformation argument for distance in risk as alternative suppliers for differentiated goods are scarcer, increasing the bargaining power of the exporter even in an Open Account setting. Given this incentive, risk-averse suppliers would self-select into these goods.

Meanwhile, more risk-tolerant players gain a comparative advantage for non-differentiated goods as they put less weight on the associated opportunity costs - i.e. the risk of being substituted with a competitor and the general OA risks. As they are effectively offered risk premia for providing non-differentiated goods, risk-tolerant players will conversely self-select into these. However, the formal organization of the markets for non-differentiated goods and nation-specific resource allotments should reduce the effect on these goods categories.Footnote 28

Patience yields opposite results to risk: a one standard deviation increase (0.370: from Brazil to Vietnam) in the preference increases exports of differentiated goods by 3.28%, but decreases those of non-differentiated ones by 2.42%. That is, more patient countries export more in differentiated goods and less in non-differentiated ones. These coefficients align with their underlying long-term considerations or discount factor arguments. Differentiated goods require more up-front investment to produce or trade and involve more complex searches and negotiations with potential partners. Both requires a longer time horizon for the players in question, while non-differentiated goods remove the necessity for search and negotiations by accessing organized exchanges.

Additionally, different national patience levels allow for term transformation, i.e. firms specializing on products maximizing profits corresponding to their country’s particular time horizons. These foci would differ between nations, constituting competitive advantages and efficiency gains from trade, subsequently reinforcing these specializations. Notably, due to these specializations becoming more niche, gains could be achieved even between partners of similarly high time preferences, thus explaining the non-significance of dpati.

Capital allotment—based on discount and interest rates—and contract enforcement would appear as reasonable channels for these specialization procedures.Footnote 29 As illustrated by Nunn (2007), better enforcement implies more trade in goods which are intensive in relationship-specific investments. Patience, as long-term orientation, would be conducive to considering gains from repeated interactions and more elaborate trade networks. The costs for contract enforcement and its design would then become bearable given the expected future gains from engaging in the effort.

Lastly, the change in effect directions for differentiated and non-differentiated goods further underlines that term and risk preferences address more than cultural heterogeneity when it comes to trade. These results also explain the lack of a clear relationship between aggregated, normalized exports and national preferences in Fig. 1.

5.4 Breadth of trade: the extensive margin

Lastly, the extensive goods margin of trade and thus the negotiations establishing economic exchange are observed using the 3-digit SITC-industry specifications to transform trade volumes into 240 binary choices per country pair. That is: Does country i export good c to country j? Specification (1) of Table 6 presents a conventional PPML gravity estimation for the aggregation of these choices. Specification (2) displays the extensive margin equivalent to Sect. 5.1, while specifications (3) and (4) are equivalent to Sect. 5.2. The coefficients and significances for the conventional variables are reasonable and in line with the volume results, except for the (partial) non-significance of contiguity and regional trade agreements.Footnote 30

Table 6 Estimation of the breadth of trade

Distance in patience is significant for the breadth of trade between two nations.Footnote 31 A one standard deviation increase in dpati (0.331, Estonia to France) increases the number of goods categories traded by 9 to 10%. This positive effect supports the term transformation and specialization argument. Likely, the more patient country in a respective pair invests more heavily in his trade network to achieve further specialization gains. If so, country pairs with higher bilateral distances in patience would follow diverging specialization and investment paths, yielding different product sets and thus venues for trade across goods classes.Footnote 32Footnote 33 This interpretation also aligns with the observation that high patience reduces (outward) export barriers for differentiated goods, while low patience appears to reduce them for non-differentiated commodities (see Sect. 5.3). Term orientation can therefore be seen as a motivation for specialization and trade.

Distances between countries in positive reciprocity also appear to affect the number of goods categories traded. Per standard deviation of distance (France and Spain, for example), the number of categories traded is reduced by 3%. This adverse effect is puzzling. Given the contract-stabilising effect of unexpected rewards to cooperative behaviour by one party, which would intensify existing relationships but not affect the development of new ones, a non-significant coefficient had been expected. Similar to that argument, the non-significance of dnegrec implies that its negative effect on trade volumes is not based on the threat of punishment, but reduction of exposure in existing contracts.Footnote 34

6 Robustness

This section addresses three potential robustness issues: potential sampling issues, the definition of the preference variables and the relationship to surveys similar to the GPS.

