Advertisement

Intereconomics

, Volume 54, Issue 4, pp 228–232 | Cite as

Data Governance: Enhancing Innovation and Protecting Against Its Risks

  • Max von GrafensteinEmail author
  • Alina Wernick
  • Christopher Olk
Forum
  • 15 Downloads

Abtract

Big Data is expected to unleash data-driven innovation,which is supposed to better address and solve challengesin our society.

As a so-called non-rival good, the sharingand re-using of data by one actor does not diminish its valuefor other actors and can create significant spillover effects.

Data is still often stored in data silos. Releasing data fromsilos and sharing it may enhance social and economic welfare.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. 1.
    See V. Mayer-Schönberger, K. Cukier: Big Data: A Revolution that Will Transform How We Live, Work, and Think, New York 2013, Houghton Mifflin Harcourt Publishing Company, p. 30.Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    See M. Hilbert: Big Data for Development: A Review of Promises and Challenges, in: Development Policy Review, Vol. 34, No. 1, 2016, pp. 135–174, p. 142.Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    OECD: Data-Driven Innovation: Big Data for Growth and Well-Being, Paris 2015, OECD Publishing, p. 179.Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    See M. von Grafenstein, J. Holzel, F. Irgmeier, J. Pohle: Nudging: Regulierung durch Big Data und Verhaltenswissenschaften, Berlin 2018, ABIDA (Assessing Big Data), p. 46.Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    See A. Habenstein, S. D'Onofrio, E. Portmann, M. Sturmer, T. Myrach: Open Smart City: Good Governance fur smarte Stadte, in: A. Meier, E. Portmann (eds.):Smart City: Strategie, Governance und Projekte, Wiesbaden 2016, Springer Vieweg, pp. 47–71, p. 48.Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Regarding lock-in-effects, see E. Veronelli: Smart cities vs “locked- in” cities, CORDIS EU research results, 12 September 2016, available at https://cordis.europa.eu/news/rcn/135237/en.Google Scholar
  7. 7.
    Regarding smart cities and surveillance, see T. Wadhwa: Smart Cities: Toward the Surveillance Society?, in: D. Araya (ed.): Smart Cities as Democratic Ecologies, New York 2015, Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 125–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. 8.
    See W. Hoffmann-Riem, S. Fritzsche: Innovationsverantwor- tung - zur Einleitung, in: M. Eifert, W. Hoffmann-Riem (eds.): Innovation und Recht III - Innovationsverantwortung, Berlin 2009, Duncker & Humblot, p. 16.Google Scholar
  9. 9.
    See for example the smart city project in Toronto: J. Wakefield:The Google city that has angered Toronto, BBC News, 18 May 2019.Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    Regarding biomedical data, see J. L. Contreras: Leviathan in the Commons: Biomedical Data and the State, in: K.J. Strandburg, B.M. Frischmann, M.J. Madison (eds.): Governing Medical Knowledge Commons, Cambridge 2017, Cambridge University Press, pp. 19–45.Google Scholar
  11. 11.
    See, regarding the perspective of the legal regulator, A. Vofßkuhle: Neue Verwaltungsrechtswissenschaft, in: W. Hoffmann-Riem, E. Schmidt-Aßmann.A. Voßkuhle (eds.): Grundlagen des Verwal- tungsrechts - Band I: Methoden - Maßstäbe - Aufgaben - Organisation, 2nd edition, Munich 2012, C.H. Beck, cip. 20; and regarding the governance perspective, J. Hofmann, C. Katzenbach, K. Golatz: Between coordination and regulation: Finding the governance in Internet governance, in: New Media & Society, Vol. 19, No. 9, 2017, pp. 1406–1423.Google Scholar
  12. 12.
    See, regarding regulation by the state: A. VofSkuhle, op. cit.; and regarding regulation by private companies: J. Black: Decentring regulation: Understanding the role of regulation and selfregulation in a “post-regulatory” world, in: Current legal problems, Vol. 54, No. 1, 2001, pp.103–146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. 12a.
    see the term “private ordering” at Elkin-Koren who defines the term as a situation wherein “the rule-making process regarding the use of information is privatized, and the legal power to define the boundaries of public access to information is delegated to private parties.” N. Elkin-Koren: A Public-Regarding Approach to Contracting over Copyrights, in: R. Dreyfuss, H. First, D. Zimmerman (eds): Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property: hnovation Policy for the Knowledge Society, Oxford 2001, Oxford University Press, pp. 191Google Scholar
  14. 12b.
    192 as cited by S. Dusollier: Sharing Access to Intellectual Property through Private Ordering, in: Chicago-Kent Law Review, Vol. 82, 2007, pp. 1391, 1393, fn. 8Google Scholar
  15. 12c.
    see S. Schwarcz: Private ordering, in: Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 97, No. 1, 2002, p. 319.Google Scholar
  16. 13.
