Advertisement

International Journal of Game Theory

, Volume 41, Issue 3, pp 651–669 | Cite as

Repeated congestion games with bounded rationality

  • Marco Scarsini
  • Tristan Tomala
Article

Abstract

We consider a repeated congestion game with imperfect monitoring. At each stage, each player chooses to use some facilities and pays a cost that increases with the congestion. Two versions of the model are examined: a public monitoring setting where agents observe the cost of each available facility, and a private monitoring one where players observe only the cost of the facilities they use. A partial folk theorem holds: a Pareto-optimal outcome may result from selfish behavior and be sustained by a belief-free equilibrium of the repeated game. We prove this result assuming that players use strategies of bounded complexity and we estimate the strategic complexity needed to achieve efficiency. It is shown that, under some conditions on the number of players and the structure of the game, this complexity is very small even under private monitoring. The case of network routing games is examined in detail.

Keywords

Folk theorem Braess’s paradox Network routing games Private monitoring Public monitoring Anonymous games Strategic complexity Contagion strategy Calendar strategy 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Afergan M (2005) Applying the repeated game framework to multiparty networked applications. Ph.D. thesis, MIT, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  2. Afergan M (2006) Using repeated games to design incentive-based routing systems. In: IEEE INFOCOM 2006. BarcelonaGoogle Scholar
  3. Afergan M, Sami R (2006) Repeated-game modeling of multicast overlays. In: IEEE INFOCOM 2006. BarcelonaGoogle Scholar
  4. Anshelevich E, Dasgupta A, Kleinberg J, Tardos É, Wexler T, Roughgarden T (2008) The price of stability for network design with fair cost allocation. SIAM J Comput 38: 1602–1623CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Aumann RJ, Shapley LS (1976) Long-term competition—a game-theoretic analysis. Technical report, Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Reprinted in Essays in Game Theory. In: Megiddo N (ed) Honor of Michael Maschler (1994). Springer, New York, pp 1–15Google Scholar
  6. Braess D (1968) Úber ein Paradoxon aus der Verkehrsplanung. Unternehmensforschung 12: 258–268Google Scholar
  7. Braess D (2005) On a paradox of traffic planning. Transport Sci 39:446–450. Translation of the original German (1968) article by D. Braess, A. Nagurney and T. WakolbingerGoogle Scholar
  8. Correa JR, Schulz AS, Stier-Moses NE (2004) Selfish routing in capacitated networks. Math Oper Res 29: 961–976CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ely JC, Hörner J, Olszewski W (2005) Belief-free equilibria in repeated games. Econometrica 73: 377–415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Friedman JW (1971) A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. Rev Econ Stud 38: 1–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Fudenberg D, Levine DK (1991) An approximate folk theorem with imperfect private information. J Econ Theory 54: 26–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Fudenberg D, Levine D, Maskin E (1994) The folk theorem with imperfect public information. Econometrica 62: 997–1039CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Holzman R, Law-Yone N (1997) Strong equilibrium in congestion games. Game Econ Behav 21: 85–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Holzman R, Law-yone N (2003) Network structure and strong equilibrium in route selection games. Math Soc Sci 46: 193–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kalai E, Stanford W (1988) Finite rationality and interpersonal complexity in repeated games. Econometrica 56: 397–410CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kandori M (1992) Social norms and community enforcement. Rev Econ Stud 59: 63–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. La RJ, Anantharam V (2002) Optimal routing control: repeated game approach. IEEE Trans Automat Control 47: 437–450CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Mailath GJ, Samuelson L (2006) Repeated games and reputations. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Monderer D, Shapley LS (1996) Potential Games. Game Econ Behav 14: 124–143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Papadimitriou C (2001) Algorithms, games, and the Internet. In: Proceedings of the 33rd annual ACM symposium on the theory of computing, Hersonissos, Crete. ACM, New York, NY, USA, pp 749–753Google Scholar
  21. Rosenthal RW (1973) A class of games possessing pure-strategy Nash equilibria. Int J Game Theory 2: 65–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Roughgarden T (2005) Selfish routing and the price of anarchy. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  23. Roughgarden T (2007) Routing games. In: Algorithmic game theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 461–486CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Roughgarden T, Tardos É (2004) Bounding the inefficiency of equilibria in nonatomic congestion games. Game Econ Behav 47: 389–403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Roughgarden T, Tardos É (2007) Introduction to the inefficiency of equilibria. In: Algorithmic game theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 443–459Google Scholar
  26. Rubinstein A (1977) Equilibrium in supergames. Master’s thesis, Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Reprinted in Essays in Game Theory, In honor of Michael Maschler (1994) Edited by Nimrod Megiddo, pp 17–27. Springer, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  27. Stigler GJ (1964) A theory of oligopoly. J Polit Econ 72: 44–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Dipartimento di Economia e FinanzaLUISSRomeItaly
  2. 2.Economics and Decision Science DepartmentHEC ParisJouy-en-Josas CedexFrance

Personalised recommendations