1 Introduction

In their controversial paper, Feldstein and Horioka (1980; hereafter FH) examined the relationship between the GDP share of domestic investment and the GDP share of domestic savings in a single regression analysis (FH regression) for 21 OECD countries. Their empirical studies showed that the estimated correlation, which was within 0.85–0.95, was remarkably high across countries. They interpreted their findings as indicating a high degree of financial frictions and concluded that they were inconsistent with the assumption of perfect capital mobility commonly used in studies of international finance. The idea is this. Under perfect capital mobility, if a country has excess domestic investment, capital flows will come from countries with excess savings, and vice versa. In other words, domestic investment will be uncorrelated with domestic saving. On the contrary, the FH regression showed a very high correlation. This problem is often referred to as the "Feldstein–Horioka puzzle" (FHP). Although the FHP is old, it is still an important issue. I will leave earlier research on the FHP to a detailed survey by Coakley et al. (1998), and Apergis and Tsoumas (2009) for relatively recent research.

On the other hand, many recent studies report that, despite the globalization of financial markets, investors have failed to reap its potential benefits, favoring domestic assets over international positions in their investment portfolios. This bias, known as the equity home country bias (EHB), is another major puzzle in financial economics. The measure of EHB is commonly defined as follows:

$$ EHB_i = 1 - \frac{{\text{Share of Foreign Equities in Country } i \text{ Equity Holdings}}}{{\text{Share of Foreign Equities in the World Market Portfolio}}}$$

The two issues are obviously closely related, since they are based on the idea that "financial globalization" has lowered barriers to international trade in financial assets and international capital flows. I have proposed here a new measure of home country bias. In a completely different approach from the international CAPM of previous empirical studies, I propose the following new measure:

$$HBM_i(={\beta }_{i})=\text{Corr}.(\text{Gross Domestic Saving Share of GDP in Country }\,i \, \text{,} \, \text{Gross Domestic Investment Share of GDP in Country}\,i),$$

where Corr. stands for the correlation.

In a world without financial market frictions, the international capital asset pricing model (CAPM) with homogeneous investors across the world predicts that the representative investor of a given country should hold the world market portfolio. In other words, if the EHB for country i (EHBi) is zero, the portfolio is optimally diversified along the international CAPM. Bekaert and Wang (2009) report that in the case of equities, the global average EHB was around 0.63. It has declined in the last two decades in the process of financial globalization, but remains high. A major drawback of the EHB is that it does not cover a wide range of financial asset holdings. Similar to FHP, a growing body of research examines the determinants of the EHB. Coeurdacier and Rey (2012) review the large body of research on the EHB in terms of (i) hedging motives in frictionless financial markets, (ii) asset transaction costs in international financial markets, and (iii) information frictions and behavioral biases. They refer to macroeconomic modeling that incorporates international portfolio choice as open economy financial macroeconomics. As reported in Bekaert and Wang (2009), these studies additionally propose transaction costs, real exchange rate risk, information barriers, corporate governance issues, and lack of familiarity as determinants. Because the causes of home bias are diverse, complex, and still unresolved, we focus here only on estimating an accurate measure of home bias.

That is, we estimate the home country bias as the slope coefficient β of the FH regression using ordinary least squares, called the "savings retention rate." This is considered the home country bias indicator (HBMi) in country i. This measure varies between zero and one. When it is zero, the savings–investment correlation is zero and there are complete capital flows; when it is one, the savings–investment correlation is perfect and there are no capital flows. Since the actual savings retention rate lies between 1 and 0, it can be considered an indicator of HBM. Note that the estimation of HBM faces some estimation biases, as discussed in much of the literature, which will be discussed below. To avoid this, I start to set up a representative firm’s investment behavior model, which was developed by Abel (1982), Hayashi (1982), and Summers et al. (1981) based on Tobin’s q theory. According to the System of National Accounts (SNA), gross domestic investment (GDI) comprises housing, gross private, and public investments. Among them, gross private investment predominates and plays a crucial role in GDI behavior. Therefore, I first addressed the investment behavior of a representative firm based on the saddle dynamics of investment under convex adjustment costs. Then, a dynamic panel estimation model was derived by embedding the savings retention rate: the slope coefficient beta, into the optimal investment process of the firm. We then apply dynamic panel estimation to measure the savings retention rate, the HBM in OECD countries rather than in individual countries, such as the EHB. Thus, country-specific indices are removed. Since domestic savings cover a wide range of financial asset holdings, the HBM can capture the intensity of home bias and can be considered a comprehensive measure of home bias in OECD countries. Since optimal investment behavior involves lagged investment variables, a dynamic panel regression method was used to avoid strong endogeneity problems.Footnote 1

