Journal of Economics

, Volume 93, Issue 3, pp 223–265 | Cite as

Migration dynamics

Article

Most migration flows include observable jumps, a phenomenon that is in line with migration irreversibility. We present a real option model where the migration choice depends on both the wage differential between the host country and the country of origin, and on the probability of full integration into the host country. The optimal migration decision of an individual consists of waiting to migrate in a (coordinated) mass of individuals. The size of the migration flow depends on the behavioural characteristics of the ethnic groups: the more “sociable” they are, the larger the wave and the lower the wage differential required. The second part of the paper is devoted to calibrating the model and simulating migration flows into Italy over the last decade. Our calibration can replicate the migration jumps in the short term. In particular, the calibrated model is able to project the induced labour demand elasticity level of the host country and the behavioural rationale of the migrants.

Keywords

migration real option labour market network effect 

JEL Classifications

F22 J61 O15 R23 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Anam M, Chiang SH, Hua L (2004) Uncertainty and international migration: an option cum portfolio model, mimeoGoogle Scholar
  2. Angrist JD and Kugler AD (2003). Protective or counter-productive? Labor market institutions and the effect of immigration on EU natives. Econ J 113: 302–331 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Antonji T, Card D (1991) The effects of immigration on the labor market outcomes of less-skilled natives. In: Abowd JM, Freeman RB (eds), pp 201–234Google Scholar
  4. Bartolini L (1993). Competivive runs: the case of a ceiling on aggregate investment. Eur Econ Rev 37: 921–948 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bass FM (1969). A new product growth for model consumer durables. Manage Sci 15/5: 215–227 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bauer T (1997). Lohneffekte der Zuwanderung: Eine empirische Untersuchung für Deutschland. Mitt Arbeitsmarkt Berufsforsch 3: 652–656 Google Scholar
  7. Bauer T and Zimmermann KF (1997). Network migration of ethnic Germans. Int Migr Rev 1(1): 143–149 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bauer TG, Epstein, Gang IN (2002) Herd effects or migration networks? The location choice of Mexican immigrants in the US. IZA Discussion Paper no. 551Google Scholar
  9. Boeri T and Bucker H (2005). Migration, co-ordination failures and EU enlargement. Econ Policy 20(44): 629–703 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Borjas GJ (1990) Friends and strangers. Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
  11. Borjas GJ (1994). The economics of immigration. J Econ Lit 32(4): 1667–1717 Google Scholar
  12. Borjas GJ (2003). The labor demand curve is downward sloping: reexamining the impact of immigration on the labor market. Q J Econ 118(4): 1335–1374 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Boyd M (1989) Family and personal networks in international migration: recent developments and new agendas. Int Migr Rev 23(3). Special Silver Anniversary Issue: International Migration in Assessment for the 90’s, pp. 638–670Google Scholar
  14. Burda MC (1995). Migration and the option value of waiting. Econ Soc Rev 27: 1–19 Google Scholar
  15. CARITAS (2003a) Dossier statistico immigrazioneGoogle Scholar
  16. CARITAS (2003b) Contemporary immigration in ItalyGoogle Scholar
  17. Chiswick BR (1978). The effect of Americanization on the earnings of foreign-born men. J Polit Econ 86(5): 897–921 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Coniglio ND (2003) Migropolis: migration networks and formation of ethnic clusters in cities. SNF Working Paper 46/03Google Scholar
  19. Corneo G and Jeanne O (1999). Segmented communication and fashionable behavior. J Econ Behav Organ 39: 371–385 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Cox DR and Miller HD (1965). The theory of stochastic process. Chapman & Hall, London Google Scholar
  21. De New JP and Zimmermann KF (1994). Native wage impacts of foreign labor: a random effects panel analysis. J Popul Econ 7: 177–192 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Dixit A and Pindyck RS (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton Google Scholar
  23. Dos Santos MD (2000) Is the unskilled workers immigration necessarily harmful for the unskilled natives? mimeoGoogle Scholar
  24. Efron B and Tibshirani RJ (1994). An introduction to the bootstrap. CRC Press, Boca Raton Google Scholar
  25. Feist H (1998). Wage-distance regulation in social-welfare programs: an option-theory perspective. J Econ 68: 271–293 Google Scholar
  26. Friedberg RM (2001). The impact of mass migration on the Israeli labor market. Q J Econ 116(4): 1373–1408 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gang IN and Rivera-Batiz FL (1994). Unemployment and attitudes towards foreigner in Germany. In: Steinmann G, Ulrich, RE (eds) The economic consequences of immigration to Germany, pp 121–154. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg Google Scholar
  28. Garson JP, Moulier-Boutang Y, Silberman R, Magnac T (1987) La Substitution des Autochtones aux étrangers sur le Marché du Travail dans la CEE, CEE, Direzione Generale per l’occupazione, gli Affari Sociali e L’Educazione/Groupe de Recherche et d’Analyse des Migrations Internationales, mimeoGoogle Scholar
  29. Gavosto A, Venturini A and Villosio C (1999). Do immigrants compete with natives?. Labour 3(13): 630–621 Google Scholar
  30. Harrison JM (1985). Brownian motion and stochastic flow systems. Wiley, New York Google Scholar
  31. Hartog J and Winkelmann R (2003). Comparing migrants to non-migrants: the case of Dutch migration to New Zealand. J Popul Econ 16(4): 683–705 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Hart RA (1975). Interregional economic migration: some theoretical considerations. J Reg Sci 15(2): 127–138 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Hatton TJ, Williamson JG (2006) What determines immigration’s impact? Comparing two global centuries. NBER Working Paper no. 12414Google Scholar
