Skip to main content
Log in

Promoting Entrepreneurship — The New Company Law Agenda

  • Articles
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Promoting entrepreneurship is high on the agenda at both European and national level. This is, e.g., reflected in a number of company law initiatives, which have mainly focused on creating easier and cheaper access to limited liability, for example, by introducing sub-types of the private limited company. The main questions addressed here are whether it is possible to promote entrepreneurship through company law reforms and what the content of such frameworks should be in order to meet the needs of entrepreneurs. The analysis takes its point of departure in a new Danish survey of what the content of company legislation should be in order to meet the needs of entrepreneurs. In line with existing empirical studies, the importance of the capital requirement and formation procedures and costs is analysed, and further insight is given into, for example, what level of minimum capital and cost is regarded as acceptable. Besides this insight, the Danish survey adds to the existing studies and literature by also shedding light on whether company laws can be further optimised, for instance, by introducing more flexible rules for company management, etc. The results of the survey are compared with the reforms which, in recent years, have been adopted in several EU Member States, with the aim of evaluating whether these have met the needs indicated in the survey. The overall conclusion is that this is not the case on all points and that there is thus room for improvement. It is also briefly discussed whether the different reform methods used in the recent national reforms are well-suited for further optimising the legislation and it is shown that the method of introducing sub-types of private limited companies has its limitations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Micro-undertakings are understood as undertakings that employ fewer than 10 people and have an annual turnover or annual balance sheet total that does not exceed EUR 2 million; see Commission Recommendation 2003/361/EC of 6 May 2003 concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises.

  2. SBA (Small Business Act) Fact Sheet 2010/11, European Commission, Enterprise and Industry.

  3. COM(2014) 212 final.

  4. Registered in the Danish Central Business Register (CVR).

  5. See Commission Recommendation 94/1069/EC on the transfer of small and medium-sized enterprises.

  6. For a discussion of whether these company law initiatives have been sufficient, see Rüdiger Krause, ‘Die Stellung von KMU im europäischen Gesellschaftsrecht’, Europäische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht (2003) p. 747.

  7. Communication from the Commission ‘Review of the “Small Business Act” for Europe’ (COM(2011) 78 final).

  8. ‘Europe 2020 — A Strategy for Smart, Sustainable and Inclusive Growth’ (COM(2010) 2020 final).

  9. COM(2010) 614 final.

  10. See, e.g., Paul Krüger Andersen, ‘Corporate Governance, PÅ vej mod et selskabsretligt paradigmeskifte’, Nordisk Tidsskrift for Selskabsret (1999) p. 3, especially at p. 5.

  11. The report is available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/company/docs/modern/report_en.pdf>.

  12. The European Parliament proposed amendments to the Commission proposal. These amendments prompted further debate within the Council of Ministers, which came up with a revised Presidency compromise proposal for a Council Regulation on a European private company, Annex to Addendum 1 16115/09, Brussels, 27 November 2009. As there was still no agreement, the Hungarian Presidency referred, on 30 May 2011, a compromise proposal regarding the outstanding issues to the Competitiveness Council with a view to reaching political agreement on the Draft Regulation, but this compromise was rejected as well.

  13. The withdrawal of the SPE proposal was announced in the Annex to the Commission Communication on Regulatory Fitness and Performance (REFIT): Results and Next Steps (COM(2013) 685 final).

  14. COM(2014) 212 final.

  15. See the Explanatory Memorandum in COM(2014) 212 final.

  16. See, e.g., Friedrich Kübler, ‘A Comparative Approach to Capital Maintenance: Germany’, 15 European Business Law Review (EBLR) (2004) p. 1031; Pieter Leyte, ‘The Regime of Capital Maintenance Pertaining to Public Companies, Its Reform and Alternatives’, 25 Business Law Review (2004) p. 84; Jonathan Richford, ‘Legal Approaches to Restricting Distributions to Shareholders: Balance Sheet Tests and Solvency Tests’, 7 European Business Organization Law Review (EBOR) (2006) p. 137; John Armour, ‘Legal Capital: An Outdated Concept?’, 7 EBOR (2006) p. 5; Peter O. Mülbert and Max Birke, ‘Legal Capital — Is There a Case Against the European Capital Rules?’, 3 EBOR (2002) p. 696; Jonathan Rickford, ed., ‘Provisional Report of the Interdisciplinary Group on Capital Maintenance’ (2004), The Company Law Centre, British Institute of International and Comparative Law; and Luca Enriques and Jonathan R. Macey, ‘Creditors Versus Capital Formation: The Case Against the European Legal Capital Rules’, 86 Cornell Law Review (2001) p. 1165.

