Advertisement

Journal of Evolutionary Economics

, Volume 24, Issue 1, pp 83–106 | Cite as

The evolution of morality and the end of economic man

  • Geoffrey M. HodgsonEmail author
Regular Article

Abstract

1871 saw the publication of two major treatises in economics, with self-seeking economic man at their center. In the same year Darwin published The Descent of Man, which emphasized sympathy and cooperation as well as self-interest, and contained a powerful argument that morality has evolved in humans by natural selection. Essentially this stance is supported by modern research. This paper considers the nature of morality and how it has evolved. It reconciles Darwin’s notion that a developed morality requires language and deliberation (and is thus unique to humans), with his other view that moral feelings have a long-evolved and biologically-inherited basis. The social role of morality and its difference with altruism is illustrated by an agent-based simulation. The fact that humans combine both moral and selfish dispositions has major implications for the social sciences and obliges us to abandon the pre-eminent notion of selfish economic man. Economic policy must take account of our moral nature.

Keywords

Morality Darwin Evolution Cooperation Altruism 

JEL Classification

B52 D01 D64 

References

  1. Alexander RD (1987) The biology of moral systems. Aldine de Gruter, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  2. Andreoni J (1995) Cooperation in public goods experiments: kindness or confusion? Am Econ Rev 85(4):891–904Google Scholar
  3. Arrow KJ (1994) Methodological individualism and social knowledge. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 84(2):1–9Google Scholar
  4. Becker GS (1976) The economic approach to human behavior. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  5. Ben-Ner A, Putterman L (2000) Some implications of evolutionary psychology for the study of preferences and institutions. J Econ Behav Organ 43(1):91–109Google Scholar
  6. Binmore K (1994) Playing fair: game theory and the social contract, vol I. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  7. Binmore K (1998) Just playing: game theory and the social contract, vol 2. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  8. Bok S (1978) Lying: moral choice in public and private life. Pantheon, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  9. Bowles S, Choi J-K, Hopfensitz A (2003) The co-evolution of individual behaviors and social institutions. J Theor Biol 223(2):135–147Google Scholar
  10. Bowles S, Gintis H (2011) A cooperative species: human reciprocity and its evolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  11. Boyd R, Gintis H, Bowles S, Richerson PJ (2003) Evolution of altruistic punishment. Proc Natl Acad Sci 100(6):3531–3535Google Scholar
  12. Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  13. Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1992) Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethol Sociobiol 13:171–195Google Scholar
  14. Brown DE (1991) Human universals. McGraw-Hill, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  15. Camerer CF, Fehr E (2006) When does “economic man” dominate social behavior? Science 311:47–52Google Scholar
  16. Carpenter JP, Matthews PH, Ong’ong’a O (2004) Why punish? Social reciprocity and the enforcement of prosocial norms. J Evol Econ 14(4):407–429Google Scholar
  17. Carpenter JP, Matthews PH (2009) What norms trigger punishment? Exp Econ 12(3):272–288Google Scholar
  18. Darwin CR (1871) The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex, 2 vols. Murray and Hill, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  19. Dawkins R (1976) The selfish gene. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  20. De Waal FBM (1996) Good natured: the origin of right and wrong in humans and other animals. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  21. De Waal FBM (2006) Primates and philosophers: how morality evolved. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  22. Deacon TW (1997) The symbolic species: the co-evolution of language and the brain. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  23. Diamond J (1991) The rise and fall of the third chimpanzee. Vintage, LondonGoogle Scholar
  24. Durham WH (1991) Coevolution: genes, culture, and human diversity. Stanford University Press, StanfordGoogle Scholar
  25. Edgeworth FY (1881) Mathematical psychics: an essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. Kegan Paul, LondonGoogle Scholar
  26. Elster J (1986) The multiple self. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  27. Etzioni A (1988) The moral dimension: toward a new economics. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  28. Evans N, Levinson SC (2009) The myth of language universals: language diversity and its importance for cognitive science. Behav Brain Sci 32(5):429–492Google Scholar
  29. Evensky J (2005) Adam Smith’s theory of moral sentiments: on morals and why they matter to a liberal society of free people and free markets. J Econ Perspect 19(3):109–130Google Scholar
  30. Fehr E, Camerer CF (2007) Social neuroeconomics: the neural circuitry of social preferences. Trends Cogn Sci 11(1):419–427Google Scholar
  31. Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2002) Why do social preferences matter—the impact of non-selfish motives on competition, cooperation and incentives. Econ J 112:C1–C33Google Scholar
  32. Fehr E, Gächter S (2000a) Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity. J Econ Perspect 14(3):159–181Google Scholar
  33. Fehr E, Gächter S (2000b) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90(4):980–995Google Scholar
  34. Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140Google Scholar