    Regarding the privacy paradox, see for example G. Müller, C. Flender, M. Peters: Vertrauensinfrastruktur und Privatheit als ökonomische Fragestellung, in:J.Buchmann (ed.): Internet Privacy: Eine multidisziplinäre Bestandsaufnahme, Heidelberg 2012, Springer Vieweg, pp. 143–188, p. 175.Google Scholar
  17. 14.
    See H. Richter, P. R. Slowinski: The Data Sharing Economy: On the Emergence of New Intermediaries, in: IIC-lnternational Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, Vol. 50, No. 1, 2019, pp. 4–29, p. 7, fn 15, discussing the risk of liability of breaching data protection law.Google Scholar
  18. 15.
    Regarding coopetition, see D.R. Gnyawali, R. Madhavan, J. He, M. Bengtsson: The competitioncooperation paradox in inter-firm relationships: A conceptual framework, in: Industrial Marketing Man- agement, Vol. 53, 2016, pp. 7–18; sometimes, the data donor also overestimates the value of its data due to an endowment effectGoogle Scholar
  19. 15a.
    see D. Kahneman, J. Knetsch, R. Thaler: Anomalies: The Endow- ment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias, in: Journal of Eco- nomic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1, 1991, pp. 193–206.Google Scholar
  20. 16.
    Regarding transaction costs in law in general, see R.H. Coase: The problem of social cost, in: The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 111, 1960, pp. 1–44.Google Scholar
  21. 16a.
    Bounded rationality, such as unwarranted fear of failing to comply with data protection law, may also contribute to the reluctance to share data, see, for example H.A. Simon: Bounded rationality and organizational learning, in: Organization science, Vol. 2, No. 1, 1991, pp. 125–134.Google Scholar
  22. 16b.
    Finally, excessive transaction costs may lead to a socalled tragedy of the anti-commons, see M.A. Heler: The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the transition from Marx to markets, in: Harvard Law Review, Vol. 111, No. 3, 1998, pp. 621–688Google Scholar
  23. 16c.
    and regarding patents, M.A. Heller, R.S. Eisenberg: Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research, in: Science, Vol. 280, No. 5364, 1998, pp. 698–701.Google Scholar
  24. 17.
    See similar reasons mentioned by V. Kathuria: Greed for data and exclusionary conduct in data-driven markets, in: Computer law & security review, Vol. 35, No. 1, 2019, pp. 89–102.Google Scholar
  25. 18.
    See M. von Grafenstein: The Principle of Purpose Limitation in Data Protection Laws, Baden-Baden 2018, Nomos, p. 77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. 19.
    Regarding decision heuristics, see S. Mousavi, G. Gigerenzer: Risk, uncertainty, and heuristics, in: Journal of Business Research, Vol. 67, No. 8, 2014, pp. 1671–1678.Google Scholar
  27. 20.
    See M. Olson: Collective action, in: S.N. Durlauf, L.E. Blume:The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edition, London 2008, Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 876–880.Google Scholar
  28. 21.
    Regarding the rationale of Art. 20 GDPR, see for example T. Jülicher, C. Rottgen, M. von Schönfeld: Das Recht auf Datenubertragbarkeit: Ein datenschutzrechtliches Novum, in: Zeitschrift für Dat- enschutz, Vol. 6, No. 8, 2016, pp. 358–362.Google Scholar
  29. 22.
    R. H. Weber: Improvement of Data Economy Through Compulsory Licences?, in:S. Lohsse, R. Schulze, D. Staudenmayer: Trading Data in the Digital Economy: Legal Concepts and Tools, Baden-Baden 2017, Nomos.p. 151.Google Scholar
  30. 23.
    See, for example, M. Grützmacher: Dateneigentumein Flickenteppich, in: Computer und Recht, Vol. 32, No. 8, 2016, pp. 485–495Google Scholar
  31. 23a.
    N. Härting: “Dateneigentum” -Schutz durch Immaterialgüter- recht?, in: Computer und Recht, Vol. 32, No. 10, 2016, pp. 646–649; N. Jentzsch: Dateneigentum - Eine gute Idee für die Datenokönomie, Berlin 2018, Think Tank für die Gesellschaft in technologischen Wan- del, available at https://www.stiftung-nv.de/sites/default/files/nicola_jentzsch_dateneigentum.pdf}.Google Scholar
  32. 24.
    See H. Richter, R.M. Hilty: Die Hydra des Dateneigentums - eine methodische Betrachtung, Discussion Paper No. 12, Munich 2018, Max-Planck-Institut für Innovation und Wettbewerb, in: Stiftung Dat- enschutz (ed.): Dateneigentum und Datenhandel, Schriftenreihe Daten Debatten, Vol. 3, Berlin 2018, Erich Schmidt Verlag, pp. 241–259.Google Scholar
  33. 25.
    Regarding this last aspect, see again, ibid., p. 15.Google Scholar
  34. 26.
    See A. Nahles: Digitaler Fortschritt durch ein Daten-für-Alle-Gesetz, Positionspapier der Parteivorsitzenden der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, Berlin 2019, available at https://www.spd.de/aktuelles/daten-fuer-alle-gesetz/}Google Scholar
  35. 27.
    See T. Ramge, V. Mayer-Schonberger: Das Digital: Markt, Wertschöpfung und Gerechtigkeit im Datenkapitalismus, 3rd edition. Berlin 2017, Ullstein.Google Scholar
