Skip to main content
Log in

The Poverty Focus of Swedish Bilateral Aid: A Comparative Analysis

  • Original Article
  • Published:
The European Journal of Development Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article considers the poverty focus of Swedish bilateral aid from a comparative perspective. Using data on aid disbursements to 106 developing countries between 2010 and 2012, it constructs aid concentration curves for Sweden, three other major bilateral donors and the Development Assistance Committee (DAC). Sweden’s bilateral aid is shown to be less poverty and deprivation focused than the aid programmes of Denmark and the United Kingdom, but more progressive than those of the United States and the DAC. While Sweden does well in targeting its aid to low-income countries, around half of its priority development cooperation partners are small middle-income countries in which relatively few poor or deprived people live. There is therefore scope to improve the poverty focus of Swedish bilateral aid in the future.

Abstract

Cet article examine l’accent que l’aide bilatérale suédoise met sur la pauvreté, dans une perspective comparative. En utilisant des données sur les décaissements de l’aide au développement à 106 pays en développement entre 2010 et 2012, cette étude construit les courbes de concentration de l’aide au développement pour la Suède, trois autres bailleurs bilatéraux importants, et le Comité d’aide au développement (CAD). L’aide bilatérale suédoise se révèle être moins axée sur la pauvreté et sur la fragilité financière que les programmes d’aide au développement du Danemark et du Royaume-Uni, mais plus progressive que l’aide bilatérale des Etats-Unis et du CAD. Bien que la Suède réussisse à cibler les pays à faible revenu pour l’allocation de son aide bilatérale, environ la moitié de ses partenaires prioritaires de coopération au développement est constituée de petits pays à revenu intermédiaire dans lesquels vivent relativement peu de personnes pauvres ou en situation de fragilité financière. Il est donc possible à l’avenir d’améliorer l’accent que l’aide bilatérale suédoise met sur la pauvreté.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7
Figure 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Following the seminal work of World Bank (1998) and Collier and Dollar (2002) showing that aid is more effective in the presence of ‘good’ policies, there has been considerable debate on whether there should be greater policy selectivity in aid allocation decisions. As we do not consider policy selectivity, this article does not aim to contribute to this debate.

  2. When the cumulative percentage of aid is plotted against the cumulative percentage of the population of developing countries, aid concentration curves are also called ‘aid Lorenz curves’ as in White and McGillivray (1995). The term aid concentration curve is more precise because a Lorenz curve should not cross the leading diagonal.

  3. See Appendix for further information on the calculation and interpretation of the Suits index.

  4. The relatively small share of ODA received by India reflects both the large country effect and the Government of India’s policy to reduce the number of donors it cooperates within recent years.

  5. This part of the curve includes Iraq, which in 2010–2012 received more than three and a half times as much aid from the DAC as China.

  6. Other less populous countries that do not have international poverty estimates are Cuba, Mongolia, Uzbekistan and Zimbabwe plus some small island states in the Caribbean and the Pacific.

  7. In addition, items such as debt relief and loan repayments – which CPA appropriately excludes from aid flows – comprise a very small proportion of Swedish bilateral aid in recent years.

  8. See http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/development/data/creditor-reporting-system_dev-cred-data-en/.

  9. These bilateral donors were selected as relevant comparators by staff of the Swedish Expert Group for Aid.

  10. India is home to more than a third of the moderately poor people in the world, receives negligible amounts of aid from most bilateral donors, and accounts for the long flat segment in most aid concentration curves.

  11. As a consequence, the donor fractionalization index for Sweden, which is 1 minus the sum of squares of the share of total bilateral aid given to each country, increased marginally from 0.965 in 2000–2002 to 0.968 in 2010–2012. This is in line with the trend for most other DAC donors (Easterly, 2007).

  12. These 33 countries include Burkina Faso, whose development cooperation partnership with Sweden is due to end in 2016.

  13. These countries are Afghanistan, Kosovo, Moldova, Myanmar, Somalia, South Sudan, the West Bank and Gaza, and Zimbabwe.

  14. One other lower middle-income country, the West Bank and Gaza, received $185 million of Swedish bilateral aid in these years but cannot be included in Figure 5 because of missing data on monetary poverty.

  15. While a graph with a common set of 92 countries can be produced, it would not be particularly helpful as it would exclude seven of Sweden’s key development cooperation partners (Albania, Belarus, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia, Turkey, Ukraine, and the West Bank and Gaza.)

  16. The mortality aid concentration curves also initially rise less steeply because the shares of child mortality in India and China are much lower than their shares of monetary poverty. In 2011 India accounted for 23.2 per cent of the burden of child mortality but 34.8 per cent of moderate poverty in our 106 study countries. The corresponding percentages for China are 4.3 per cent for child mortality and 15.2 per cent for moderate poverty.

  17. As China is an upper middle income country, this also shifts the vertical line showing the threshold between lower and upper middle incomes to the left in Figure 5.

  18. This is largely a consequence of the amount of bilateral aid that the United Kingdom gives to India and Nigeria, both countries with which the United Kingdom has strong historical ties.

References

  • Alesina, A. and Dollar, D. (2000) Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of Economic Growth 5(1): 33–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S. (2007) The missing dimensions of poverty data: Introduction to the special issue. Oxford Development Studies 35(4): 347–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baulch, B. (2006) Aid and the MDGs. World Development 34(6): 933–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baulch, B. and Le, T. (2013) The Progressivity and Regressivity of aid to the Social Sectors. Helsinki: World Institute of Development Economics. WIDER Working Paper 7.

