Skip to main content
Log in

The q-factor model and the redundancy of the value factor: An application to hedge funds

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Asset Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We test the new Fama and French five-factor model on a sample of hedge fund strategies. This model embeds the q-factor asset pricing model which lies on the CMA and RMW factors. We find that the HML factor is not redundant for many strategies, as conjectured by Fama and French in their setting. HML seems to embed risk dimensions which are not included in the Fama and French new factors. In contrast to Fama and French, the α puzzle is robust to the addition of CMA and RMW. Furthermore, hedge funds seem to prefer, on the one hand, firms which invest a lot to firms which invest less, and, on the other hand, weak firms over robust ones. Finally, our results are not sensitive to the addition of the Fung and Hsieh seven-factor model. However, the explanatory power of the eleven-factor model is much higher for some hedge fund strategies involved in arbitrage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. CMA is the abbreviation for ‘conservative minus aggressive’ – that is, a portfolio which is long in stocks of firms with a low ratio of investment to assets and short in stocks of firms with a high ratio of investment to assets.

  2. RMW is the abbreviation for ‘robust minus weak’ – that is, a portfolio which is long in stocks of robust firms in terms of profitability and short in stocks of weak firms in terms of profitability.

  3. HML is the abbreviation for ‘high minus low’ – that is, a portfolio which is long in stocks of firms having a high book-to-market ratio and short in stocks of firms having a low book-to-market ratio.

  4. SMB is the abbreviation for ‘small minus big’ – that is, a portfolio which is long in stocks of small firms and long in stocks of big firms.

  5. More precisely, firms overinvest when they are in financial distress and expect that projects with positive VAN may rescue them. By doing so, they expropiate their debt stakeholders.

  6. Even if they consider that the factors of their model – including market risk premium, SMB and HML – are measured with errors, Hou et al (2015) and Fama and French (2015) do not ‘instrument’ factors to tackle the problem related to measurement errors. Their objective, as ours, is to study the interaction between factors. Replacing factors with instruments is inconsistent with this objective since it creates interactions per se which are not related to our goal. Moreover, introducing more factors – that is, CMA and RMW – in the original Fama and French three-factor model is a way to reduce the co-movement of the original three factors with the innovation of the empirical model, which creates the problem related to errors-in-variables. This interaction will be partly taken into account by CMA and RMW. It is precisely the object of our paper to study the interaction between old and new factors.

  7. Note that Fama and French (2015) do not introduce the momentum factor (UMD) proposed by Carhart (1997) and the liquidity factor proposed by Pástor and Stambaugh (2003) in their new asset pricing model. They justify this omission by the fact that these two factors have regression slopes close to zero in their experiments so they decided to discard them. According to Fama and French (2015), these factors produce trivial changes in model performance.

  8. Note that investment represents a decrease in the book value of equity (B t) – that is, an expense or a negative cash-flow. Instead of putting ΔB in equation (4), Miller and Modigliani (1961) put I in their original equation – that is, equation (9) in their 1961 article.

  9. The address of French’s website is: http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html.

  10. The address of Hsieh database is: https://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/~dah7/HFData.htm.

  11. Note that there are more sophisticated ways to account for return smoothing. See Getmansky et al (2004) and Brown et al (2012).

  12. Excepting the futures strategy.

  13. Note that we list only the strategies which have a significant exposure to HML in the Fama and French three-factor model.

  14. That is, the model including the market risk premium, SMB, CMA and RMW.

  15. When excluding HML.

References

  • Bali, T.G., Brown, S.J. and Caglayan, M.O. (2014) Macroeconomic risk and hedge fund returns. Journal of Financial Economics 114(1): 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, S.J., Gregoriou, G. and Pascalau, R. (2012) It is possible to overdiversify? The case of funds of hedge funds. Review of Asset Pricing Studies 2(1): 89–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carhart, M. (1997) On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52(1): 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, N., Getmansky, M., Haas, S.M. and Lo, A.W. (2007) Systemic Risk and Hedge Funds. Cambridge, MA: NBER, Working Paper.