The main results are as follows: except for the financial bubble period from 2000 to 2008, the HBM, which had steadily declined from 0.5 to 0.3 until 2000, as indicated by the EHB measured by the CAPM, returned to its previous home bias measure of 0.5 after the 2008 financial crisis. In other words, people expected the HBM to be very high after the financial crisis, but in fact it only returned to the persistent levels of the 60 s, 70 s, and 80 s.

The sections are organized as follows: Sect. 2 presents a theoretical model of the investment behavior of a representative firm. We derive an estimation model by solving the firm's optimization problem. A dynamic panel estimation model is obtained by embedding the relationship between the domestic investment share and the domestic savings share in the firm's optimal investment process expressed by the FH regression in Sect. 2.1. We also describe the data used here and apply two types of panel unit root tests in Sect. 2.2. We run dynamic panel regressions with four different specifications to estimate the measure of home bias as indicated by the savings retention rate in Sect. 2.3. Section 3 reports and discusses the estimation results. Section 4 provides a brief discussion on the results. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2 Theory and estimation equation

Consider the following optimal problem (P) of the investment behavior of representative firms in country i, developed by Abel (1982), Hayashi (1982), and Summers et al. (1981) on the basis of Tobin's q theoryFootnote 2:

$$\left(P\right)\left\{\begin{array}{c}\underset{\left\{{I}_{\mathit{it}}\right\}}{\mathrm{max}}\sum_{t=1}^{\infty }\frac{1}{{\left(1+{r}_{i}\right)}^{t}}\left({R}_{i}({k}_{it})-{I}_{it}-{C}_{i}({k}_{it})\right)\\ \\ s.t.{k}_{it}={I}_{it}+\left(1-\delta \right){k}_{it}\,and\,{k}_{i0,}\end{array}\right.$$

where \({r}_{i}\) is the discount rate (0 < \({r}_{i}\)  < 1),\({R}_{i}({k}_{it}\)\()\) is the revenue function,\({I}_{it}\) is the gross investment a\({C}_{i}({k}_{it}\)\()\) is the adjustment cost function, and i is the country index.

The problem implies that the representative firm chooses its level of investment so as to maximize the total discounted pure revenue flow, where investment increases the capital stock and raises revenues, but it pays the costs of investment adjustment as well as the investment itself.

2.1 Estimation equation

In this section, by demonstrating the saddle point stability of the model and assuming that the estimation coefficients are the same across countries, we derive the following equation for estimating investment shares, as shown below:

$${\widetilde{I}}_{it}={\beta }_{0}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+{\beta }_{1}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-2}+{\beta }_{2}{\widetilde{S}}_{it}+{\beta }_{3}{\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}$$
(1)

where \({\widetilde{I}}_{it} ({\widetilde{S}}_{it})\) is the domestic investment (saving) share of country i in period t.