  35. Fehr E, Gintis H (2007) Human motivation and social cooperation: experimental and analytical foundations. Annu Rev Sociol 33:43–64Google Scholar
  36. Field AJ (2001) Altruistically inclined? The behavioral sciences, evolutionary theory, and the origins of reciprocity. University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar
  37. Field AJ (2007) Beyond foraging: evolutionary theory, institutional variation, and economic performance. J Inst Econ 3(3):265–291Google Scholar
  38. Fiske AP (1991) Structures of social life: the four elementary forms of human relations: communal sharing, authority ranking, equality matching, market pricing. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  39. Frey BS (1997) Not just for money: an economic theory of personal motivation. Edward Elgar, AldershotGoogle Scholar
  40. Ghiselin MT (1974) The economy of nature and the evolution of sex. University of California Press, BerkeleyGoogle Scholar
  41. Gintis H (2000) Strong reciprocity and human sociality. J Theor Biol 206:169–179Google Scholar
  42. Gintis H, Bowles S, Boyd R, Fehr E (eds) (2005) Moral sentiments and material interests: the foundations of cooperation in economic life. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  43. Greene JD, Haidt J (2002) How (and Where) Does moral judgement work? Trends Cogn Sci 6(12):517–523Google Scholar
  44. Guzmán RA, Rodriguez-Sicken C, Rowthorn R (2007) When in Rome, do as the Romans do: the coevolution of altruistic punishment, conformist learning, and cooperationEvol Hum Behav 28:112–117Google Scholar
  45. Güth W (1995) On ultimatum bargaining experiments—a personal review. J Econ Behav 27:329–344Google Scholar
  46. Haidt J (2001) The emotional dog and the rational tail: a social interactionist approach to moral judgment. Psychol Rev 108:814–834Google Scholar
  47. Haidt J, Joseph C (2004) Intuitive ethics: how innately prepared intuitions generate culturally variable virtues. Daedalus 133(4):55–66Google Scholar
  48. Haidt J, Joseph C (2008) The moral mind: how five sets of innate intuitions guide the development of many culture-specific virtues, and perhaps even modules. In: Carruthers P, Laurence S, Stich S (eds) The innate mind, vol 3, pp 367–444Google Scholar
  49. Hamilton WD (1964) The genetical evolution of social behavior. J Theor Biol 7(1):1–32Google Scholar
  50. Hamlin JK, Wynn K, Bloom P (2007) Social evaluation by preverbal infants. Nature 450:557–560Google Scholar
  51. Hammerstein P (ed) (2003) Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  52. Hare RM (1952) The language of morals. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  53. Hauser MD (2006) Moral minds: how nature designed our universal sense of right and wrong. Harper Collins, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  54. Henrich J (2004) Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. J Econ Behav Organ 53(1):3–35Google Scholar
  55. Henrich J, Boyd R (1998) The evolution of conformist transmission and the emergence of between group differences. Evol Hum Behav 19:215–242Google Scholar
  56. Henrich J, Gil-White FJ (2001) The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav 22(3):165–196Google Scholar
  57. Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H, McElreath R (2001) In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 91(2):73–84Google Scholar
  58. Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H (2004) Foundations of human sociality: economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  59. Henrich J, McElreath R, Barr A, Ensminger J, Barrett C, Bolyanatz A, Cardenas JC, Gurven M, Gwako E, Henrich N, Lesorogol C, Marlowe F, Tracer D, Ziker J (2006) Costly punishment across human societies. Science 312(5781):1767–1770Google Scholar
  60. Henrich J, Ensminger J, McElreath R, Barr A, Barrett C, Bolyanatz A, Cardenas JC, Gurven M, Gwako E, Henrich N, Lesorogol C, Marlowe F, Tracer D, Ziker J (2010) Markets, religion, community size, and the evolution of fairness and punishment. Science 327(5972):1480–1484Google Scholar
  61. Hill KR, Walker RS, Božičević M, Eder J, Headland T, Hewlett B, Hurtado AM, Marlowe F, Wiessner P, Wood B (2011) Co-residence patterns in hunter-gatherer societies show unique human social structure. Science 331(6022):1286–1289Google Scholar
  62. Hobson JA (1929) Wealth and life: a study in values. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  63. Hodgson GM (1993) Economics and evolution: bringing life back into economics. Polity Press and University of Michigan Press, Cambridge, UK and Ann Arbor, MIGoogle Scholar
  64. Hodgson GM (2007) Meanings of methodological individualism. J Econ Methodol 14(2):211–226Google Scholar
  65. Hodgson GM (2009) On the institutional foundations of law: the insufficiency of custom and private ordering. J Econ Iss 43(1):143–166Google Scholar
  66. Hodgson GM (2013) From pleasure machines to moral communities: an evolutionary economics without homo economicus. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  67. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2010) Darwin’s conjecture: the search for general principles of social and economic evolution. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  68. Huxley TH, Huxley J (1947) Evolution and ethics, 1893–1943. Pilot Press, LondonGoogle Scholar
  69. Jevons WS (1871) The theory of political economy. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  70. Joyce R (2006) The evolution of morality. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  71. Kaplow L, Shavell S (2007) Moral rules, the moral sentiments, and behavior: toward a theory of an optimal moral system. J Polit Econ 115(3):494–514Google Scholar