    Google Scholar 

  17. See, among others, William W. Bratton, Joseph A. McCahery and Erik P. M. Vermeulen, ‘How Does Corporate Mobility Affect Lawmaking? A Comparative Analysis’, 57 American Journal of Comparative Law (2009) p. 347; Reiner Braun, Horst Eidenmüller, Andreas Engert and Lars Hornuf, ‘Does Charter Competition Foster Entrepreneurship? A Difference-indifference Approach to European Company Law Reforms’, Journal of Common Market Studies (2012) p. 1; and Wolf-Georg Ringe, ‘Sparkling Regulatory Competition in European Company Law: The Impact of the Centros Line of Case Law and Its Concept of “Abuse of Law”’, in Rita de la Feria and Stefan Vogenaur, eds., Prohibition of Abuse of Law. A New General Principle of EU Law? (Hart Publishing 2011) p. 107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. According to the practice of the Court of Justice of the European Union, a Member State can require companies incorporated in its jurisdiction to retain some link to the country, for example, to have its head office in the country of incorporation. If a Member State has imposed such requirements, it can prevent the corporate form being used by entrepreneurs from other countries for activities that have no connection to the country of incorporation; see Case C-208/00 Überseering and Case C-210/06 Cartesio.

  19. Law nr. 63/2011. For a review of the reform, see Gudmund Knudsen, ‘Forenkling og mod-ernisering af den norske aksjeloven’, Nordisk Tidsskrift for Selskabsret (2010) p. 43.

  20. The amendments are based on the recommendations in Gudmund Knudsen’s report ‘Forenkling og modernisering av aksjeloven’, available at: <http://www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/jd/dok/rapporter_planer/rapporter/2011/forenkling-og-moderinsering-av-aksjelove.html?id=630516>. In addition to the amendments already made, the report contained proposals to further relax the capital requirements for companies. It was also proposed to change the rules on the internal organisation of private companies so as to give shareholders and company management greater freedom to adapt the company’s organisation to its needs and thereby reduce its administrative tasks and costs. Some of these proposals are contained in amendment Lovvedtak 68 (2012–2013), see <https://www.stortinget.no/no/Saker-og-publikasjoner/Vedtak/Beslutninger/Lovvedtak/2012-2013/vedtak-201213-068>. However, a more conservative approach than that proposed by Gudmund Knudsen has been adopted.

  21. Norway has experienced a rapid increase in the number of NUFs. In the first quarter of 2010, more than 1,350 NUFs were set up, which was 33% more than in the same quarter in 2009. NUFs thus constituted 18% of all newly started companies. In the first quarter of 2010, 30,000 NUFs were listed in the Brønnøysund Register Centre.

  22. Finnish Statute 624/2006, Government Bill HE 109/2005.

  23. Decree Law No. 33/2011 of 7 March 2011. In practical terms, this regulation sets a minimum value of EUR 1 for each share of a limited liability company (LDA).

  24. The term ‘network externalities’ refers to the economic theory that the value of a product depends on how many use it.

  25. In economic theory, a ‘network benefit’ arises when the advantage of using a given product increases as the number of people using it increases.

  26. The terms ‘network benefits’ and ‘learning benefits’ are closely related. Network benefits are advantages which the user of a product, such as a contractual provision, obtains when others use the same provision. Learning benefits are the advantages a user obtains from using a contractual provision that has previously been used by others.

  27. See Michael Klausner, ‘Corporations, Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts’, 81 Virginia Law Review (1995) p. 757, at p. 774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. See the discussion in Mette Neville and Karsten Engsig Sørensen, ‘Styrkelse af iværksæt-teri — en ny selskabsretlig dagsorden?’, 2 Nordisk Tidsskrift i Selskabsret (2012) pp. 18–68.

    Google Scholar 

  29. The law can be found at <http://www.bmj.bund.de/media/archive/1236.pdf>.

  30. See on the Unternehmergesellschaft, Jessica Schmidt, ‘The New Unternehmergesellschaft (Entrepreneurial Company) and the Limited — A Comparison’, 9 German Law Journal (2008) p. 1093; Christoph Teichmann, ‘Modernizing the GmbH: Germany’s Move in Regulatory Competition’, 7 European Company Law (2010) p. 20; Alice Nagel, ‘Balancing Entrepreneurial Freedom and Creditor Protection in Company and Insolvency Law: German and European Union Perspectives’, 27 Australian Journal of Corporate Law (2013) p. 293; Stefan Holzner, Die Unternehmergesellschaft (haftungsbeschränkt) im Wettbewerb der Gesellschaftsrechtsformen (Verlag Dr. Kovac 2011).

