Advertisement

Poiesis & Praxis

, Volume 4, Issue 1, pp 54–73 | Cite as

The institutionalization of Open Source

  • R.A. Gehring
Focus

Abstract

Using concepts of neoinstitutional economics, such as transaction cost economics, institutional economics, property rights theory, and information economics, the development of the Open Source movement is investigated. Following the evolution of institutions in Open Source, it is discussed what the comparative institutional advantages of this model are. The conclusion is that it is the institutional framework of Open Source, not merely the low cost of Open Source software that makes it an attractive alternative mode of organizing the production and distribution of software and software-related services. Alternative organizations will be formed and existing organizations will be transformed to take advantage of its opportunities.

Keywords

Transaction Cost Intellectual Property Open Source Open Source Software Institutional Framework 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Zusammenfassung

Unter Rückgriff auf Konzepte der neuen Institutionenökonomik—Transaktionskosten, Institutionen, Eigentumsrechte und Informationsökonomik—wird die Entstehung der Open-Source-Bewegung untersucht. Die Herausbildung von Institutionen innerhalb der Open-Source-Bewegung wird hinsichtlich der dadurch induzierten komparativen Vorteile diskutiert. Es wird geschlussfolgert, dass nicht singuläre Faktoren wie etwa der niedrige Preis von Open-Source-Software für die Akzeptanz dieses Modelles ausschlaggebend sind. Vielmehr ist es die Gesamtheit der institutionellen Rahmenbedingungen, die Open Source als alternatives Modell für die Produktion und Distribution von Software attraktiv machen. Es ist davon auszugehen, dass unter Verwendung dieses Modells alternative Organisationen zur Softwareproduktion entstehen werden bzw. bestehende Organisationen sich transformieren.

