Journal of Population Economics

, Volume 20, Issue 3, pp 643–667 | Cite as

Oppositional identities and the labor market

Original Paper

Abstract

We develop a model in which nonwhite individuals are defined with respect to their social environment (family, friends, and neighbors) and their attachments to their culture of origin (religion or language), and in which jobs are mainly found through social networks. We find that depending on how strong peer pressures are, nonwhites choose to adopt “oppositional” identities because some individuals may identify with the dominant culture and others may reject that culture, even if it implies adverse labor market outcomes.

Keywords

Ethnic minorities Identity Social networks White’s norm Multiple equilibria 

JEL Classification

A14 J15 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Ainsworth-Darnell JW, Downey DB (1998) Assessing the oppositional culture explanation for racial/ethnic differences in school performance. Am Sociol Rev 63(4):536–553CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Akerlof GA (1997) Social distance and social decisions. Econometrica 65(5):1005–1027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2000) Economics and identity. Q J Econ 105(3):715–753Google Scholar
  4. Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2002) Identity and schooling: some lessons for the economics of education. J Econ Lit 40(4):1167–1201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Austen-Smith D, Fryer RD Jr (2005) An economic analysis of ‘acting white’. Q J Econ 120(2):551–583CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Battu H, Zenou Y (2006) Oppositional identities in England. Mimeo, Research Institute of Industrial EconomicsGoogle Scholar
  7. Becker GS (1957) The economics of discrimination. Chicago University Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  8. Bernal ME, Knight GP (1993) Ethnic identity: formation and transmission among Hispanics and other minorities. State University of New York Press, AlbanyGoogle Scholar
  9. Borjas GJ (1994) The economics of immigration. J Econ Lit 32(4):1667–1717Google Scholar
  10. Calvó-Armengol A (2004) Job contact networks. J Econ Theory 115(1):191–206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Calvó-Armengol A, Jackson MO (2004) The effects of social networks on employment and inequality. Am Econ Rev 94(3):426–454CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Calvó-Armengol A, Zenou Y (2005) Job matching, social network and word-of-mouth communication. J Urban Econ 57(3):500–522CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chiswick BR (1978) The effect of Americanization on earnings of foreign born men. J Polit Econ 86(5):897–921CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Cutler D, Glaeser EL, Vigdor JL (1999) The rise and decline of the American ghetto. J Polit Econ 107(3):455–506CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Diamond P (1981) Mobility costs, frictional unemployment, and efficiency. J Polit Econ 89(4):798–812CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Delpit L (1995) Other people’s children: cultural conflict in the classroom. The Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  17. Dustmann C, Fabbri F (2003) Language proficiency and labour market performance of immigrants in the UK. Econ J 113(489):695–717CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Farkas G, Lleras C, Maczuga S (2002) Does oppositional culture exist in minority and poverty peer groups. Am Sociol Rev 67(1):148–155CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Fershtman C, Weiss Y (1998) Social rewards, externalities and stable preferences. J Public Econ 70(1):53–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fordham S, Ogbu JU (1986) Black students’ school success: coping with the burden of acting white. Urban Rev 18(3):176–206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Fryer RG Jr, Torelli P (2005) An empirical analysis of ‘acting white.’ NBER Working Paper No. 11334Google Scholar
  22. Gilbertson GA, Fitzpatrick JP, Yang L (1996) Hispanic intermarriage in New York City: new evidence from 1991. Int Migr Rev 30(2):445–459CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Iannaccone LR (1998) Introduction to the economics of religion. J Econ Lit 36(3):1465–1496Google Scholar
  24. Ihlanfeldt K, Scafidi B (2002) Black self-segregation as a cause of housing segregation. Evidence from the multi-city study of urban inequality. J Urban Econ 51(2):366–390CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Lazear EP (1999) Culture and language. J Polit Econ 107(6):S95–S126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. The Guardian (2005) Learning from each other. The Guardian, UK (Tuesday, November 8)Google Scholar
  27. Logan JR, Alba RD, Leung S-Y (1996) Minority access to white suburbs: a multiregional comparison. Soc Forces 74(3):851–881CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Massey DS, Mullan BP (1984) Processes of Hispanic and black spatial assimilation. Am J Sociol 89(4):836–873CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. McManus WS, Gould W, Welch F (1983) Earnings of Hispanic men: the role of English language proficiency. J Labor Econ 1(2):101–130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Modood T et al (1997) Ethnic minorities in Britain: diversity and disadvantage. Policy Studies Institute, LondonGoogle Scholar
  31. Montgomery J (1991) Social networks and labor-market outcomes: toward an economic analysis. Am Econ Rev 81(5):1408–1418Google Scholar
  32. Mortensen DT, Vishwanath T (1994) Personal contacts and earnings. It is who you know! Labour Econ 1(2):187–201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Ogbu JU (1978) Minority education and caste. Academic, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  34. Patacchini E, Zenou Y (2006) Racial identity and education. CEPR discussion paper 5607Google Scholar
  35. Peach C (2005) Social integration and social mobility: spatial segregation and intermarriage of the Caribbean population in Britain. In: Loury GC, Modood T, Teles SM (eds) Ethnicity, social mobility, and public policy: comparing the US and UK. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 178–203Google Scholar
  36. Pissarides CA (2000) Equilibrium unemployment theory, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  37. Portes A, Nash Parker R, Cobas JA (1980) Assimilation or consciousness: perception of U.S. society among recent Latin American immigrants to the United States. Soc Forces 59(1):200–224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Selod H, Zenou Y (2006) City-structure, job search, and labor discrimination. Theory and policy implications. Econ J (in press)Google Scholar
  39. Topa G (2001) Social interactions, local spillovers and unemployment. Rev Econ Stud 68(2):261–295CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Vives X (1999) Oligopoly pricing: old ideas and new tools. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of AberdeenOld AberdeenUK
  2. 2.Health Economics Research Unit (HERU), Medical SchoolUniversity of AberdeenAberdeenUK
  3. 3.Research Institute of Industrial EconomicsStockholmSweden

Personalised recommendations