  • Chen, J. and Tindal, M.L. (2012) Hedge Fund Dynamic Market Sensitivity, Occasional Paper 12-01, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Dallas, Tx.

  • Cochrane, J. (1991) Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and economic fluctuations. Journal of Finance 46(1): 209–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeJong, D.N. and Dave, C. (2007) Structural Macroeconometrics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1993) Common risk factors and the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33(1): 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (2015) A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial Economics 116(1): 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fazzari, S., Hubbard, R.G. and Petersen, B. (1988) Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1988(1): 141–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1930) The Theory of Interest: As Determined by Impatience to Spend Income and Opportunity to Invest it, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fung, W. and Hsieh, D.A. (1997) Empirical characteristics of dynamic trading strategies: The case of hedge funds. Review of Financial Studies 10(2): 275–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fung, W. and Hsieh, D.A. (2001) The risk in hedge fund strategies: Theory and evidence from trend followers. Review of Financial Studies 14(2): 313–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fung, W. and Hsieh, D.A. (2004) Hedge fund benchmarks: A risk based approach. Financial Analysts Journal 60(5): 65–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Getmansky, M., Lo, A.W. and Makarov, I. (2004) An econometric model of serial correlation and illiquidity in hedge fund returns. Journal of Financial Economics 74(3): 529–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou, K., Xue, C. and Zhang, L. (2015) Digesting anomalies: An investment approach. Review of Financial Studies 28(3): 650–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, M. and Modigliani, F. (1961) Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares. Journal of Business 34(4): 411–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okunev, J. and White, D. (2003) Hedge Fund Risk Factors and Value at Risk of Credit Trading Strategies. Working Paper. New South Wales, Sydney: University of New South Wales.

  • Pástor, L. and Stambaugh, R. (2003) Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal of Political Economy 111(3): 642–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Racicot, F.-É. and Théoret, R. (2015) Procyclical behavior of hedge funds: A portfolio mananger and investor’s perspective. Alternative Investment Analyst Review (CAIA) 3(4): 52–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Racicot, F.-É. and Théoret, R. (2016) Macroeconomic shocks, forward-looking dynamics, and the behavior of hedge funds. Journal of Banking and Finance 62: 41–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, J.P. and Worrall, T. (2014) Dynamic Relational Contracts Under Complete Information. Working Paper. Edinburgh, Scotland: University of Edinburgh.

  • Tobin, J. (1969) A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1(1): 15–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the seminar participants at the SFA Annual Meeting held in November 2015.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to François-Éric Racicot.

Additional information

1is a professor of finance and econometrics at the Telfer School of Management, University of Ottawa. His research interests focus on the problems of measurement errors, specification errors and endogeneity in financial models of returns. He is also interested in developing new methods used for forecasting financial time series – especially hedge fund measures of risk. He has published several books and articles in quantitative finance and financial econometrics. He is an advisory board member of Aestimatio, the IEB International Journal of Finance and an editorial board member of the Journal of Asset Management (JAM) and Journal of Derivatives & Hedge Funds (merged with JAM). He is an associate member of the Groupe de Recherche en Finance Appliquée (GReFA), University of Sherbrooke; the CGA-Canada Accounting and Governance Research Center (CGA-AGRC) and the Corporate Reporting Chair (ESG-UQAM).

2holds a PhD in Economics (financial economics) issued by the University of Montreal. He is full Professor of Finance at the Business School (ESG) of the University of Quebec, Montreal (UQAM). His articles appeared in the following journals: The Journal of Derivatives & Hedge Funds; The Journal of Banking and Finance; The Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money; Applied Economics; Managerial Finance; Review of Economics & Finance; Applied Financial Economics; The Journal of Asset Management; The Journal of Wealth Management; International Advances in Economic Research; L’Actualité Économique; Journal of Theoretical Accounting Research; Luxembourg Economic Papers and Journal of Risk and Insurance. He is member of the Corporate Reporting Chair (ESG-UQAM).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Racicot, FÉ., Théoret, R. The q-factor model and the redundancy of the value factor: An application to hedge funds. J Asset Manag 17, 526–539 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/jam.2016.22

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jam.2016.22

Keywords

Navigation