Advertisement

Economics of Governance

, Volume 20, Issue 1, pp 73–101 | Cite as

The state economic modernity index: an index of state building, state size and scope, and state economic power

  • Ryan H. MurphyEmail author
Original Paper

Abstract

One line of thought in development economics and political science emphasizes the need for state building to achieve economic growth and better outcomes throughout the developing world. Conventionally, this has been conceptualized in terms of “state capacity,” sometimes operationalized via the Worldwide Governance Indicators report. This paper proposes a simple alternative, using two of the five components of the Economic Freedom of the World report, with a greater emphasis placed on state power within an economy, as opposed to its capacity. This alternative measure, here called the “State Economic Modernity” index (SEM) is a combination of various measures of a state’s willingness and ability to perform its core public goods functions, and the state’s size relative to the economy. It is shown that the SEM index, in combination with the Economic Freedom of the World report, creates intuitive categorizations of economic institutions across countries. The SEM index is shown to relate to various measures of social capital and may be determined by them. Finally, while the SEM index is closely related to economic growth and output as seen in raw correlations, it appears to cause neither upon the inclusion of country fixed effects.

Keywords

State building State capacity Economic freedom Economic institutions Governance Social capital 

JEL Classification

O43 H10 

Notes

References

  1. Acemoglu D (2003) The form of property rights: oligarchic vs. democratic societies. NBER working paper no. 10037Google Scholar
  2. Acemoglu D (2005) Politics and economics in weak and strong states. J Monet Econ 52:1199–1226Google Scholar
  3. Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2005) Unbundling institutions. J Political Econ 113(5):949–995Google Scholar
  4. Adler PS, Kwon S-W (2000) Social capital: the good, the bad, and the ugly. In: Lesser EL (ed) Knowledge and social capital: foundations and applications. Butterworth-Heineman, Woburn, pp 89–115Google Scholar
  5. Adler PS, Kwon S-W (2002) Social capital: prospects for a new concept. Acad Manag Rev 27(1):17–40Google Scholar
  6. Andrews M, Pritchett L, Woolcock M (2017) Building state capacity: evidence, analysis, and action. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  7. Baier S, Dwyer G, Tamura R (2006) How important are capital and total factor productivity for economic growth. Econ Inq 44(1):23–49Google Scholar
  8. Barro R, Lee JW (2013) A new data set on educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. J Dev Econ 104:184–198Google Scholar
  9. Berggren N, Bjornskov C (2017) The market-promoting and market-preserving roles of social trust in reforms of policies and institutions. South Econ J 84(1):3–25Google Scholar
  10. Berggren N, Jordahl H (2006) Free to trust: economic freedom and social capital. Kyklos 59(2):141–169Google Scholar
  11. Bergh A, Bjornskov C (2011) Historical trust levels predict the current size of the welfare state. Kyklos 64(1):1–19Google Scholar
  12. Besley T, Ghatak M (2010) Property rights and economic development. In: Rodrik D, Rosenzweig M (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 5. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 4525–4595Google Scholar
  13. Besley T, Persson T (2009) The origins of state capacity: property rights, taxation, and politics. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1218–1244Google Scholar
  14. Besley T, Persson T (2010) State capacity, conflict, and development. Econometrica 78(1):1–34Google Scholar
  15. Besley T, Persson T (2013) Taxation and development. In: Auerbach AJ, Chetty R, Feldstein M, Saez E (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 5. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 51–110Google Scholar
  16. Bjornskov C (2010) How does social trust lead to better governance? An attempt to separate electoral and bureaucratic mechanisms. Public Choice 144(1–2):323–346Google Scholar
  17. Borjas G (2015) Immigration and globalization: a review essay. J Econ Lit 53(4):961–974Google Scholar
  18. Buchanan JM (1975) The limits of liberty: between anarchy and Leviathan. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  19. Burakova L, Lawson R (2014) Georgia’s Rose revolution: how one country beat the odds, transformed its economy, and provided a model for reformers everywhere. The Antigua Forum, GuatemalaGoogle Scholar
  20. Clark JR, Lawson R, Nowrasteh A, Powell B, Murphy RH (2015) Does immigration impact institutions? Public Choice 163(3–4):321–334Google Scholar
  21. De Soto H (2000) The mystery of capital: why capitalism succeeds in the west and fails everywhere else. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  22. Dinecco M, Prado M (2012) Warfare, fiscal capacity, and performance. J Econ Growth 17:171–203Google Scholar
  23. Easterly W (2014) The tyranny of experts: economists, dictators, and the forgotten rights of the poor. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  24. Elster J (1989) The cement of society: a survey of social order. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  25. Fike R (2016) Gender disparity in legal rights and its effect on economic freedom. In: Gwartney J, Lawson R, Hall J (eds) Economic freedom of the world: 2016 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver, pp 189–211Google Scholar