  72. Kropotkin PA (1902) Mutual aid: a factor of evolution, 1st edn. Heinemann, LondonGoogle Scholar
  73. Lopes H, Santos AC, Teles N (2009) The motives for cooperation in work organisations. J Inst Econ 5(3):259–288Google Scholar
  74. Mackie JL (1977) Ethics: inventing right and wrong. Penguin, HarmondsworthGoogle Scholar
  75. Margolis H (1982) Selfishness, altruism, and rationality: a theory of social choice. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  76. McCloskey DN (2006) The bourgeois virtues: ethics for an age of commerce. Chicago University Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  77. McCrink K, Bloom P, Santos LR (2010) Children’s and adult’s judgments of equitable resource distributions. Dev Sci 13(1):37–45Google Scholar
  78. Menger C (1871) Grundsätze der volkwirtschaftslehre. J. C. B. Mohr, Tübingen. Translated and published in English in 1981 as Principles of Economics (New York University Press, New York)Google Scholar
  79. Midgley M (2003) Myths we live by. Routledge, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  80. Minkler LP (2008) Integrity and agreement: economics when principles also matter. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MIGoogle Scholar
  81. Nichols S (2004) Sentimental rules: on the natural foundations of moral judgment. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  82. Oppenheimer S (2004) The real eve. Carroll and Graf, New York. Published in the UK as Out of Eden (Constable and Robinson, London)Google Scholar
  83. Palmer CT, Steadman LB (1997) Human kinship as a descendant-leaving strategy: a solution to an evolutionary puzzle. J Soc Evol Syst 20(1):39–51Google Scholar
  84. Pinker S (1994) The language instinct: the new science of language and mind. Allen Lane and Morrow, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  85. Price ME, Cosmides L, Tooby J (2002) Punitive sentiment as an anti-free-rider device. Evol Hum Behav 23:203–31Google Scholar
  86. Rizzolatti G, Corrado S, Frances A (2007) Mirrors in the brain: how our minds share actions, emotions, and experience. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  87. Roberts S (1979) Order and discipline: an introduction to legal anthropology. St Martins Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  88. Robinson PH, Kurzban R, Jones OD (2007) The origins of shared intuitions of justice. Vanderbilt Law Rev 60(6):1633–1688Google Scholar
  89. Runciman WG (2002) Heritable variation and competitive selection as the mechanism of sociocultural evolution. In: Wheeler M, Ziman J, Boden MA (eds) The evolution of cultural entities. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 9–25Google Scholar
  90. Sampson G (2005) The language instinct debate. Continuum, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  91. Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy, 1st edn. George Allen and Unwin, LondonGoogle Scholar
  92. Schwartz SH (1994) Are there universal aspects in the structure and contents of human values? J Soc Iss 50(4):19–45Google Scholar
  93. Sen AK (1987) On ethics and economics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  94. Smart JJC, Williams B (1973) Utilitarianism: for and against. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  95. Sober E, Wilson DS (1998) Unto others: the evolution and psychology of unselfish behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  96. Tancredi L (2005) Hardwired behavior: what neuroscience reveals about morality. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  97. Thiroux JP, Krasemann KW (2009) Ethics: theory and practice, 10th edn. Pearson, LondonGoogle Scholar
  98. Tisak MS, Turiel E (1984) Children’s conceptions of moral and prudential rules. Child Dev 55:1030–1039Google Scholar
  99. Trivers RL (1971) The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol 46(1):35–57Google Scholar
  100. Vanberg VJ (2008) On the economics of moral preferences. Am J Econ Sociol 67(4):605–628Google Scholar
  101. Wade MJ (1978) A critical review of the models of group selection. Q Rev Biol 53:101–114Google Scholar
  102. Walras L (1874) Éléments d’économie politique pure, ou théorie de la richesse sociale. Rouge, LausanneGoogle Scholar
  103. Westermarck E (1891) The history of human marriage. Macmillan, London and New YorkGoogle Scholar
  104. Wicksteed PH (1910) The commonsense of political economy, including a study of the human basis of economic law. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  105. Wiessner P (2005) Norm enforcement among the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen: a case of strong reciprocity? Hum Nat 16(2):115–145Google Scholar
  106. Williams GC (1966) Adaptation and natural selection. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  107. Wilson DS (1980) The natural selection of populations and communities. Benjamin/Cummings, Menlo Park, CAGoogle Scholar
  108. Wilson DS (1983) The group selection controversy: history and current status. Annu Rev Ecol Evol Syst 14:159–188Google Scholar
  109. Wilson DS (2002) Darwin’s cathedral: evolution, religion, and the nature of society. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  110. Wilson DS, Sober E (1994) Reintroducing group selection to the human behavioral sciences. Behav Brain Sci 17(4):585–608Google Scholar
  111. Wilson DS, Wilson EO (2007) Rethinking the theoretical foundations of sociobiology. Q Rev Biol 82(4):327–348Google Scholar
  112. Zak PJ (2004) Neuroeconomics. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B 359:1737–1748Google Scholar
  113. Zak PJ (ed) (2008) Moral markets: the critical role of values in the economy. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Hertfordshire Business SchoolUniversity of HertfordshireHatfieldUK

Personalised recommendations