  • Benn, J., Rogerson, A. and Steensen, S. (2010) Getting close to the core – Measuring Country Programmable Aid. Development Brief, Development Assistance Committee Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development.

  • Berthelemy, J.C. and Tichit, A. (2004) Bilateral donor’s aid allocation decisions: A three dimensional panel analysis. International Review of Economics and Finance 13(3): 253–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassen, R., Associates (1994) Does Aid Work? Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • CGD (2013) Commitment to Development Index. Washington: Centre for Global Development.

  • Chen, S. and Ravallion, M. (2011) The developing world is poorer than we thought but no less successful in the fight against poverty. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(4): 1577–1625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D. (1992) Distributions of Official Development Assistance among developing country aid recipients. The Developing Economies 30(3): 189–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P. and Dollar, D. (2002) Aid allocation and poverty reduction. European Economic Review 46(8): 475–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DAC (2013) OECD Development Cooperation Peer Review: Sweden 2013. Paris: Development Assistance Committee, Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development.

  • Deaton, A. (2001) Counting the world’s poor: Problems and possible solutions. World Bank Research Observer 16(2): 125–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar, D. and Levin, V. (2006) The increasing selectivity of foreign aid, 1984–2003. World Development 34(12): 2034–2046.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2007) Are aid agencies improving? Economic Policy 52(October): 635–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Government of Sweden (2003) Shared Responsibility: Sweden’s Policy for Global Development. Stockholm: Ministry for Foreign Affairs.

  • Government Offices of Sweden (2008) Swedish Development Cooperation. Stockholm: Government Offices of Sweden.

  • Government of Sweden (2013) Proposition 2013/14:1 Utgiftsområde 7: Internationellt bistånd, Stockholm, Sweden. http://www.regeringen.se/sb/d/17776, accessed 26 August 2014.

  • Harsmar, M. (2010) Swedish aid – A multipurpose tool for globalization? International issues and Slovak Foreign Policy Affairs 19(3): 38–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani, N. (1980) Income Inequality and Poverty. Oxford: Oxford Univeristy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maizels, A. and Nissante, M. (1984) Motivations for aid to developing countries. World Development 12(9): 879–900.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Foreign Affairs (2007) Focus Bilateral Development Cooperation. Stockholm: Ministry of Foreign Affairs.

  • Mosley, P. (1987) Overseas Aid: Its Defence and Reform. Brighton, UK: Wheatsheaf Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunnenkamp, P. and Theile, R. (2006) Targeting aid to the needy and deserving: Nothing but promises? The World Economy 29(4): 1177–1201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oden, B. and Wohlgemuth, L. (2013) Swedish development cooperation policy in an international perspective. Perspectives 24School of Global Studies, University of Gothenburg.

  • OECD (2013) Review of Development Cooperation (various issues) Paris: Organisation of Cooperation and Development.

  • Snyder, D. (1993) Donor bias toward small countries: An overlooked factor in the analysis of foreign aid and growth. Applied Economics 25(4): 481–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suits, D. (1977) Measurement of tax progressivity. American Economic Review 67(4): 747–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, A. (2012) Where Will the World’s Poor Live? An Update on Global Poverty and the New Bottom Billion. Washington DC: Center for Global Development. CGD Working Paper 305.

  • UNDP (1994) Human Development Report, 1994. New York: United Nations Development Program.

  • UNESCO (2014) Global Monitoring Report 2013–14: Teaching and Learning Achieving Quality for All. Paris: United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization.

  • UNICEF et al. (2013) Levels and Trends in Child Mortality: Estimates Developed by the UN Interagency Group for Child Mortality Estimation. New York: United Nations Children’s Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. and McGillivray, M. (1995) How well is aid allocated? Descriptive measures of aid allocation. Development and Change 26(1): 163–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1998) Assessing Aid: What Works What Doesn’t, and Why?. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper was originally prepared for the 1 September 2014 seminar organised by the Swedish Expert Group for Aid Studies (EBA) in Stockholm. Sincere thanks to Kofi Nyamekye who provided excellent research assistance and to Mats Harsmar for comments on earlier versions of this paper. The views expressed are those of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bob Baulch.

Appendix

Appendix

Calculation and Interpretation of the Suits Index

For a continuous distribution, the Suits index may be calculated using the following expression:

where S d is the Suits index for donor d, A i is the cumulative distribution of aid ranked in terms of their per capita incomes, y, and K is the area of right angle triangle bounded by the bottom and right-hand-side axes of the aid concentration curve box and the leading diagonal.

For a discrete distribution (of which the distribution of development assistance across developing countries would be an example), the Suits index can be calculated using the following trapezoid approximation:

where p i is the population share of country i and CA i is the cumulative aid share of country i and all poorer countries. Note that in contrast to some previous papers that have calculated the Suits index (White and McGillivray, 1995) using the trapezoid formula involving ranks, this formula allows for the population shares of different countries to differ substantially.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Baulch, B. The Poverty Focus of Swedish Bilateral Aid: A Comparative Analysis. Eur J Dev Res 28, 758–775 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.45

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.45

Keywords

Navigation