The derivation of the estimation equation is explained intuitively here. I have left the detailed derivation in Appendix. In addition, to avoid complications, country-specific indicators are temporarily removed from the variables. Applying the standard solution method to the optimization problem (P), the Euler equation is derived as a necessary condition for optimality. We can also show that the transversality conditions are satisfied. The linearization of the Euler equation near the optimal steady state shows the saddle point stability. That is, there are two distinct positive real roots, and one of the two roots has an absolute value less than one. Furthermore, saddle-point stability implies that the optimal path should be on a stable path, otherwise it will diverge and eventually violate optimality. To estimate the savings retention coefficient beta, we do not directly estimate the firm's investment function, but rather use the saddle-point stability property of the optimal accumulation path.

Let \({\lambda }_{1}\) be the root satisfying \(0<{\lambda }_{1}<1\). Subsequently, the optimal path should be on a stable path, other than that it diverges. Therefore, the optimal path is expected to satisfy the following difference equations:

$$\left({k}_{t}-{k}^{*}\right)={\lambda }_{1}\left({k}_{t-1}-{k}^{*}\right) for\ all\ t\ge 1.$$
(2)

From Eq. (2), subtraction to eliminate \({k}^{*}\) gives

$$\left\{\begin{array}{c}\left({k}_{t}-{k}_{t-1}\right)={\lambda }_{1}\left({k}_{t-1}-{k}_{t-2}\right)\\ \\ \left({k}_{t-1}-{k}_{t-2}\right)={\lambda }_{1}\left({k}_{t-2}-{k}_{t-3}\right)\end{array}\right.$$

From the capital accumulation equations, it follows that

$$\left\{\begin{array}{c}{(I}_{t}-{I}_{t-1})=\left({k}_{t}-{k}_{t-1}\right)-(1-\delta )\left({k}_{t-1}-{k}_{t-2}\right)\\ \\ {(I}_{t}-{I}_{t-2})=\left({k}_{t}-{k}_{t-2}\right)-(1-\delta )\left({k}_{t-2}-{k}_{t-3}\right)\end{array}\right.$$

Combining both relations will readily give the difference equation:

$$\left({I}_{t}-{I}_{t-1}\right)={\lambda }_{1}\left({I}_{t-1}-{I}_{t-2}\right).$$

Finally, we obtain the following equation along the saddle-point path as the optimal investment behavior:

$${I}_{t}=\left(1+{\lambda }_{1}\right){I}_{t-1}-{\lambda }_{1}{I}_{t-2}.$$
(3)

Equation (3) must then be rewritten in terms of the GDP share originally used in FH (1980). To do so, I assume that a country's average GDP growth rate over the observation period, denoted by \(g\), is a constant average growth rate over the observation period and \(0 < g < 1\). In fact, the average GDP growth rate for OECD countries has been stable at around 0.02–0.04 (2–4%) over the past 40 years, supporting this assumption.

Dividing both sides by regarding \({Y}_{t}={GDP}_{t}\) gives

$$\frac{{I}_{t}}{{Y}_{t}}=\left(1+{\lambda }_{1}\right)\left(\frac{{Y}_{t-1}}{{Y}_{t}}\right)\left(\frac{{I}_{t-1}}{{Y}_{t-1}}\right)-{\lambda }_{1}\left(\frac{{Y}_{t-2}}{{Y}_{t}}\right)\left(\frac{{I}_{t-2}}{{Y}_{t-2}}\right).$$

Because \({Y}_{t+1}=(1+g){Y}_{t}\), the following theoretical model will be obtained:

$$\frac{{I}_{t}}{{Y}_{t}}=\frac{(1+{\lambda }_{1})}{(1+g)}\left(\frac{{I}_{t-1}}{{Y}_{t-1}}\right)-\frac{{\lambda }_{1}}{{\left(1+g\right)}^{2}}\left(\frac{{I}_{t-2}}{{Y}_{t}}\right)=\frac{\left(1+{\lambda }_{1}\right)}{\left(1+g\right)}{\widetilde{I}}_{t-1}-\frac{{\lambda }_{1}}{{\left(1+g\right)}^{2}}{\widetilde{I}}_{t-2}.$$

Finally, taking the country indices of the variables again and assuming that the coefficients are common across countries, it follows that

$${\widetilde{I}}_{it}={\beta }_{0}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+{\beta }_{1}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-2}$$
(4)

, where \({\beta }_{0}=\frac{(1+{\lambda }_{1i})}{(1+{g}_{i})}\mathrm{\,and\,}{\beta }_{1}=\frac{{\lambda }_{1i}}{{(1+{g}_{i})}^{2}}\).