    Google Scholar 

  31. Lov nr. 616 af 12. juni 2013 om ændring af selskabsloven, lov om visse erhvervsdrivende virksomheder, Årsregnskabsloven og lov om Det Centrale Virksomhedsregister.

  32. Wolf-Georg Ringe’s study of the use of the British limited company form in Germany shows a fall in the number of British limited companies, which, however, seems due to factors other than the reduced capital requirements; see Wolf-Georg Ringe, ‘Corporate Mobility in the European Union — a Flash in the Pan? An Empirical Study on the Success of Lawmaking and Regulatory Competition’, 10 European Company and Financial Law Review (2013) p. 230, at p. 247 et seq.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. This limitation does not apply to the società a responsabilità limitata a capitale ridotto.

  34. Jonathan Levie and Erkko Autio, ‘Regulatory Burden, Rule of Law, and Entry of Strategic Entrepreneurs: An International Panel Study’, 48 Journal of Management Studies (2011) p. 1392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. See, e.g., Frank H. Easterbrook and Daniel R. Fischel, ‘Limited Liability and the Corporation’, 52 University of Chicago Law Review (1985) p. 89; idem, The Economic Structure of Corporate Law (Harvard University Press 1991); Jack L. Carr and Frank Mathewson, ‘Unlimited Liability as a Barrier to Entry’, 96 Journal of Political Economy (1988) p. 766; P. Halpern, M. Trebilcock and S. Turnbull, ‘An Economic Analysis of Limited Liability in Corporation Law’, 30 University of Toronto Law Journal (1980) p. 117. A study by Brian J. Broughman, ‘Entrepreneur Wealth and Demand for Limited Liability’ (17 May 2012), available at: <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1761011>, shows that limited liability is most important for ‘better-off’ entrepreneurs.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Leora Klapper and Inessa Love, ‘The Impact of the Financial Crisis on New Firm Registration’ (2010), World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 4937. Other studies of ‘entry regulation’ show the same tendency; see Leora Klapper, Luc Laeven and Raghuram Rajan, ‘Entry Regulation as a Barrier to Entrepreneurship’, 82 Journal of Financial Economics (2006) p. 591; and Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, ‘The Regulation of Entry’, 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics (2002) p. 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. André van Stel, David J. Storey and A. Roy Thurik, ‘Entrepreneurship and Its Determinants in a Cross-country Setting’, 82 Small Business Economics (2007) p. 171. This study covered 39 countries and examined start-up procedures, time to incorporate, costs, minimum capital, hiring and firing, bankruptcy law, taxes, etc.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Braun, Eidenmüller, Engert and Hornuf, supra n. 17.

  39. The study was carried out by the University of Jena (Institut für Rechtstatsachenforschung, see <http://www.rewi.uni-jena.de>). See also Walter Bayer and Thomas Hoffman, ‘Neue Daten zur Unternehmergesellschaft’, 4 GmbHR-Rundschau (2012) R51; idem ‘Vier Jahre Unternehmergesellschaft’, 23 GmbHR-Rundschau (2012) R322; and idem ‘Was ist aus der ersten Generation von Unternehmergesellschaften geworden?’, GmbHR (2011) R321 f.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Christoph Teichmann and Ralf Knaier ‘Die deutsche Unternehmergesellschaft als Alternative für österreichische Gründer — eine empirische Annäherung’, 5 Der Gesellschafter (GesRZ) (2014) p. 285.

    Google Scholar 

  41. David G. Blanchflower, Andrew Oswald and Alois Stutzer, ‘Latent Entrepreneurship Across Nations’, European Economic Review (2001) p. 680. See also Raquel Fonseca, Paloma Lopez-Garcia and Christopher A. Pissarides, ‘Entrepreneurship, Start-up Costs and Employment’, European Economic Review (2001) p. 692; David S. Evans and Linda S. Leighton, ‘Some Empirical Aspects of Entrepreneurship’, 79 American Economic Review (1989) p. 519; David S. Evans and Boyan Jovanovic, ‘An Estimated Model of Entrepreneurial Choice under Liquidity Constraints’, 97 Journal of Political Economy (1989) p. 808.

    Google Scholar 

  42. As can be seen in the tables below, tax considerations also play an important role in the choice of the framework for an undertaking. The assessment of tax aspects lies outside the scope of this article. However, the optimal choice of corporate form is what fits best with regard to liability and organisation. This includes being free to choose whether to be taxed as a partnership or as an independent taxable entity. Such an arrangement has been introduced in the USA. In 1997, the USA launched the ‘check-the-box’ system under which business entities with a minimum of two members can be classified either as a partnership or as an association taxable as a corporation. In the case of single member entities, the owner can choose between being taxed either as a single member entity or as a corporation.