6.1 OECD subset

As mentioned before, economic preferences—and the experiments and questions by which they are measured—might be influenced by the economic situations of the subjects in question. Risk and patience specifically might be linked to the wealth and development path of the country in question beyond relationships covered by GDP per capita or institutional settings. If preferences are linked to economic characteristics, endogeneity could ensue through relationships between them and trade patterns and intensities. To control for this, a subset of all OECD countries also included in the GPS is used. The greater similarity of OECD countries in terms of wealth, institutional quality and societal organisation mitigates the endogeneity risks.Footnote 35 On the other hand, it also limits generality of results due to the smaller set of 25 members and in the case that preference distances between countries impact trade differently for less developed nations.Footnote 36

Comparing the gravity estimations for GPS and OECD countries, preference distances have stronger effects within the OECD than for the full GPS set—see Tables 18 and 19 in the Appendix for detailed results. Overall, the results also imply that preferences might matter more in situations where other issues such as strong discrepancies in economic development or the legal systems of the country pair are less relevant. The smaller effects for commonalities in the legal systems and the negative, but barely significant effects of differences in the quality of legal systems support this interpretation.

6.2 Alternative preference definitions

In addition to the unilateral preference levels and absolute distances between countries used in the main analysis, two alternative specifications have been tested: squared preference distances between countries and maximum preference values per pair. The results for the corresponding gravity equations, applied to goods category-specific exports, are displayed in Tables 22 and 23 of the Appendix. In the former case, the effects for bilateral distances in negative reciprocity remain similar, while distances in patience and positive reciprocity become significant (at higher confidence levels). Neither effect changes directions. These additional significances might be a venue for future research in that they could imply a non-linearity in the effect of distances.

In the maximum value cases, negative reciprocity is highly significant.Footnote 37 Risk and positive reciprocity remain significant at the 10%-level for differentiated goods. For negative reciprocity, a higher maximum value is associated with a decrease in trading volume. That is, the larger the distance, the smaller the trade volume, which is equivalent to the results from the main analysis. For risk and positive reciprocity, higher maximum values increase trading volumes. This likewise fits the overall positive effect for distances observed in the main analysis, thus supporting the risk transformation and negotiation mechanisms. Given the greater difficulty with disentangling effects, this specification is not used in the main analysis.Footnote 38

6.3 Relationship with similar surveys

While the GPS is unique in its combination of decision-relevant preferences and experimental validation, some of its contents have been analysed before. The World Values Survey (WVS) (Jaeggi et al. 2018) and the Hofstede Dimensions (Hofstede et al. 2010) report measures for some of the GPS preferences, which are used for robustness checks in this analysis. Additionally, Wacziarg’s genetic and religious distances (Spolaore and Wacziarg 2016, 2018) are used to ascertain their relationship with preferences, controlling for potential links between these traits and preferences. This follows the literature on ancient origins of cultural and societal traits.

World Values Survey The World Values Survey (WVS) is a global study designed to gather information on values and beliefs of different nations. It is a questionnaire containing items relating to the subject’s personal and professional life, their beliefs, culture and values, as well as questions on the perceptions of their society. The evaluation includes risk and time preferences, allowing direct comparison with the GPS. 57 countries of the GPS are also included in the WVS, 47 of them contain all of the items, providing a sufficiently large set for comparison on aggregate volumes. Bilateral distances for the WVS variables are drawn from Jaeggi et al. (2018).

The output table can be found in the Appendix as Table 24. Using mean distance in World Values Survey items instead of the aggregated distance in GPS preferences does not alter the result noted in Sect. 5.1. Both coefficients are non-significant. When replacing risk and time preferences with their WVS equivalents, WVS time preferences become significant at the 5% level. Risk does not, negative reciprocity remains significant. The discrepancy in risk and time preference significance might result from the reduced sample size, if the reduction is non-random. Depending on a person’s (or nation’s) material wealth, saving becomes easier and risk-aversion more logical given higher potential losses. This bias might also manifest differently depending on the phrasing of questions or the execution of experiments.

Hofstede Dimensions Geert Hofstede has modelled national culture as a six-dimensional model with the dimensions proposed as basic issues for societal organisation. These dimensions include long-term orientation and uncertainty avoidance, which correspond to patience and risk attitude in the GPS. Due to Hofstede’s calculation, only level effects can be analysed. For that purpose, first stage gravity equation without preference distances is estimated to avoid confounding.Footnote 39 The fixed effects of that estimation are analysed using the same specification as in Sect. 5.3, but with the Hofstede measures for patience and risk (see Table 25 of the Appendix). Of these, only patience is significant, while risk is not. However, the Hofstede sample encompasses only 44 countries instead of the GPS’ 72 and its indices are defined much more broadly in terms of values, morale and philosophy, further limiting their accuracy and comparability.