  26. Fukuyama F (1996) Trust: the social virtues and the creation of prosperity. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  27. Fukuyama F (2004) State building: governance and world order in the 21st century. Cornell University Press, IthacaGoogle Scholar
  28. Fukuyama F (2011) The origins of political order. Farrar, Straus and Giroux, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  29. Fukuyama F (2014) Political order and political decay. Farrar, Straus and Giroux, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  30. Gennaioli N, Voth H-J (2015) State capacity and military conflict. Rev Econ Stud 82(4):1409–1448Google Scholar
  31. Glaeser EL, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2004) Do institutions cause growth? J Econ Growth 2004(9):271–303Google Scholar
  32. Gwartney J (2009) Institutions, economic freedom, and cross-country differences in performance. South Econ J 75(4):937–956Google Scholar
  33. Gwartney J, Lawson R, Hall J (2017) Economic freedom of the world. Fraser Institute, VancouverGoogle Scholar
  34. Haan D, Jakob SL, Sturm J-E (2006) Market-oriented institutions and policies and economic growth: a critical survey. J Econ Surv 20(2):157–191Google Scholar
  35. Hall J, Lawson R (2014) economic freedom of the world: an accounting of the literature. Contemp Econ Policy 32(1):1–19Google Scholar
  36. Herbst JI (2000) States and power in Africa: comparative lessons in authority and control. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  37. Huskinson T, Lawson R (2014) Clusters of economic freedom. Appl Econ Lett 21(15):1070–1074Google Scholar
  38. Jackson J (2017) Economic freedom and social capital: pooled mean group evidence. Appl Econ Lett 24(6):370–373Google Scholar
  39. Jackson J, Carden A, Compton R (2015) Economic freedom and social capital. Appl Econ 47(54):5853–5867Google Scholar
  40. Jones G (2016) Do immigrants import their economic destiny?” Evonomics. http://evonomics.com/do-immigrants-import-their-economic-destiny-garrett-jones/. Accessed 28 July 2017
  41. Kaufmann D, Kraay A, Mastruzzi M (2009) Governance matters VIII: aggregate and individual governance indicators 1996–2008. World Bank Policy Research working paper no. 4978Google Scholar
  42. Kaufmann D, Kraay A, Mastruzzi M (2010) The worldwide governance indicators: methodological and analytical issues. Global Economy and Development at Brookings. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/09_wgi_kaufmann.pdf. Accessed 11 Nov 2017
  43. Lawson R, Murphy RH (2015) Measuring institutions and policies across countries. In: Cebula R, Hall JC, Mixon FG, Payne JE (eds) Economic behavior, economic freedom, and entrepreneurship. Edward Elgar Publishing, NorthamptonGoogle Scholar
  44. Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Q J Econ 107:407–437Google Scholar
  45. Marshall MG, Gurr TR, Jaggers K (2016) Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions 1800–2015. Center for Systemic Peace, ViennaGoogle Scholar
  46. Migdal J (1988) Strong societies and weak states: state-society relations and state capabilities in the third world. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  47. Murphy RH (2018) The perils of buying social capital locally. J Priv Enterp 33(2):67–81Google Scholar
  48. North DC, Wallis JJ, Weingast BR (2009) Violence and social orders: a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded history. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  49. Ott J (2018) Measuring economic freedom: better without size of government. Soc Indic Res 135(2):479–498Google Scholar
  50. Putnam RD, Leonardi R, Nanetti RY (1993) Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  51. Rajagopalan S, Tabarrok A (2014) Lessons from Gurgaon, India’s private city. In: Andersson DE, Moroni S (eds) Cities and private planning: property rights, entrepreneurship, and transaction costs. Edward Elgar, Northampton, pp 199–231Google Scholar
  52. Ruhland JH (2016) The impact of social trust and system support on economic freedom. Working paper. https://www.depts.ttu.edu/freemarketinstitute/research/templeton_papers/TheImpactofSocialTrustandSystemSupportonEconomicFreedom.pdf. Accessed 25 July 2017
  53. Sala-I-Martin XX (1997) I just ran two million regressions. Am Econ Rev 87(2):178–183Google Scholar
  54. Stringham E (2015) Private governance: creating order in economic and social life. Oxford University Press, UKGoogle Scholar
  55. Sumner S (2010) The Great Danes: cultural values and neoliberal reforms. Working paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1629940. Accessed 5 Sep 2017
  56. Szreter S, Woodcock M (2004) Health by association? social capital, social theory, and the political economy of public health. Int J Epidemiol 33(4):650–667Google Scholar
  57. Tabellini G (2010) Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe. J Eur Econ Assoc 8(4):677–716Google Scholar
  58. Tilly C (1990) Coercion, capital, and European States, AD 990–1992. Blackwell, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  59. Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit 38:595–613Google Scholar
  60. Williamson CR (2009) Informal institutions rule: institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice 139(3):371–387Google Scholar
  61. Williamson CR, Kerekes CD (2011) Securing Private property: formal versus informal institutions. J Law Econ 54(3):537–572Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.The O’Neil Center for Global Markets and Freedom, SMU Cox School of BusinessSouthern Methodist UniversityDallasUSA

Personalised recommendations