  43. See Tore BrÅthen, Selskapsrett (Universitetsforlaget 2002), at p. 40. For a criticism of the minimum capital requirement as a rule for protecting capital, see Jan Wouters, ‘Towards a European Private Company?’, in Harm-Jan de Kluiver and Walter van Gerven, eds., The European Private Company (1995) at p. 166, and Harm-Jan de Kluiver in idem, at p. 115; Günther Wüst, ‘Unterkapitalisierung und Überschuldung bei Beschränkthaftern’, Juristenzeitung (1985) p. 817; and Mette Neville, ‘Fokus pÅ smÅ selskaber’, in Paul Krüger Andersen, ed., Selskabers organisation — Nye tendenser i skandinavisk selskabsret (2) (Djoef Publishing 1997) p. 44.

  44. Braun, Eidenmüller, Engert and Hornuf, supra n. 17.

  45. In Norway, the reform was implemented in 2011 and already in the first half of 2012, registrations of private companies increased by 76.5% in comparison with the preceding year. What is interesting is that, at the same time, the number of new Norwegian foreign-registered undertakings fell by 60%. It has been stated that this was due to the reduced capital requirements for Norwegian private limited companies, see <http://www.brreg.no/presse/pressemeldinger/2012/07/fr-statistikk-1-ha.html>.

  46. This may be in connection with an entrepreneurial company’s re-registration as a private limited company, whereby the reserve will be transferred to the private company’s capital, or it may be the case if the shareholders want to increase the company’s capital by transferring the tied reserve prior to re-registration.

  47. The German provision states the following: ‘(3) The balance sheet in the annual accounts to be prepared in accordance with §§ 242 and 264 of the Commercial Code must include statutory reserves comprising one quarter of the annual surplus minus any losses carried forward from the previous year. The reserves may be used only (1) for the purposes set out in § 57c; (2) to compensate for an annual deficit, in so far as it is not covered by profits carried forward from the previous year; (3) to compensate for losses carried forward from the previous year, in so far as they are not covered by an annual surplus.’

  48. The Financial Statements Act § 35c states: ‘Each year an entrepreneurial company shall set aside at least 25% of the undertaking’s profits in a tied reserve for building up the company’s capital base until this reserve, together with the company’s share capital, amounts to at least DKK 50,000. This reserve may not be eliminated by the company’s losses or reduced by any other means. However, the reserve can be liquidated or reduced to the extent that the company’s share capital is increased.’

  49. For an overview of these reforms, see Katja Fuchs Mtwebana, ‘The Regulation of Companies’ Capital in the European Union: What Is the Current State of Affairs’, 22 European Business Law Review (2011) p. 237; and Joseph A. McCahery, Levinus Timmerman and Erik P.M. Vermeulen, eds., Private Company Law Reform (Asser Press 2010). The Danish amendment to the Companies Act in 2013 has also led to further relaxation of requirements regarding, for example, self-financing, own shares, etc., and in Norway a draft law has been put forward containing a number of relaxations of rules, for example, on the payment of dividends, share premium accounts, own shares, etc. However, the draft law does not go as far as proposed by Gudmund Knudsen in his report (supra n. 21). See further Prop. 111 L (2012–2013), available at: <http://www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/jd/dok/regpubl/prop/2012-2013/prop-111-l-20122013/1.html?id=721284>.

    Google Scholar 

  50. ‘While the current statutory restrictions on the purchase by a BV of its own shares, the reduction of its capital and the payment of dividends or distribution of reserves will be repealed, the new rules also introduce a distribution test and an obligation on the part of management board members and the recipients of a distribution to pay compensation if they act in bad faith.’ See: <http://www.newsletter-nautadutilh.com/EN/xzine/corporate/simplification_and_flexibilisation_of_rules_governing_dutch_bvs/vereenvoudiging_en_flexibilisering_nederlands_bv-recht_(stand_van_zaken_flex-b_v_).html?cid=4&xzine_id=4729>.

  51. This is the case with the German reform of the GmbH law, whereby liability for carrying on the business of insolvent companies was made stricter. There have been cases where the management resigned and required GmbH shareholders to initiate insolvency proceedings; see Ulrich Noack and Michael Beurskens, ‘Modernising the German GmbH — Mere Window Dressing or Fundamental Redesign?’, 9 EBOR (2008) p. 119. The Dutch reform includes rules on stricter liability of the management if the company makes a distribution, including rules requiring repayment of funds distributed by a company within one year of its insolvency; see Frank Woolridge, ‘Proposed Amendments to the Law Governing the Dutch BV’, 20 European Business Law Review (2009) p. 369. In the Norwegian reform the intensification of management responsibility is less in evidence, but it is stated that the management carries responsibility for the company’s liquidity; see the report drawn up by Gudmund Knudsen, supra n. 21, at p. 96.