Genetic and Religious Distance Thirdly, the relationship between preferences and other persistent, long-term drivers of cultural characteristics has to be considered, specifically: common origins. To this end, measures for genetic and religious distance from Jaeggi et al. (2018) are used. Both aspects can be seen as persistent influences on developing characteristics of any nation’s population and their distance relates to the (in-)frequency of interaction between any two nations. If not the causes, they can still be used as proxies for shared history or origins. Table 26 of the Appendix shows the detailed results for weighted distances and an alternative definition of these distances using only the dominant genetic or religious “group” within each country. Neither measure affects coefficients or significance of GPS variables.

7 Conclusion

This analysis suggests that behavioural leanings can express themselves in trade outcomes and outlines mechanisms—term and risk optimisation on one hand and negotiation on the other—by which these outcomes manifest. In contrast to cultural distances, this relationship is not constrained to differences reducing trade. The effects of this mechanism are more pronounced and more robust for differentiated goods, which is reassuring as these goods are more negotiation- and specialisation-heavy than standardised or exchange-traded goods. They are also centered on the exporter, which aligns well with the prevalence of open account in trade finance, placing the risk primarily with the exporter.

Term and risk preferences appear to impact trade outcomes through transformation mechanisms. That is, investment, production and trade patterns are subject to different risks and amortization cycles. This prompts players to self-select into products suiting their own preferences in these matters, if given the chance—which can be provided by trade. These selections then lead to specializations, providing comparative and competitive advantage as well as further opportunity for trade. Consequently, countries with populations leaning towards risk-aversion and patience export more differentiated goods. This is reflective of the higher effort associated with establishing their production and the greater difficulty, for their partner, to change suppliers. Moreover, distances between countries in patience correspond to trading in more product categories, reflecting the growth in trading opportunities between differently specialized partners.

For reciprocity, the mechanisms depend not on preference leanings, but on bilateral differences. Distances between countries in negative reciprocity in particular adversely impact trade volumes. This supports the dual hypothesis that the punishment costs and risks associated with a more negatively reciprocal partner coerce a less negatively reciprocal partner towards limiting his exposure. Conversely, distances between countries in positive reciprocity weakly intensify trade relationships. Unexpected rewards or gifts for cooperative behaviour by the more positively reciprocal player would be appreciated by their partner, strengthening the relationship.

While we cannot speak of causal inference, term, risk and reciprocity attitudes present an intriguing approach towards explaining certain anomalies in trade flows and behaviours not covered by conventional theory. This approach joins the literature strands on trade, behavioural economics and contracts with one another, tying trade outcomes to the people deciding upon their design. At this intersection and following from our analysis, further research questions unfold, of which we want to address a few.

One question is that of the relationship between preferences and the duration of trade. Patience and positive reciprocity might well contribute to more persistent relationships, which could perhaps be investigated using a long-term panel of bilateral trade intensity. Risk and negative reciprocity, on the other hand, could diminish that persistence. Another question would be whether and how term and risk considerations would affect more disaggregated trade flows, since our results and specialization channel would postulate high and highly specific flows.

More technically, we have found signs for a potential non-linearity in the relationships between trade activity and preferences. Above a presumed threshold, the impact of national preferences and their bilateral distances might change, as is hinted at by the results for the OECD subset. For negative reciprocity, there are signs for a non-linearity relating not to the preferences but to the trade volume in question. Both of these anomalies could be interesting for further studies. At the same time, a decomposition of negative reciprocity into its different levels of manifestation—i.e. costly, but rational punishment vs. irrational revenge—would be interesting.

Lastly, we want to address policy implications. Preferences might define limits to the effects of infrastructure, institutions and political action, including trade agreements, on economic outcomes. At the same time, term and risk transformation could add another dimension to trade negotiations and the perspectives for judging their outcomes, as they provide a potential source for gains from trade. With regards to negative reciprocity and the risk of punishment, supranational mediators for trade disputes might be able to alleviate concerns of both sides by delegating punishment to a neutral and transparent court, increasing predictability of the process.