  36. 28.
    Information on the project “Privacy by design in smart cities” available at https://www.hiig.de/en/project/privacy-by-design-in-smart-cities/Google Scholar
  37. 29.
    Alexander von Humboldt Institute for Internet and Society: Data Protection by Design in Smart Cities, HUG Discussion Paper, forthcoming, available at https://www.hiig.de
  38. 30.
    For more on “reasonable expectations”, see Article 29 Data Protection Working Party: Opinion 06/2014 on the notion of legitimate in- terests of the data controller under Article 7 of Directive 95/46/EC, 2014, p. 51; regarding risk expectations, see Art. 35 (9) GDPR: “Where appropriate, the controller shall seek the views of data subjects or their representatives on the intended processing, without prejudice to the protection of commercial or public interests or the security of processing operations.”Google Scholar
  39. 31.
    See N. Purtova: The law of everything. Broad concept of persona data and future of EU data protection law, in: Law, Innovation and Technology, Vol. 10, No. 1, 2018, pp. 40–81.Google Scholar
  40. 32.
    See also W. Kerber: Digital markets, data, and privacy: competition law, consumer law and data protection, in: Journal of Intellectual Property Law & Practice, Vol. 11, No. 11, 2016, pp. 856–866.Google Scholar
  41. 33.
    M.A. Heller: The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the transition from Marx to markets, in: Harvard Law Review, Vol. 111, No. 3, 1998, pp. 621–688Google Scholar
  42. 33a.
    M.A. Heller, R.S. Eisenberg: Can patents deter nnovation? The anticommons in biomedical research, in: Science, Vol. 280, No.5364, 1998, pp. 698–701Google Scholar
  43. 33b.
    R.P. Merges: Contracting into liability rules: Intellectual property rights and collective rights organi- zations, in: California Law Review, Vol.84, No.5, 1996, pp. 1293–1393Google Scholar
  44. 33c.
    M.J. Barnett: The anti-commons revisited, in: Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, Vol.29, No. 1, 2015, pp. 127–203.Google Scholar
  45. 34.
    A. Acquisti, C. Taylor, L. Wagman: The economics of privacy, in: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 54, No. 2, 2016, pp. 442–92.Google Scholar
  46. 35.
    M.E. Stucke, A.P. Grunes: Big data and competition policy, Oxford 2016, Oxford University Press; N. Srnicek: Platform Capitalism, London 2017, PolityGoogle Scholar
  47. 35a.
    V. Kathuria: Greed for data and exclusionary conduct in data-driven markets, in: Computer law & security review, Vol.35, No. 1, 2019, pp. 89–102.Google Scholar
  48. 36.
    H.W. Chesbrough: Open innovation: The new imperative for cre- ating and profiting from technology, Boston 2006, Harvard Business School PressGoogle Scholar
  49. 36a.
    E. von Hippel: Democratizing innovation: The evolv- ng phenomenon of user innovation, in: Journal für Betriebswirtschaft, Vol. 55, No. 1, 2005, pp. 63–78Google Scholar
  50. 35b.
    E. von Hippel, G. von Krogh: Open source software and the “privatecollective” innovation model: Issues for organization science, in: Organization Science, Vol. 14, No. 2, 2003, pp. 209–223.Google Scholar
  51. 37.
    R.B. Bouncken, J. Gast, S. Kraus, M. Bogers: Coopetition: a systematic review, synthesis, and future research directions, in: Review of Managerial Science, Vol. 9, No. 3, 2015, pp. 577–601.Google Scholar
  52. 38.
    See, for example, G. van Overwalle, E. van Zimmeren, B. Verbeure, G. Matthijs: Models for facilitating access to patents on ge- netic inventions, in: Nature Reviews Genetics, Vol. 7, No. 2, 2006, pp. 143–148Google Scholar
  53. 38a.
    M. Mattioli: The data-pooling problem, in: Berkeley Tech- nology Law Journal, Vol. 32, No. 1, 2017, pp. 179–236Google Scholar
  54. 38b.
    B. Lundqvist: Competition and data pools, in: Journal of European Consumer and Market Law, Vol. 7, No. 4, 2018, pp. 146–154Google Scholar
  55. 38c.
    M. Finck: Blockchains and theGDPR, in: European Data Protection Law Review, Vol. 4, 2018, pp. 17–35Google Scholar
  56. 38d.
    H. Richter, P.R. Slowinski: The Data Sharing Economy: On the Emergence of New Intermediaries, in: HC-International Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, Vol. 50, No. 1, 2019, pp. 4–29.Google Scholar
  57. 39.
    See the proposed terminology and a first categorisation of interorganisational data governance models in Alexander von Humboldt Institute for Internet and Society: Data Governance: Towards a Conceptual Framework, HUG Discussion Paper, forthcoming, available at http://www.hiig.de/paper-Data-Governance-Towards-Conceptual-Framework/

Copyright information

© ZBW and Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Max von Grafenstein
    • 1
    Email author
  • Alina Wernick
    • 1
  • Christopher Olk
    • 1
  1. 1.Institute for Internet and SocietyAlexander von HumboldtBerlinGermany

Personalised recommendations