References

  1. Albin ST (2003) The art of software architecture: design methods and techniques. Wiley, IndianapolisGoogle Scholar
  2. Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1973) The property rights paradigm. J Econ Hist 33(1):16–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. anon. (2003) Open source software: Microsoft at the power point. The Economist. http://www.economist.com/business/displayStory.cfm?story_id=2054746 11 Sept 2003
  4. anon. (2005) Norwegian minister: proprietary formats no longer acceptable in communication with government. Tatle. http://www.andwest.com/blojsom/blog/tatle/agenda/2005/06/27/Norwegian_Minister_Proprietary_Standards_No_Longer_Acceptable_in_Communication_with_Government.html 27 June 2005
  5. Ashurst M (2004) Brazil falls in love with Linux. BBC News. http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/3445805.stm 01 Feb 2004
  6. Bar M, Fogel K (2003) Open Source development with CVS, 3rd edn. Paraglyph Press, ScottsdaleGoogle Scholar
  7. Benkler Y (2002) Coase’s Penguin or Linux and the nature of the firm. Yale Law J 112(3):369–446CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Besen SM (1987) New technologies and intellectual property: an economic analysis. RAND Note, Santa MonicaGoogle Scholar
  9. Carlton DW, Perloff JF (2000) Modern industrial organization, 3rd edn. Addison-Wesley, ReadingGoogle Scholar
  10. Carr NG (2005) The end of corporate computing. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 46(3):67–73Google Scholar
  11. Castells M (2001) Das Informationszeitalter I: Die Netzwerkgesellschaft. Leske + Budrich, OpladenGoogle Scholar
  12. Chesbrough HW (2003) The era of open innovation. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 44(3):45-41Google Scholar
  13. Clapes AL (1993) Softwars: the legal battles for control of the global software industry. Quorum Books, WestportGoogle Scholar
  14. Coase RH (ed) (1988a) The firm. The market. And the law. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, LondonGoogle Scholar
  15. Coase RH (1988b) The lighthouse in economics. In: Coase RH (ed) The firm. The market. And the law, chapter 7, pages 187–213. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London. Reprinted from The Journal of Law and Economics 17 no. 2 (October1974):357–376Google Scholar
  16. Coase RH (1988c) The nature of the firm. In: Coase RH (ed) The firm. The market. And the law, Chapter 2, Pages 33–35. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, London. Reprinted from Economica 4 (November 1937)Google Scholar
  17. Cooter R, Ulen T (2004) Law & economics, 4th edn. Pearson Addison Wesley, BostonGoogle Scholar
  18. David PA, Steinmueller WE (1994) Economics of compatibility standards and competition in telecommunication networks. Inf Econ Policy 6(3–4):217–241CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Demsetz H (1969) Information and efficiency: another viewpoint. J Law Econ 12(1):1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. DiBona C, Ockman S, Stone M (1999) Open Sources: voices from the Open Source revolution. O’Reilly, SebastopolGoogle Scholar
  21. Dunwoodie B (2005) The state of the server market. cmswire. http://www.cmswire.com/cms/industry-news/the-state-of-the-server-market-000599.php 07 June 2005Google Scholar
  22. Ebinger T (2005) Tragen die Juristen Open-Source-Software zu Grabe? In: Lutterbeck et al. (eds) Die GNU GPL vor Gericht, chapter 4. pp 249–269Google Scholar
  23. Eggertsson T (1990) Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Feller J, Fitzgerald B (2002) Understanding Open Source software development. Addison-Wesley/Pearson, LondonGoogle Scholar
  25. Foray D (2004) The economics of knowledge. The MIT Press, Cambridge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  26. Franke N, von Hippel E (2003) Satisfying heterogeneous user needs via innovation toolkits: the case of Apache security software. Res Policy 32(7):1199–1215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Freeman C, Louçã F (2002) As time goes by: from the industrial revolution to the information revolution, 1st paperback edition. Oxford University Press, Oxford, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Frey BS, Jegen R (2000) Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical evidence (revised version). Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper No. 49Google Scholar
  29. Garner BA (1999) A handbook of business law terms. West Group, St. PaulGoogle Scholar
  30. Grad B (2002) A personal recollection: IBM’s unbundling of software and services. IEEE Annal Hist Comput 24(1):64–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Sci Mag 162:1243–1248Google Scholar
  32. Himanen P (2001) The Hacker ethic. A radical approach to the philosophy of business. Random House, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  33. von Hippel E (2001) Innovation by user communities: learning from open-source software. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 42(4):82–86Google Scholar
  34. von Hippel E (2005a) Anwender-Innovationsnetzwerke: Hersteller entbehrlich. In: Lutterbeck et al (eds), chapter 7, pp 449–461Google Scholar
  35. von Hippel E (2005b) Democratizing innovation. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  36. Hohmann L (2003) Beyond software architecture: creating and sustaining winning solutions. Addison-Wesley, BostonGoogle Scholar
  37. Homann K, Suchanek A (2000) Ökonomik: Eine Einführung. Mohr Siebeck, TübingenGoogle Scholar
  38. Jaeger T, Metzger A (2002) Open Source Software: Rechtliche Rahmenbedingungen der Freien Software. C.H. Beck, MünchenGoogle Scholar
  39. Kesan JP, Shah RC (2002) Shaping code. http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=328920 Sept 2002