Due to the definition of the home country bias measure defined in the introduction, the FH regression satisfies; \({\widetilde{I}}_{it}=\alpha +\beta {\widetilde{S}}_{it}\) it follows that

$${\widetilde{I}}_{it}-{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}=\beta ({\widetilde{S}}_{it}-{\widetilde{S}}_{it-1})=\beta {\widetilde{S}}_{it}+(-\beta ){\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}\Rightarrow {\widetilde{I}}_{it}={\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+\beta {\widetilde{S}}_{it}+(-\beta ){\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}$$
(5)

Combining Eqs. (4) and (5) finally yields the following estimation equation:

$${\widetilde{I}}_{it}={\beta }_{0}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+{\beta }_{1}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-2}+\beta {\widetilde{S}}_{it}+(-\beta ){\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}={\beta }_{0}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+{\beta }_{1}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-2}+ {\beta }_{2}{\widetilde{S}}_{it}+{\beta }_{3}{\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}$$
(6)

Since \(0 <{\lambda }_{1}< 1\) holds, it follows that the sign conditions of Eq. (1) imply that \((i) 0<{\beta }_{0}\), \((ii) -1<{\beta }_{1}<0\), and \({(iii) \beta }_{2}={-\beta }_{3}\) should hold.

Adding disturbance terms to Eq. (1) yields the following dynamic panel regression equation:

$${\widetilde{I}}_{it}={\beta }_{0}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-1}+{\beta }_{1}{\widetilde{I}}_{it-2}+ {\beta }_{2}{\widetilde{S}}_{it}+{\beta }_{3}{\widetilde{S}}_{it-1}+{\gamma }_{i}+{u}_{it},$$
(7)

where i = country index, t = time index, \({\widetilde{I}}_{it}\) is the domestic investment share of GDP, \({\widetilde{S}}_{it}\) is the domestic saving share of GDP, \({u}_{it}\) is the error term (shocks and effect of frictions), and \({\gamma }_{i}\) is the a specific effect of the country.

We continue to assume that the coefficients are the same across countries and that country-specific shocks are included in \({\gamma }_{i}\). Note that the deterministic part of the above model is derived based on the investment model of a fully rational firm; therefore, the error term indicates the impact of the various fundamental shocks and capital market frictions.

Note also that the signs of the coefficients in (7) must satisfy the following constraints (CI) and (CII) of the theoretical model described in Sect. 2.1.

(CI) \({\beta }_{0}\) and \({\beta }_{1}\) statistically significant and satisfy \((i) 0<{\beta }_{0}\) and \((ii) -1<{\beta }_{1}<0\).

(CII) \({\beta }_{0}\) and \({\beta }_{1}\) statistically significant, and \({(iii) \beta }_{2}={-\beta }_{3}.\)

If (CII) does not hold, then the estimates should not be considered as those of the savings retention coefficient (β). As mentioned earlier, β is a clear index of the HBM that indicates the impact of the domestic savings rate on domestic investment behavior.

2.2 Estimation methods

The regression equation (7) includes lagged dependent variables as independent variables, as well as the country-specific effect. As a result, standard ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation is highly biased. To circumvent this problem, we apply dynamic panel estimation (DPE), developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Arellano and Bover (1995), under the condition that all estimators are stationary. Four specifications of DPE are used for each data set: one-step difference GMM, two-step difference GMM, one-step system GMM, and two-step system GMM.

