Skip to main content
Log in

Debiasing preferences over redistribution: an experiment

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the manipulation of preferences over redistribution. Previous work showed that preferences over redistribution are malleable by the experience of success or failure in a preceding real-effort task. We manipulate the information subjects receive about the importance of chance relative to effort in determining success. We investigate the effect of this manipulation on (1) subjects’ redistribution choices affecting third parties, and (2) preferences for redistributive taxation. Our results show that informing the subjects about the relative importance of chance after the real-effort task does not mitigate the self-serving bias in redistribution choices. Only providing full information before the real-effort task prevents the emergence of the self-serving bias.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Weinzierl (2017) provides survey evidence showing that respondents do not seek full equalization of unequal outcomes produced entirely by randomness.

  2. A related strand of literature studies similar effects in bargaining (Gächter and Riedl 2005; Karagözoğlu and Riedl 2015), dictator games (Erkal et al. 2011; Spiekermann and Weiss 2016), money burning (Fehr 2018), and effort provision (Kovárík et al. 2018).

  3. In few sessions of the PostTask treatment, participants were not given this last piece of information, namely that the game was designed such as randomness almost completely determined success. We found no statistical difference neither for the demand of redistribution in the DDG (\(p=0.806\), Wilcoxon rank-sum test), nor in the RTG (\(p=0.652\)), and we pool these observations for the remainder of the paper.

  4. The associated redistribution choices were: 0%, 9.1%, 18.2%, 27.3%, 36.4%, 45.5%, 54.5%, 63.6%, 72.7%, 81.8%, 90.9%, 100%. We deliberately excluded the 50-50 split (as e.g. in Bellemare et al. 2008).

  5. We slightly depart from the DDG introduced in Deffains et al. (2016) in three ways. First, we do not display the difference of tokens between the two targets, but let dictators choose on a percentage of redistribution. This ensures that all dictators have the same strategy space. Second, we make the consequences of the dictator’s decision highly salient by means of the graphical representation. Third, participants do not learn their payoff at the end of the DGG, which minimizes spillovers on the subsequent game.

  6. The second series of tasks consisted in memorizing pictures and short video clips. After displaying each picture or video clip for about one minute, subjects had to answer questions regarding their contents. For this second real-effort task there was no hard/easy manipulation and no median split of the participants according to performance. The sole purpose of the second real-effort task was to generate variance in the earnings among subjects in a group to render the choice over redistribution in the RTG meaningful.

  7. After the random dictator mechanism participants were asked to bargain within their group of four to reach a consensus on the redistribution rule. The bargaining process consisted of five stages, in each of which participants could publicly announce their desired level of redistribution, and bargaining would stop in case of unanimous agreement on a tax rate. Both the random dictator and the result of the bargaining were potentially relevant for the outcome of the RTG. With 50% probability a group’s final tax rate was determined by the random dictator rule; with the remaining probability it was determined by the bargaining. In the following we will focus on the private decision, as this is not confounded with strategic concerns.

  8. The fact that we observe switchers raises the question whether our design was deceptive, because we told subjects that would be virtually impossible to switch. At the time we designed the experiment we based the wording of the instructions on observations from four sessions of our previous work (Deffains et al. 2016), where we used the same real effort task and observed perfect separation. We decided to keep the procedures constant between sessions despite the fact that we observed switchers in the experiments for the present study. In addition, the instructions read virtually impossible, which technically still concedes the possibility of switching.

  9. We compute scores of standardized performance by centering and standardizing the performance scores at the session and task level.

  10. To fully capture the treatment effect, we rely on an instrumental-variable approach such as suggested by Angrist et al. (1996). To do so, we instrument the actual treatment (overachiever or underachiever group) by the intention to treat (easy or hard task assignment). The instrumented variable overachiever is no longer correlated with the error term (due to the composition effect), because the task assignment was randomly allocated.

