Theoretical Medicine

, Volume 10, Issue 3, pp 217–229

Medicine as a career: Choices and consequences

  • Karen Eschenbach
  • Robert S. Woodward
Article

Abstract

Medicine has traditionally been regarded as a rewarding career both financially and socially. How true, however, is that tradition in today's world of rising costs and decreasing revenues? The educational debt of the physician-in-training is steadily increasing, and currently does not affect specialty choice. As the cost of medical education continues to rise, the applicant pool begins to shrink, thereby possibly affecting the quality of future physicians. Once the physician has completed training however, the majority enjoy a positive return on investment. Their incomes generally fail to remain ahead of inflation, and therefore, have remained within a narrow band of $40,000 in 1970 dollars. Finally, the demand for physician services cannot be attributed solely to either the consumer (patient) or to the supplier (physician). Rather, the demand for medical services appears to be a unique combination of the two. In conclusion, medicine still is an attractive career path, but the choices and consequences are becoming much more demanding.

Key words

cost of medical education demand for medical care services educational indebtedness financial rewards of medicine indebtedness and specialty choice medical economics return on investment supply of physicians 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. 1.
    Starr P. The Social Transformation of American Medicine. New York: Basic Books, Inc, 1982.Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    Bane F. Physician's for a Growing America: Report of the Surgeon General's Consultant Group on Medical Education. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 1959.Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    Coggeshall LT. Planning for Medical Progress through Education: A Report Submitted to the Executive Council of the Association of American Medical Colleges. Evanston: Association of American Medical Colleges, 1965.Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    Miller JI. Report to the President of the United States by the National Advisory Commission on Health Manpower. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 1967.Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    Kletke PR, Marder WD, Silberger AB, eds. The Demographics of Physician Supply: Trends and Projections. Chicago: AMA Center for Health Policy Research, 1986.Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Roback G, Randolph L, Mead D. Physician Characteristics and Distribution in the U.S. 1984 ed. Chicago: American Medical Association, 1985.Google Scholar
  7. 7.
    Council on Long-Range Planning and Development. Healthcare in transition: consequences for young physicians. JAMA 1986;256:3384–90.Google Scholar
  8. 8.
    Clare FL, Spratley E, Schwab P, Iglehart JK. Data watch: trends in health personnel. Health Aff 1987;6:90–103.Google Scholar
  9. 9.
    Leach DC. Money and manpower in graduate medical education. Henry Ford Hosp Med J 1986;34:263–6.Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    Owens A. Earnings: have they flattened out for good? Medical Economics 1986;63:162–81.Google Scholar
  11. 11.
    Korcok M. Medical education: prosperitas interrupta. JAMA 1983;249:12–6.Google Scholar
  12. 12.
    Brown LD. Introduction to a Decade of Transition. Durham: Duke University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    Bazzoli GJ. Does educational indebtedness affect physician specialty choice? Journal of Health Economics 1985;4:1–19.Google Scholar
  14. 14.
    Nelson S. Traditional medicine: a modern casualty? Hospitals 1987:61:98.Google Scholar
  15. 15.
    McCarty DJ. Why are today's medical students choosing high-technology specialties over internal medicine? N Engl J Med 1987;317:567–9.Google Scholar
  16. 16.
    Board of Trustees. The Effects of Educational Indebtedness on the Career Choices of New Physicians. Chicago: American Medical Association, 1983. (Report E(I-83)).Google Scholar
  17. 17.
    Hough DE, Bazzoli GJ. The economic environment of resident physicians. JAMA 1985;253:1758–62.Google Scholar
  18. 18.
    Paxton HT. Why you're spending a lot more to run your practice. Medical Economics 1987;64:170–96.Google Scholar
  19. 19.
    Human Resources Division, General Accounting Office. Medical Malpractice: Insurance Costs Increased But Varied Among Physicians and Hospitals. Washington, DC: General Accounting Office, 1986.Google Scholar
  20. 20.
    Human Resources Division, General Accounting Office. Medical Malpractice: Characteristics of Claims in 1984. Washington, DC: General Accounting Office, 1987.Google Scholar
  21. 21.
    Kirchner M. Are fees breaking all restraints? Medical Economics 1986;63:122–34.Google Scholar
  22. 22.
    Holoweiko M. Non-surgeons' earnings: which specialties are hung up? Medical Economics 1986;63:206–25.Google Scholar
  23. 23.
    Division of National Cost Estimates, Office of Actuary, Healthcare Financing Administration. National Healthcare Expenditures. Health Care Financing Review 1986;8:1–19.Google Scholar
  24. 24.
    Anonymous. National healthcare expenditures: 1986–2000. Health Care Financing Review 1987;8:1–36.Google Scholar
  25. 25.
    Gonzales ML, Emmons DW, eds. Socioeconomic Characteristics of Medical Practice. Chicago: Center for Health Policy Research, American Medical Association, 1986.Google Scholar
  26. 26.
    Burnstein PL, Cromwell J. Relative incomes and rates of return for US physicians. Journal of Health Economics 1985;4:63–78.Google Scholar
  27. 27.
    Marder WD, Kletke P, Filberger A, Willke RJ. Physician Supply and Utilization by Specialty: Trends and Projections. Chicago: AMA Center for Health Policy Research, 1988.Google Scholar
  28. 28.
    Luke RD, Bauer JC, eds. Issues in Health Economics. Rockville: Aspen Publication, 1982.Google Scholar
  29. 29.
    Council on Long-Range Planning and Development. The Environment of Medicine. Chicago: American Medical Association, 1985.Google Scholar
  30. 30.
    Feldstein PJ. Health Economics. New York: Wiley Medical Publication, 1979.Google Scholar
  31. 31.
    Wilensky GR, Rossiter LF. The relative importance of physician-induced demand in the demand for medical care. Milbank Q 1983;61:252–77.Google Scholar
  32. 32.
    Wennberg JE, Barnes BA, Zubkoff M. Professional uncertainty and the problem of supplier-induced demand. Soc Sci Med 1982;16:811–24.Google Scholar
  33. 33.
    Wennberg J, Gittelsohn A. Variations in medical care among small areas. Sci Am 1982;264;120–34.Google Scholar
  34. 34.
    Wennberg JE. Commentary: on patient need, equity, supplier-induced demand, and the need to assess the outcome of common medical practices. Med Care 1985;23:512–20.Google Scholar
  35. 35.
    Feldman R, Sloan F. Competition among physicians, revisited. J Health Polit Policy Law 1988;13:239–61.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1989

Authors and Affiliations

  • Karen Eschenbach
    • 1
  • Robert S. Woodward
    • 2
  1. 1.Massachusetts General Hospital, AdministrationBostonUSA
  2. 2.Health Administration ProgramWashington University School of MedicineSt. LouisUSA

Personalised recommendations