A brief description of these estimation methods is given in Appendix. Although they are powerful, one should be wary of weak instruments and overidentification problems. Indeed, DPEs are known to easily generate a large number of instruments. To check for these problems, two important statistics are reported in the results. For the weak instrument problem, the Arellano–Bond AR(1) test (A–B AR(1)) and the Arellano–Bond AR(2) test (A–B AR(2)) for the first and second serial correlations are reported; for the overidentification problem, the Hansen test for overidentification of instruments is reported. To avoid the weak instrument problem, the A–B AR(1) test must reject the null hypothesis of "no serial correlation". Conversely, for the A–B AR(2) test, the null hypothesis must be accepted. For the overidentification problem, the null hypothesis of "no overidentification" must be accepted for the Hansen J test. For the GMM system, the result of the difference-in-Hansen test was reported for the validity of the additional moment restriction. After checking these diagnostic tests, the estimates must satisfy the sign condition (CI). The Wald test was then applied to examine the test condition (CII). In the end, the estimates that pass all of the above diagnostic tests are selected.

I estimated the following four cases, and the results are reported in Table 2 through Table 7.

Case 1: Exact replication of the FHP estimation

Data: Gross national investment GDP share and gross saving GDP share

Period: 1960–1974

Countries: 21 OECD countries

Case 2: Replication studies of the FHP estimation

Data: Gross national investment GDP share and gross saving GDP share

Period: 1960–1974

Countries: 28 OECD countries

Case 3: Ten-year sub-samples

Data: Same as Case 2

Period: 1960–1969, 1970–1979, 1980–1989, 1990–1999

Countries: 28 OECD countries

Case 4: Breaks in 2000s.

Data: Same as Case 2

Period: 2000–2008, 2009–2014, 2000–2014

Countries:28 OECD countries

Cases 1 and 2 were implemented only to compare our results with the original FH (1980) results and to shed light on the long-term controversies of the FHP.

2.3 Data and stationarity

All data were extracted from the national accounts in Penn World Table Ver. 9. The derivation of the gross domestic investment share, the gross domestic saving share, and the economic openness index is explained in detail in Appendix. Note that the economic openness index was used only as a standard instrumental variable, not as a GMM instrument variable. Two panel data sets were constructed. One was an annual panel data set consisting of 21 countries from 1960 to 2014 to examine only Case 1 and replicate the original regression of FH (1980), and the other was an annual panel data set consisting of 28 countries for the same period to examine Cases 2 to 4. Each data set is a balanced panel data set.

One of the key assumptions for the application of DPE is the stationarity of the series. To investigate this, the first- and second-generation panel unit root tests were conducted. Although we did not report the results table of the first-generation panel unit root tests in this study, five different first-generation panel unit root tests were conducted during the estimation period (1960–2014): the Levin-Lin-Chu, Harris-Tzavalis, Breitung, Im-Pesaran-Shin (IPS), and Fisher-type panel unit root tests. As shown by Hlouskova and Wagner (2006), the performance of the Hadri-LM unit root test is poor; therefore, it was not run here. As a result of the test, both the null hypothesis that the panel has a unit root and the null hypothesis that all panels have a unit root were strongly rejected for the panel data of 28 countries. However, for the panel data of 21 countries, the test results were mixed, especially for the series of domestic saving shares.

Since country-specific data were used here, we need to pay attention to correlations across countries. Therefore, the second-generation panel unit root test proposed by Pesaran (2007), called cross-sectionally augmented IPS (CIPS), was repeated with three different ADFs for each estimation period from Case 1 to Case 4, and the results are presented in Table 1.

Table 1 Panel unit root test

Because the critical value of the t-statistic varies depending on the type of ADF, as noted in the notes to Table 1, the results of the hypothesis tests at the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are indicated only by an asterisk. According to Table 1, the two main series \(\left({\widetilde{I}}_{it},{\widetilde{S}}_{it}\right)\) were stationary overall, although some tests were rejected at the 10% significance level. However, the estimates from 2000 to 2014 in case 4 may be spurious, as the domestic savings series were not stationary in any of the three ADF types. We should be cautious about this case.