  11. Results available upon request.

  12. All regressions exclude targets from the disinterested dictator game.

  13. The coefficient associated with overachievers for Baseline loses in significance. Results available upon request.

  14. All regression results are available on request.

References

  • Ackert LF, Martinez-Vazquez J, Rider M (2007) Social preferences and tax policy design: some experimental evidence. Econ Inq 45(3):487–501

    Google Scholar 

  • Ai C, Norton EC (2003) Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Econ Lett 80(1):123–129

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Angeletos G-M (2005) Fairness and redistribution. Am Econ Rev 95(4):960–980

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Cozzi G, Mantovan N (2012) The evolution of ideology, fairness and redistribution. Econ J 122(565):1244–1261

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Giuliano P (2011) Preferences for redistribution. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson MO (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1A, chapter 4. Elsevier B.V, pp 93–131

  • Anderson CA (1982) Inoculation and counterexplanation: debiasing techniques in the perseverance of social theories. Soc Cogn 1(2):126–139

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson CA (1983) Abstract and concrete data in the perseverance of social theories: when weak data lead to unshakeable beliefs. J Exp Soc Psychol 19(2):93–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD, Imbens GW, Rubin DB (1996) Identification of causal effects using instrumental variables. J Am Stat Assoc 91(434):444–455

    Google Scholar 

  • Arkes HR (1991) Costs and benefits of judgment errors: implications for debiasing. Psychol Bull 110(3):486–498

    Google Scholar 

  • Babcock L, Loewenstein G (1997) Explaining bargaining impasse: the role of self-serving biases. J Econ Perspect 11(1):109–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Babcock L, Loewenstein G, Issacharoff S, Camerer CF (1995) Biased judgments of fairness in bargaining. Am Econ Rev 85(5):1337–1343

    Google Scholar 

  • Babcock L, Loewenstein G, Issacharoff S (1997) Creating convergence: debiasing biased litigants. Law Soc Inq 22(4):913–925

    Google Scholar 

  • Balafoutas L, Kocher MG, Putterman L, Sutter M (2013) Equality, equity and incentives: an experiment. Eur Econ Rev 60:32–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Bellemare C, Kröger S, van Soest A (2008) Measuring inequity aversion in a heterogenous population using experimental decisions and subjective probabilities. Econometrica 76(4):815–839

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjerk D (2016) In front of and behind the veil of ignorance: an analysis of motivations for redistribution. Soc Choice Welf 47(4):791–824

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonica A, McCarty N, Poole KT, Rosenthal H (2013) Why hasn’t democracy slowed rising inequality? J Econ Perspect 27(3):103–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2002) The inheritance of inequality. J Econ Perspect 16(3):3–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabrales A, Nagel R, Rodríguez Mora JV (2012) It is Hobbes, not Rousseau: an experiment on voting and redistribution. Exp Econ 15(2):278–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen AW, Tungodden B (2017) Fairness and the proportionality principle. Soc Choice Welf 49(3–4):709–719

    Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen AW, Hole AD, Sørensen EØ, Tungodden B (2007) The pluralism of fairness ideals: an experimental approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3):818–827

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassar L, Klein AH (2019) A matter of perspective: how failure shapes distributive preferences. Manag Sci 65(11):5050–5064

    Google Scholar 

  • Croson R, Konow J (2009) Social preferences and moral biases. J Econ Behav Org 69(3):201–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Deffains B, Espinosa R, Thöni C (2016) Political self-serving bias and redistribution. J Public Econ 134:67–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Durante R, Putterman L, van der Weele J (2014) Preferences for redistribution and perception of fairness: an experimental study. J Eur Econ Assoc 12(4):1059–1086

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenkopf G, Fischbacher U, Föllmi-Heusi F (2013) Unequal opportunities and distributive justice. J Econ Behav Org 93:51–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Erkal N, Gangadharan L, Nikiforakis N (2011) Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. Am Econ Rev 101(7):3330–3348

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr D (2018) Is increasing inequality harmful? Experimental evidence. Games Econ Behav 107:123–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich N, Oppenheimer JA (1990) Choosing justice in experimental democracies with production. Am Polit Sci Rev 84(2):461–477

    Google Scholar 

  • Gächter S, Riedl A (2005) Moral property rights in bargaining with infeasible claims. Manag Sci 51(2):249–263

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber A, Nicklisch A, Voigt S (2019) The role of ignorance in the emergence of redistribution. J Econ Behav Org 163:239–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Gino F, Norton MI, Weber RA (2016) Motivated bayesians: feeling moral while acting egoistically. J Econ Perspect 30(3):189–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Großer J, Reuben E (2013) Redistribution and market efficiency: an experimental study. J Public Econ 101:39–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Guenther CL, Alicke MD (2008) Self-enhancement and belief perseverance. J Exp Soc Psychol 44:706–712