  40. Kooths S, Langenfurth M, Kalwey N (2003) Open source-software: an economic assessment, vol 4. MICE Economic Research Studies. http://mice.uni-muenster.de/mers/ Dec 2003
  41. Kuchinskas S (2005) Study: cost not only open source driver. Internet News. http://www.internetnews.com/stats/article.php/3520066 14 July 2005Google Scholar
  42. Landes WM, Posner RA (2003) The economic structure of intellectual property law. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  43. Lessig L (1999) Code and other laws of cyberspace. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  44. Lessig L (2001) The future of ideas: the fate of the commons in a connected world. Random House, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  45. Levy S (2001) Hackers. Heroes of the computer revolution. Penguin Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  46. Libecap GD (1998) Common property. In: Newman P (ed) The new Palgrave dictionary of economics and the law (vol I–III), vol 1. MacMillan Reference Limited, London, vol I, A–D. pp 317–323Google Scholar
  47. Litman J (2001) Digital copyright. Prometheus Books, AmherstGoogle Scholar
  48. Lohr S (2001) Go to: the story of the math majors, bridge players, engineers, chess wizards, maverick scientists and iconoclasts—the programmers who created the software revolution. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  49. Lutterbeck B, Gehring RA, Bärwolff M (eds) (2005) Open Source Jahrbuch 2005. Lehmanns Media, BerlinGoogle Scholar
  50. McCormack A (2001) Product-development practices that work: how internet companies build software. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 42(2):75–84Google Scholar
  51. Moody G (2001) Rebel code: inside Linux and the Open Source revolution. Perseus Publishing, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  52. National Commission on New Technological Uses of Copyrighted Works (ed) (1979) Final report of the National Commission on New Technological Uses of Copyrighted Works (July 31, 1978). Library of Congress, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  53. Nelson TH (1974) Computer lib/Dream machines. Hugo’s Book Service, Chicago. Revised and updated edition reprinted by Microsoft (1987)Google Scholar
  54. Noronha F (2003) Free software carnival: Latin america takes to FLOSS in a big way. Linux Journal. http://www.linuxjournal.com/article.php?sid=6915 02 June 2003Google Scholar
  55. North DC (1981) Structure and change in economic history. W.W. Norton, New York, LondonGoogle Scholar
  56. North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. OECD (ed) (1985) Software: an emerging industry, volume 9 of Information computer communications policy. OECD, ParisGoogle Scholar
  58. OECD (ed) (1996) Information technology outlook 1995. Information computer communications policy. OECD, ParisGoogle Scholar
  59. OECD (2002) OECD information technology outlook highlights. OECD Publications ServiceGoogle Scholar
  60. Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  61. Osterloh M, Frey BS (2000) Motivation, knowledge transfer, and organizational form. Org Sci 11(5):538–550CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Perens B (1999) The open source definition. In: DiBona et al (eds), pp 171–182Google Scholar
  64. Pool R (1997) Beyond engineering: how society shapes technology. Oxford University Press, New York, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  65. Reidenberg JR (1998) Lex informatica: the formulation of information policy rules through technology. Texas Law Rev 76(3):553–593Google Scholar
  66. Salus PH (1995) A quarter century of UNIX. Addison-Wesley, reprinted and corrected editionGoogle Scholar
  67. Salvatore D (2003) Microeconomics: theory and applications, 4th edn. Oxford University Press, New York, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  68. Samuelson P, Scotchmer S (2002) The law and economics of reverse engineering. Yale Law J 111(7):1575–1663CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Saxenian A (1994) Regional advantage: culture and competition in Silican Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  70. Shapiro C, Varian HR (1999) Information rules. A strategic guide to the network economy. Harvard Business School Press, BostonGoogle Scholar
  71. Stack M, Gartland MP (2003) Path creation, path dependency, and alternative theories of the firm. J Econ Issues (JEI) 37(2):487–494CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Stallman R (1999) The GNU operating system and the free software movement. In: DiBona et al (eds), pp 53–70Google Scholar
  73. Stobbs GA (2000) Software Patents, 2nd edn. Aspen Publishers, Gaithersburg, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  74. Thomas D, Hunt A (2004) Open source ecosystems. IEEE Software 21(4):89–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Torvalds L, Diamond D (2001) Just for FUN—the story of an accidental revolutionary. HarperCollins Publishers, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  76. Wall L (1999) Diligence, patience, and humility. In: DiBona et al (eds) pp 127–147Google Scholar
  77. Weber S (2004) The success of Open Source. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  78. Williamson OE (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. The Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  79. Worthington D (2005) IBM turns to open source development. BetaNews. http://www.betanews.com/article/IBM_Turns_to_Open_Source_Development/1118688437/1 13 June 2005Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Informatik und GesellschaftTechnische Universität BerlinBerlinGermany

Personalised recommendations