3 Estimation results

One-step and two-step difference GMMs were used. To capture changes in economic structure, only the economic openness index (eco_open) was used as a standard instrumental variable, following FH (1980). In this section, the estimation results for cases 1 to 4 are discussed as follows.

3.1 Replications of FH estimations

We examine the HP estimates for cases 1 and 2. We examine the HP estimates for cases 1 and 2.

3.1.1 Case 1

Table 2 reports the exact results of the 21-country replication estimation for case 1. For this case, I applied one-step and two-step difference GMMs with collapsed instruments, with and without a constant term. The results are reported in columns (1) and (3), and the one- and two-step system GMMs are reported in columns (2) and (4), respectively, of Table 2. The Arellano–Bond AR(1) and AR(2) tests showed a weak instrument problem for columns (1) to (4). All overidentification test results were satisfactory. Since column (3) of Table 2 satisfied the sign condition (CI), I chose it as our estimate for case 1. As a result, the estimated beta is 0.71, which is still large but slightly smaller than the FH estimate of 0.89–0.95. However, it should be noted that this estimate has some bias due to the weak instrument problem. Thus, the conclusion is that there were no robust estimates in the exact replication case 1.

Table 2 Exact replication of the FHP

3.1.2 Case 2

The replication estimation for 28 countries is done in the same way as in case 1. The results for case 2 are presented in Table 3. For this case, I used one- and two-stage differences GMMs with collapsed instruments, with and without a constant term. The results are reported in columns (1) and (3) of Table 3, and the one- and two-step system GMMs are reported in columns (2) and (4) of Table 3, respectively. The Arellano–Bond AR(1) and AR(2) tests showed a weak instrument problem for columns (1) and (2). All overidentification test results were satisfactory. Column (3) of Table 3 was selected as our benchmark result of the case, because all sign conditions i) through iii) derived from the theoretical model were satisfied. As a result, the estimate of the HBM reproduced in this case was 0.52, which was much smaller than FH's original estimate: 0.89–0.95. Since all the statistical requirements were well met, we choose 0.52 as the benchmark value for the estimated HBM in the replication period.Footnote 3

Table 3 Replication of the FHP

3.2 HBM estimates in cases 3 and 4

We continue estimating HBM in cases 3 and 4 here.

3.2.1 Case 3

The estimation results are presented in Table 4, columns (1) to (3), where a one-step difference or one-step system GMM is applied. For the observation period of the 1990s, the one-step system GMM was applied, as reported in column (4) of Table 4. In addition, the two-step system GMM was applied to case 2. The results are shown in Table 5. For the results of columns (2) and (3) in Table 4, the sign of is not statistically significant. Consequently, the estimates of beta in columns (2) and (3) are not considered as savings retention coefficients, as discussed earlier. In contrast, in Table 5, conditions (i) and (ii) on the sign of the coefficients are all satisfied. Condition (iii) is also satisfied, except for the estimates in column (3). Thus, overall, the required sign conditions (CI) and (CII) are satisfied and robust. In addition, the tests for weak instrument and overidentification yielded positive results. In summary, our test statistics indicate a proper specification.

Table 4 Sample by 10 years
Table 5 Sample by 10 years with two-step system GMM

Table 6 summarizes the HBM estimates measured over a 40-year period. The table shows that the beta values were almost the same in the 1960s and 1970s, but declined significantly in the 1980s and 1990s. This finding is consistent with the results reported by Georgopoulos and Hejazi (2005) and But and Morley (2017). This may be partly due to the opening up of the economy and financial market integration in the 1980s and 1990s, which led to increased capital mobility and a decline in HBM.

