Advertisement

AI & SOCIETY

, Volume 34, Issue 3, pp 649–676 | Cite as

An agent-oriented account of Piaget’s theory of interactional morality

  • Antônio Carlos da Rocha CostaEmail author
Open Forum
  • 360 Downloads

Abstract

In this paper, we present a formal interpretive account of Jean Piaget’s theory of the morality that regulates social exchanges, which we call interactional morality. First, we place Piaget’s conception in the context of his epistemological and sociological works. Then, we review the core of that conception: the two types of interactional moralities (autonomous and heteronomous) that Piaget identified to be usual in social exchanges, and the role that the notion of respect-for-the-other plays in their definition. Next, we analyze the main features of social exchanges that are subject to each of those two types of interactional moralities. Following, we formalize Piaget’s account of how the two types of interactional moralities can be put to regulate social exchanges in which values, norms, beliefs, and goals are exchanged (besides objects and services), so that interactional commitments can be established among the participants. Then, we sketch a moral reasoning system able to support formal reasonings about interactional moralities. Finally, we illustrate the usefulness of the overall formal model of interactional moralities that resulted from our study by applying it to the explication of some of the conclusions achieved by Piaget in his moral studies about children games.

Keywords

Formal notion of interactional morality Regulation of social exchanges Moral reasoning system Piaget’s moral studies of children games. 

References

  1. Gruber HE, Vonche JJ (eds) (1977) The essential Piaget. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  2. Emerson R (1976) Social exchange theory. In: Inkeles A, Colemen J, Smelser N (eds) Annual review of sociology. Annual Reviews, Palo Alto, pp 335–362Google Scholar
  3. Emerson RM (1991) Social exchange theory. In: Rosemberg M, Turner R (eds) Social psychology: sociological perspectives. Academic Press, New York, pp 30–65Google Scholar
  4. Cook KS (ed) (1987) Social exchange theory. Sage, Newbury ParkGoogle Scholar
  5. Cook KS, Rice E (2006) Social exchange theory. In: Delamater J (ed) Handbook of social psychology. Sage, Thousand Oaks, pp 53–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Cook KS, Rice E (2005) Social exchange theory. In: Ritzer G (ed) Encyclopedia of social theory. Sage, Thousand OaksGoogle Scholar
  7. Piaget J (1995) Sociological studies. Routledge, London Collection edited by Leslie SmithGoogle Scholar
  8. Piaget J (1962) The moral judgment of the child. Collier, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  9. Piaget J (1950) Introduction l’Épist’emologie Génétique. PUF, PariszbMATHGoogle Scholar
  10. Kant I (1991) Prolegomena to any future metaphysics that can qualify as a science. Open Court Publishing, La SalleGoogle Scholar
  11. Piaget J (1997) The development of thought: equilibration of cognitive structures. Viking Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  12. Piaget J (2001) The psychology of intelligence. Routledge, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  13. Costa ACR, Dimuro GP, Dugdale J, Demazeau Y (2009) A formal notion of objective expectations in the context of multiagent systems routines. In: Lopes LS, Lau N, Mariano P, Rocha LM (eds) New trends in artifical intelligence, Proceedings of 14th Portuguese conference on artificial intelligence. Universidade de Aveiro, Aveiro, pp 367–378Google Scholar
  14. Piaget J (1995) Essay on the theory of qualitative values in statict (’synchronic’) sociology. In: Smith L (ed) Sociological studies. Routledge, London, pp 97–133Google Scholar
  15. Durkheim E (1997) The division of labor in society. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  16. Kant I (2012) Groundwork of the metaphysics of morals. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  17. Kelsen H (2009) Pure theory of law. The Law Book Exchange, New JerseyGoogle Scholar
  18. Held V (2007) The ethics of care: personal, political, and global. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Costa ACR, Dimuro GP (2007) A basis for an exchange value-based operational notion of morality for multiagent systems. In: Neves J, Santos M, Machado J (eds) Progress in artificial intelligence, 13th Portuguese conference on artificial intelligence, EPIA 2007. Number 4874 in LNAI. Springer, Berlin, pp 580–592Google Scholar
  20. Thomson JJ (1985) The trolley problem. Yale Law J 94:1395–1415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Castelfranchi C, Cesta A, Miceli M (1992) Dependence relations among autonomous agents. In: Werner E, Demazeau Y (eds) Decentralized A.I.-3. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 215–227Google Scholar
  22. Conte R, Castelfranchi C (1995) Cognitive and social action. UCL Press, LondonGoogle Scholar
  23. Costa ACR, Dimuro GP (2007) Quantifying degrees of dependence in social dependence relations. The seventh international workshop on multi-agent based simulation (LNAI 4442). Springer, Berlin, pp 172–187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Castelfranchi C (1995) Commitments: from individual intentions to groups and organizations. In: Lesser V, Gasser L (eds) Proceedings of the first international conference on multiagent systems - ICMAS 95. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 41–48Google Scholar
  25. Castelfranchi C, Falcone R (2010) Trust theory: a socio-cognitive and computational model. Wiley, ChichesterCrossRefzbMATHGoogle Scholar
  26. Bell J (1990) Nonmonotonic reasoning, nonmonotonic logics and reasoning about change. Artif Intell Rev 4:79–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Prawitz D (2006) Natural deduction: a proof-theoretical study. Dover, MineolazbMATHGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag London Ltd., part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.PPGComp, Universidade Federal do Rio Grande, FURGRio GrandeBrazil
  2. 2.PPGFIL, Pontifícia Universidade Católica do Rio Grande do Sul, PUCRSPôrto AlegreBrazil

Personalised recommendations