Advertisement

Journal of Economics

, Volume 94, Issue 2, pp 105–124 | Cite as

Why is the public sector more labor-intensive? A distortionary tax argument

  • Panu Poutvaara
  • Andreas WagenerEmail author
Article

Abstract

Government-run entities are often more labor-intensive than private companies, even with identical production technologies. This need not imply slack in the public sector, but may reflect a wage tax advantage, stemming from the fact that government entities (partly) pay their taxes to themselves. A tax-induced cost advantage of public production precludes production efficiency and reduces welfare when labor supply is inelastic. With an elastic labor supply, a wage tax advantage of the public sector may improve welfare if it allows for a higher net wage.

Keywords

Public sector Labor intensity Taxation 

JEL Classification

L33 J45 D24 H21 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Alesina A, Baqir R, Easterly W (2000) Redistributive public employment. J Urban Econ 48: 219–241CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Atkinson SE, Halvorsen R (1986) The relative efficiency of public and private firms in a regulated environment: the case of U.S. electric utilities. J Public Econ 29: 281–294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Borjas GJ (2004) Labor economics, 3rd edn. McGraw-Hill, BostonGoogle Scholar
  4. Cardona F (2002) Scope of civil services in European countries. OECD, Paris. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/331850438.pdf
  5. Corneo G, Rob R (2003) Working in public and private firms. J Public Econ 87: 1335–1352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Dasgupta P, Siglitz J (1972) On optimal taxation and public production. Rev Econ Stud 39: 87–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. De Fraja G (1993) Productive efficiency in public and private firms. J Public Econ 50: 15–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Dewenter KL, Malatesta PH (2001) State-owned and privately-owned firms: an empirical analysis of profitability, leverage, and labor intensity. Am Econ Rev 91: 320–334CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Diamond P, Mirrlees J (1971) Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. Am Econ Rev 61: 8–27Google Scholar
  10. European Commission (2006) Structures of the taxation systems in the European Union: 1995–2004. Document TAXUD/E4/2006/DOC/3201. European Commission, Directorate-General for Taxation and Customs Union, BrusselsGoogle Scholar
  11. Felipe J, Fisher FM (2003) Aggregation in production functions: what applied economists should know. Metroeconomica 54: 208–262CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Genser B, Schindler D (2007) Dual income taxation as a stepping-stone towards a European corporate income tax. Intereconomics May/June 2007:132–138Google Scholar
  13. Gordon RH (2003) Taxes and privatization. In: Cnossen S, Sinn H-W (eds) Public finance and public policy in the new century. The MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 185–211Google Scholar
  14. Gordon RH, Bai C-E, Li DD (1999) Efficiency losses from tax distortions vs government control. Eur Econ Rev 43: 1095–1113CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Huizinga HP, Nielsen SB (2001) Privatization, public investment, and capital income taxation. J Public Econ 82: 399–414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kotsogiannis C, Makris M (2002) On production efficiency in federal systems. Econ Lett 76: 281–287CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. La Porta R, Lòpez-de-Silanes F (1999) Benefits of privatization—evidence from Mexico. Q J Econ 114:1193–1242 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Lane J-E (2000) New public management. Routledge, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  19. Martin S, Parker D (1997) The impact of privatization—ownership and corporate performance in the UK. Routledge, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  20. Megginson WL, Nash RC, van Randenborgh M (1994) The financing and operating performance of newly privatized firms: an international empirical analysis. J Finance 44: 403–452CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Megginson WL, Netter JM (2001) From state to market: a survey of empirical studies on privatization. J Econ Lit 39: 321–389Google Scholar
  22. Parker D, Saal D (eds) (2003) International handbook of privatization. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and NorthamptonGoogle Scholar
  23. Pint EM (1991) Nationalization vs. regulation of monopolies: the effects of ownership on efficiency. J Public Econ 44: 131–164CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Pirttilä J, Tuomala M (2005) Public versus private production decisions: redistribution and the size of the public sector. Finanzarchiv 61: 120–137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Shleifer A (1998) State versus private ownership. J Econ Perspect 12: 133–150Google Scholar
  26. Sørensen PB (2000) The case for international tax coordination reconsidered. Econ Policy 15(31): 429–472CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Sørensen PB (ed) (2004) Measuring the tax burden on capital and labor. In: CESifo Seminar Series. The MIT Press, Cambridge and LondonGoogle Scholar
  28. Takayama A (1985) Mathematical economics, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  29. Wassenaar MC, Gradus RHJM (2004) Contracting out: the importance of a solution for the VAT distortion. CESifo Econ Stud 20: 377–396CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Willner J, Parker D (2007) The performance of public and private enterprise under conditions of active and passive ownership and competition and monopoly. J Econ 90: 221–253CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of HelsinkiHelsinkiFinland
  2. 2.Faculty of Economics and ManagementUniversity of HannoverHannoverGermany

Personalised recommendations