Skip to main content
Log in

Policy Cooperation, Incomplete Markets, and Risk Sharing

  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper derives “targeting rules” for optimal policy in a simple two-country model in which financial markets are incomplete and policy is noncooperative. The optimal rules are compared with the cooperative case. Although the model is simple, it is complex enough so that the distortion introduced by incomplete financial markets matters. The complete markets case serves as a benchmark. Under complete markets, it is shown that the policy response in one state of the world influences outcomes in all other states through the effect on asset prices. It is noted that monetary policy cannot replicate an optimal tariff, so that the absence of a tariff instrument is a distortion even in the complete-markets economy. We show that optimal policy, even under complete markets and cooperation, does not try to minimize spillovers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. That is, undistorted assuming that there was an appropriate constant subsidy to output to alleviate the underproduction that arises in the model from the monopoly power of producers.

  2. This wedge corresponds to the labor market wedge in the macroeconomics literature. See, for example, Hall (1997), Gali and others (2007), or Chari and others (2007).

  3. The numeraire for state contingent claims is irrelevant. We express things in nominal terms here so that the model can be easily generalized to the sticky nominal price case.

  4. See Senay and Sutherland (2007, 2013) for a comparison of optimal policy in models with asset trade, in the cases of commitment vs. discretionary policy (policy chosen after portfolios have been set).

  5. The Appendix derives the solution to the model under balanced trade and complete markets, in terms of productivity shocks and the employment subsidy.

  6. Hereinafter, we omit the state subscript j when there is no possibility of confusion.

  7. See Engel and Matsumoto (2009) and Heathcote and Perri (2013) for examples of similar models where there is substantial home bias in equity holdings when nonstate-contingent bonds are also traded.

  8. These derivations and results correspond to those in Corsetti, Dedola, and Leduc (2011a).

  9. In order to take these differences, it is important that the log linearizations in both cases of incomplete and complete markets are around the same steady state.

  10. See Corsetti, Dedola, and Leduc (2011b), Engel (2014) and Bhattarai, Lee, and Park (2015) for examples of dynamic two-country New Keynesian models with incomplete markets, where policymaking under cooperation is considered.

  11. These steps draw on the Appendix of Devereux and Engel (2003).

References

  • Benigno, Pierpaolo, 2002, “A Simple Approach to International Monetary Policy Coordination,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 57, No. 1, pp. 177–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno, Gianluca and Pierpaolo Benigno, 2003, “Price Stability in Open Economies,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 70, No. 4, pp. 743–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, Ben S., 2012, “U.S. Monetary Policy and International Implications.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Speech at the “Challenges of the Global Financial System: Risks and Governance under Evolving Globalization,” sponsored by Bank of Japan-International Monetary Fund, Tokyo, Japan.

  • Bhattarai, Saroj, Jae Won Lee, and Woong Yong Park, 2015, “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Currency Union with Interest Rate Spreads,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 96, No. 2, pp. 375–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., J.D. Ostry, and A.R. Ghosh, 2013, “International Policy Coordination: The Loch Ness Monster,” International Monetary Fund, IMFDirect.

  • Canzoneri, Matthew and Dale Henderson, 1991, Monetary Policy in Interdependent Economies: A Game Theoretic Approach (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri, Matthew, Robert Cumby, and Behzad Diba, 2005, “The Need for International Policy Coordination: What’s Old? What’s New? and What’s Yet to Come?,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 66, No. 2, pp. 363–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V.V., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Ellen R. McGrattan, 2007, “Business Cycle Accounting,” Econometrica, Vol. 75, No. 3, pp. 781–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler, 2002, “A Simple Framework for International Monetary Policy Analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, No. 5, pp. 879–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, Harold L. and Maurice Obstfeld, 1991, “Commodity Trade and International Risk Sharing: How Much Do Financial Markets Matter?,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 28, No. 1, pp. 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, Richard, 1985, “Economic Interdependence and Coordination of Economic Policies,” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by Ronald Jones and Peter Kenen (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti, Giancarlo and Paolo Pesenti, 2005, “International Dimensions of Optimal Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 52, No. 2, pp. 281–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, Luca Dedola, and Sylvain Leduc, 2011a, “Optimal Monetary Policies in Open Economies,” in Handbook of Monetary Economics, Vol. 3, ed. by Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael Woodford (Amsterdam: Elsevier).

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, Luca Dedola, and Sylvain Leduc, 2011b, “Demand Imbalances, Exchange-Rate Misalignments, and Monetary Policy,” Working paper (Cambridge University).

  • de Paoli, Bianca, 2009, “Monetary Policy and Welfare in a Small Open Economy,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 77, No. 1, pp. 11–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, Michael B. and Charles Engel, 2003, “Monetary Policy in the Open Economy Revisited: Exchange Rate Flexibility and Price Setting Behavior,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 70, No. 4, pp. 765–803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, Charles, 2011, “Currency Misalignments and Optimal Monetary Policy: A Reexamination,” American Economic Review, Vol. 101, No. 6, pp. 2796–2822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, Charles, 2014, “Exchange Rate Stabilization and Welfare,” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 6, pp. 155–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, Charles, 2016, “International Coordination of Central Bank Policy,” Journal of International Money and Finance, forthcoming.