Table 6 HBM estimates over the past 40 years

3.2.2 Case 4

We estimated the HBM not only for the entire observation period 2000–2014, but also for two subperiods, 2000–2008 and 2009–2014. The main reason for using 2008 as the breakpoint year was the financial crisis of 2008. Table 7 reports the estimation results from 2000 to 2014 with 2008 as the breakpoint year. All of the estimates are statistically significant. It is important to note that the estimates were insignificant before the breakpoint year and then became significant again after the breakpoint year. The estimates in columns (1) and (2) of Table 7 show that they became insignificant over the period 2000–2008. In other words, one could say that the home country bias temporarily disappeared during this period. In addition, it is very interesting to note that the period in which the home bias disappeared coincided with a period of a global financial bubble (2000–2008). This implies that the declining trend of the HBM continued in 2000–2008. Indeed, Coeurdacier and Rey (2012) calculate the EBH separately for cross-border bonds, cross-border bank loans, and cross-regional bank assets and find that all three measures of home bias declined between 1999 and 2008. In contrast, column (3) of Table 7 shows that the relationship between savings and investment returns after 2008, with an estimated HBM of 0.51, is similar to that in the 1960s and 1970s. Interestingly, But and Morley (2017) report a similar fact. As mentioned above, the series of the domestic saving share was non-stationary between 2000 and 2014, so the result in column (4) of Table 7 may be spurious.

Table 7 Break sample in 2000s

In summary, the empirical results reported in Table 2 through Table 7 are as follows.

  1. A.

    An exact replication of the FHP in 21 OECD countries during 1964–1974 yielded an estimate of 0.71, high enough to support the FH result, but with some bias due to weak instrument problems.

  2. B.

    Replication of the FHP in the 28 OECD countries during 1964–1974 yielded an estimated HBM of 0.52, which was much smaller than the FH (1980) estimate of 0.89.

  3. C.

    Estimates using samples for every 10 years during 1960–1999 showed that the HBM gradually decreased from 0.57 to 0.32.

  4. D.

    From 2000 to 2014, the estimated HMB was not statistically significant from 2000 to 2008. It was only after 2008 that it became statistically significant, with an estimated HBM of 0.51 from 2009 to 2014, which is comparable to that of the 1960s and 1970s.

4 Discussion

Our results A) through D) above have the following three important implications. A) and B) implies that the robust estimate of the HBM is 0.52, which is much lower than the 0.89 of the originally estimated by FH (1980). C) shows that the HBM has declined steadily from 0.52 to 0.33 over the last four decades until 2000. Furthermore, D) shows that the correlation between savings and investment temporarily disappeared during the era of globalization and the financial bubble years from 2000 to 2008. The HBM turned 0.51 from 2009 to 2014. These results clearly indicate that despite the fact that globalization has accelerated the integration of international financial markets in recent decades, the home country bias is still significant from 2009 to 2014 in OECD countries. The last fact is particularly interesting: the home bias had been declining steadily until 2008, but after the 2008 financial crisis, it returned to the HBM of 0.5. In other words, after the financial crisis, people expected the home bias measure to be very high, but in fact it ended up returning to the levels of the '60 s and '70 s.

5 Conclusion

In this study, we have focused on investigating the home country bias puzzle: although recent financial globalization has lowered barriers to international trade in financial assets and international capital flows, we still observe relatively high home country bias in advanced countries. The EHB based on the international CAPM supports this for equities. Indeed, the EHB measure showed that it had declined over the past two decades and was about 0.63 globally. However, it was unclear whether this was true for a wide range of financial assets beyond equities. To investigate this issue, we introduced the HBM based on the FH regression. Note that since we use the country's domestic saving, it includes all types of asset holdings. We show that in OECD countries, the HBM declined over the four decades until the 2008 financial crisis and returned to 0.50 after the crisis. Our estimation results clearly support those of the EHB (Table 7).

Finally, we leave the study of the main source of home bias to other studies, but to determine this, we need to investigate how each economic factor affects the savings retention coefficient. A promising econometric approach would be to apply the dynamic panel threshold analysis proposed by Seo and Shin (2016). This should be on the agenda for future research.