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, Spitzer ML (1985) Entitlements, rights, and fairness: an experimental examination of subjects’ concepts of distributive justice. J Legal Stud 14(2):259–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiménez-Jiménez N, Molis E, Solano-García Á (2018) The effect of initial inequality on meritocracy: a voting experiment on tax redistribution. J Econ Behav Org. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2018.09.019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jolls C, Sunstein CR (2006) Debiasing through law. J Legal Stud 35(1):199–241

    Google Scholar 

  • Karadja M, Mollerstrom J, Seim D (2017) Richer (and holier) than thou? The effect of relative income improvements on demand for redistribution. Rev Econ Stat 99(2):201–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Karagözoğlu E, Riedl A (2015) Performance information, production uncertainty, and subjective entitlements in bargaining. Manag Sci 61(11):2611–2626

    Google Scholar 

  • Kataria M, Montinari N (2012) Risk, entitlement and fairness bias: explaining preferences for redistribution in multi-person setting. Working paper

  • Kittel B, Kanitsar G, Traub S (2017) Knowledge, power, and self-interest. J Public Econ 150:39–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Klor EF, Shayo M (2010) Social identity and preferences over redistribution. J Public Econ 94(3–4):269–278

    Google Scholar 

  • Konow J (2000) Fair shares: accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions. Am Econ Rev 90(4):1072–1091

    Google Scholar 

  • Konow J (2009) Is fairness in the eye of the beholder? An impartial spectator analysis of justice. Soc Choice Welf 33(1):101–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Konow J, Saijo T, Akai K (2019) Equity versus equality: Spectators, stakeholders and groups. J Econ Psychol 77:1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Koriat A, Lichtenstein S, Fischhoff B (1980) Memory reasons for confidence. J Exp Psychol Hum Learn Mem 6(2):107–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovárík J, Martínez-Macías I, Miller L (2018) Distributive preferences and effort provision: what determines what?. Working paper

  • Larrick RP (2004) Debiasing. In: Koehler DJ, Harvey N (eds) Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making. Blackwell Publishing, pp 316–337. https://doi.org/10.1002/9780470752937.ch16

  • Lord CG, Lepper MR, Preston E (1984) Considering the opposite: a corrective strategy for social judgment. J Pers Soc Psychol 47(6):1231–1243

    Google Scholar 

  • Luhan WJ, Poulsen O, Roos MWM (2019) Money or morality: Fairness ideals in unstructured bargaining. Soc Choice Welfare 53(4):655–675

    Google Scholar 

  • Nisbett RE, Krantz DH, Jepson C, Kunda Z (1983) The use of statictical heuristics in everyday inductive reasoning. Psychol Rev 90(4):339–363

    Google Scholar 

  • Norton EC, Wang H, Ai C (2004) Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and probit models. Stata J 4:154–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Lara I, Moreno-Garrido L (2012) Self-interest and fairness: self-serving choices of justice principles. Exp Econ 15(1):158–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross L, Lepper MD, Hubbard M (1975) Perseverance in self-perception and social perception: biased attributional processes in the debriefing paradigm. J Pers Soc Psychol 32(5):880–892

    Google Scholar 

  • Schildberg-Hörisch H (2010) Is the veil of ignorance only a concept about risk? An experiment. J Public Econ 94(11–12):1062–1066

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic P, Fischhoff B (1977) On the psychology of experimental surprises. J Exp Psychol Hum Percept Perform 3(4):544–551

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiekermann K, Weiss A (2016) Objective and subjective compliance: a norm-based explanation of ‘moral wiggle room’. Games Econ Behav 96:170–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinghög G, Andersson D, Västfjäll D (2017) Are individuals luck egalitarians? An experiment on the influence of brute and option luck on social preferences. Front Psychol 8:1–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Tyran J-R, Sausgruber R (2006) A little fairness may induce a lot of redistribution in democracy. Eur Econ Rev 50(2):469–485

    Google Scholar 

  • Ubeda P (2014) The consistency of fairness rules: an experimental study. J Econ Psychol 41:88–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinzierl M (2017) Popular acceptance of inequality due to innate brute luck and support for classical benefit-based taxation. J Public Econ 155:54–63

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the seminar participants in Leuven (CELSE), Rennes (CREM), Hué (PET), and Paris (AFSE). Financial support of the Institut Universitaire de France is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Thöni.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 595 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Espinosa, R., Deffains, B. & Thöni, C. Debiasing preferences over redistribution: an experiment. Soc Choice Welf 55, 823–843 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-020-01265-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-020-01265-z

Navigation