  • Engel, Charles and Akito Matsumoto, 2009, “The International Diversification Puzzle when Goods Prices are Sticky: It’s Really about Exchange-Rate Hedging, not Equity Portfolios,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 2, pp. 155–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Financial Times, 2010, “Brazil in ‘Currency War’ Alert,” September 27.

  • Fischer, Stanley, 2014, “The Federal Reserve and the Global Economy,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Speech at the Per Jacobsson Foundation Lecture, 2014 Annual Meetings of the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank Group, Washington, DC.

  • Gali, Jordi and Tommaso Monacelli, 2005, “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 72, No. 3, pp. 707–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali, Jordi, Mark Gertler, and J. David Lopez-Salido, 2007, “Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare Costs of Business Fluctuations,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 89, No. 1, pp. 44–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Robert E., 1997, “Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Allocation of Time,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. S223–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamada, Koichi, 1974, “Alternative Exchange Rate Systems and the Interdependence of Monetary Policies,” in National Monetary Policies and the International Financial System, ed. by Robert Aliber (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamada, Koichi, 1976, “A Strategic Analysis of Monetary Interdependence,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84, No. 4, pp. 677–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamada, Koichi, 1979, “Macroeconomic Strategy and Coordination under Alternative Exchange Rates,” in International Economic Policy, ed. by Rudiger Dornbusch and Jacob Frenkel (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Heathcote, Jonathan and Fabrizio Perri, 2013, “The International Diversification Puzzle is Not as Bad as You Think,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 121, No. 6, pp. 1108–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 1995, “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, No. 3, pp. 624–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 1996, Foundations of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 2000, “New Directions for Stochastic Open Economy Models,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp. 117–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 2002a, “Risk and Exchange Rates,” in Contemporary Economic Policy: Essays in Honor of Assaf Razin, ed. by Elhanan Helpman and Efraim Sadka (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 2002b, “Global Implications of Self-Oriented National Monetary Rules,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 2, pp. 503–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostry, Jonathan D. and Atish R. Ghosh, 2013, “Obstacles to International Policy Coordination and How to Overcome Them,” IMF Staff Discussion Note 13/11. (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).

  • Pappa, Evi, 2004, “Do the ECB and the Fed Really Need to Cooperate? Optimal Monetary Policy in a Two-Country World,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp. 753–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 1995, “Double-Edged Incentives: Institutions and Policy Coordination,” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3, ed. by Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, Raghuram, 2014, Competitive Monetary Easing: Is It Yesterday Once More? (Reserve Bank of India).

    Google Scholar 

  • Senay, Ozge and Alan Sutherland, 2007, “Optimal Monetary Policy and the Timing of Asset Trade in Open Economies,” Economic Letters, Vol. 95, No. 2, pp. 297–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senay, Ozge and Alan Sutherland, 2013, “The Timing of Asset Trade and Optimal Policy in Dynamic Open Economies,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 17, No. 8, pp. 1543–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*This paper was prepared for the Jacques Pollak Annual Research Conference, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, November 13–14, 2014. The author acknowledges research support from NSF grant # 1226007. He thanks Mick Devereux, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Linda Tesar, Anton Korinek, reviewers for the IMF Economic Review, and participants at the conference at the IMF and seminars at Wisconsin and Johns Hopkins for helpful comments. Charles Engel is the Hester Professor of Economics at the University of Wisconsin.

Appendix

Appendix

Derivation of Equilibrium under Complete Markets

Here, we solve for the ratio of Lagrange multipliers, λ/λ*, in Equation (10).Footnote 11 From the zero profit condition under free entry in competitive markets and the budget constraint (equation (4)), using the definition of profits (equation (7)), we have:

Then using the equilibrium condition (equation (12)) and the demand equations (2) and (3), we can write this equation as:

Multiply by the price of contingent claims, sum up over states, and recall ∑ Z j D j =0, to get:

Then use the first-order conditions (equations (5) and (6)) to write

Substituting into the previous expression, we find:

Solution to Model in Terms of Productivity Shocks and Labor Subsidies

The equivalent equation to Equation (11) for the Foreign country is given by:

Using this equation and Equation (11), we find:

Then using Equation (18), the trade-balance equation, we can derive:

Substitute this equation back into Equation (11) and we find:

Analogously, for the Foreign country, we have:

Under complete markets, we can combine Equation (A.3) with the condition for equilibrium (equation (16)) to find:

We can use this to derive:

Also, using Equations (11), (A.2), and (A.7) and (A.8), we find:

From these expressions, we can solve:

This expression can be substituted into Equations (A.8), (A.9) and (A.10) to complete the characterization of the solution.

As noted in the text, there are two well-known cases in which the balanced-trade and complete-markets solution are the same. The first is when σ=1, in which case we find

The second case is when ν=1, in which case we find

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Engel, C. Policy Cooperation, Incomplete Markets, and Risk Sharing. IMF Econ Rev 64, 103–133 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2016.2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2016.2

JEL Classifications

Navigation