  34. Heitmueller A (2003) Coordination failures in network migration, IZA (Institute for the Study of Labor) Discussion Papers 770Google Scholar
  35. Hunt JC (1992). The impact of the 1962 repatriates from Algeria on the French labor market. Ind Labor Relat Rev 43: 556–572 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. ISTAT, Istituto Nazionale di Statistica, http://www.istat.it
  37. Jackman R and Savouri S (1992). Regional migration in Britain: an analysis of gross flows using NHS central register data. Econ J 102(415): 1433–1450 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Khwaja Y (2002) Should I stay or should I go? Migration under uncertainty: a real option approach, mimeoGoogle Scholar
  39. Langley PC (1974). The spatial allocation of migrants in England and Wales. Scott J Polit Econ 21(3): 259–277 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Leahy JP (1993). Investment in competitive equilibrium: the optimality of myopic behavior. Q J Econ 108: 1105–1133 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Locher L (2002) Testing for the option value of migration. mimeoGoogle Scholar
  42. Maillat D (1986) The Experience of European Receiving Countries. Presented at OECD Conference on the Future of Migration, Paris, FranceGoogle Scholar
  43. Massey D (1987). Do undocumented migrants earn lower wages than legal immigrants? New evidence from Mexico?. Int Migr Rev 21(2): 236–274 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Massey D (1995). The new immigration and ethnicity in the United States. Popul Dev Rev 21(3): 631–652 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Massey D, Arango J, Hugo G, Kouaouci A, Pellegriono A and Taylor J (1993). Theories of international migration: a review and appraisal. Popul Dev Rev 19: 431–466 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Matsuyama K (1992) Custom versus fashion: path-dependance and limit cycles in a random matching game. Working paper E-92-11. Stanford UniversityGoogle Scholar
  47. Moretti E (1999). Social networks and migrations: Italy 1876–1913. Int Migr Rev 33(3): 640–657 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Moretto M (2000). Irreversible investment with uncertainty and strategic behavior. Econ Model 17: 589–617 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Moretto M (2003) Competition and irreversible investments under uncertainty. Feem Nota di Lavoro 32.03Google Scholar
  50. Moretto M (2007) Competition and irreversible investment under uncertainty. Information Economics and Policy (forthcoming)Google Scholar
  51. Munshi K (2001) Identification of network effects: Mexican migrants in the US. Labor Market, paper presented at NEUDC conference, BostonGoogle Scholar
  52. Munshi K (2003). Networks in the modern economy: Mexican migrants in the US. labor market. Q J Econ 118(2): 549–599 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Nordhaus WD and Yang Z (1996). A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies. Am Econ Rev 86(4): 741–765 Google Scholar
  54. Ottaviano G, Peri G (2005) Rethinking the gains from immigration: theory and evidence from the US. NBER Working Paper no. 11672Google Scholar
  55. Pedersen PJ, Pytlikova M, Smith N (2004) Selection or network effects? Migration flows into 27 OECD Countries, 1990–2000. IZA Discussion Paper no. 1104Google Scholar
  56. Peri G (2005) International migrations: some comparisons and lessons for the European Union, mimeoGoogle Scholar
  57. Peri G (2006) Rethinking the effect of immigration on wages: new data and analysis from 1990–2004. Immigration Policy IN FOCUS Immigration Policy Center 5(8)Google Scholar
  58. Rodick D (1991). Policy uncertainty and private investment in developing countries. J Dev Econ 36(2): 229–242 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Sjaastad LA (1962). The costs and returns of human migration, part 2. J Polit Econ 70(5): 80–93 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Thierry X and Rogers GI (2004). Recent immigration trends in France and elements for a comparison with the United Kingdom. Population 59(5): 68–672 Google Scholar
  61. Todaro PM (1969). A model of labor migration and Urban unemployment in less developed countries. Am Econ Rev 59(1): 138–148 Google Scholar
  62. Vandermeer JH and Goldberg DE (2004). Population ecology: first principles. Princeton University Press, New Jersey Google Scholar
  63. Varian H (2005). Bootstrap tutorial. Math J 9: 768–775 Google Scholar
  64. Veblen T (1924). The theory of the leisure class. An economic study of institutions. George Allen & Unwin, London (first published 1899) Google Scholar
  65. Venturini A (1997) Competition and Complementary of Illegal Immigrants: the Italian Case, CEPR Workshop on the Economics of Illegal Migration Problem, Athens, 14/15 February, mimeoGoogle Scholar
  66. Venturini A (1999). Do immigrants working illegally reduce the natives’ legal employment Italy?. J Popul Econ 12: 135–154 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Vergalli S (2005) Migration dynamics. PhD thesis, University of PaduaGoogle Scholar
  68. Vergalli S (2007) Entry and exit strategies in migration dynamics. Feem Working Paper no. 123 and Discussion Paper no. 0701, University of BresciaGoogle Scholar
  69. Vergalli S (2008) The role of community in migration dynamiscs. Labour, Review of Labour Economics and Industrial Relations (forthcoming)Google Scholar
  70. Winters P, de Janvry A and Sadoulet E (2001). Family and community networks in Mexico–US migration. J Hum Resour 36(1): 159–184 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Wien 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of PaduaPaduaItaly
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsUniversity of BresciaBresciaItaly

Personalised recommendations