    Google Scholar 

  52. In addition to the Dutch reform, see the Belgian reform, whereby the promoters of a company must draw up a financial plan in which they justify the amount of capital. The plan is not made public, but must be deposited with a notary. If the company becomes insolvent within three years, its promoters are personally liable if the capital with which the company was set up was clearly insufficient to ensure the operation of the company for at least two years.

  53. ,Article 18(5) of the Commission’s proposal for a single-member private limited liability company states that ‘[a]ny director shall be personally liable for recommending or ordering a distribution if that director knew, or, in view of the circumstances, ought to have known that the distribution would be contrary to para. 2 or 3. The same applies to the single-member with regard to any decision to make a distribution referred to in Article 21.

  54. See Jerome Werner, ‘The Uncompleted Reform of the Law for Limited Liability Companies (GmbH)’, International Business Law Journal (2009) p. 149.

  55. See the report by the UK Department for Business Innovation & Skills, Transparency & Trust: Enhancing the Transparency of UK Company Ownership and Increasing Trust in UK Business (April 2014).

  56. At its meeting in Northern Ireland in June 2013, the G8 agreed an action plan entitled ‘Principles to Prevent the Misuse of Companies and Legal Arrangements’. It also encourages the introduction of rules to ensure insight into the identity of a company’s beneficial owners, including limiting the use of bearer shares and nominee shareholders; see: <https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/207532/G8-Action-Plan-principles-to-prevent-the-misuse-of-companies-and-legal-arrangements.pdf>. The G8 action plan following up the declaration adopted is available at: <http://star.worldbank.org/star/about-us/transparency-beneficial-ownership-resource-center>.

  57. See the comparative analysis by Karsten Engsig Sørensen, ‘Disqualifying Directors in the EU’, in Hanne Birkmose, Mette Neville and Karsten Engsig Sørensen, eds., Boards of Directors in European Companies. Reshaping and Harmonising Their Organisation and Duties (Kluwer 2013) p. 327.

  58. See the Competitiveness Council of 31 May 2011, available at: <http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/sme/business-environment/start-up-procedures/index_en.htm>.

  59. See the findings of the World Bank and International Finance Corporation, ‘Doing Business 2011’, at p. 16 ff.

  60. See COM(2014) 212 final, as well as <http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-14-274_en.htm>.

  61. It must be assumed that many entrepreneurs will find it difficult to get an overview of the kinds of problems that can arise, and thus of which issues need to be regulated. Günter H. Roth, ‘Das System der Kapitalgesellschaften im Umbruch — ein internationaler Vergleich’, 60 Rechtsfragen der Handelsgesellschaften (1990) p. 18, warned against regarding Satzungsautonomie as a way to protect oneself through ‘corporate planning’. He stated that neither the average shareholder nor a lawyer who is not specialised in the area will be able to have a perspective on all possible problems, let alone regulate such issues properly. On ‘incomplete contracting’ in SMEs, see Joseph A. McCahery and Erik P.M. Vermeulen ‘Conflict Resolution and the Role of Courts: An Empirical Study’, in Mette Neville and Karsten Engsig Sørensen, eds., Company Law and SMEs (Thomson Reuters 2010) p. 207.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Robert A. Hillmann, The Richness of Contract Law: An Analysis and Critique of Con-temporary Theories of Contract Law (Springer 1997) p. 226; and David Charney, ‘Hypothetical Bargains: The Normative Structure of Contract’, 89 Michigan Law Review (1991) p. 1815, at p.1841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  63. Frank D. Easterbrook and Daniel R. Fischel, The Economic Structure of Corporate Law (Harvard University Press 1991), at p. 236 et seq.

  64. The Danish Committee on the Modernisation of Company Law stated explicitly in its report (betænkning 1498/2008) that a positive side effect of including the regulation of both private and public companies in a single legislative act could be to remove the uncertainty that followed the 1996 reform of the Private Limited Companies Act.

  65. Larry E. Ribstein, ‘Statutory Forms for Closely Held Firms: Theories and Evidence From LLCS’, 73 Washington University Law Quarterly (1995) p. 369, at p. 374; and Sandra K. Miller, Penelope Sue Greenberg and Ralph H. Greenberg, ‘An Empirical Glimpse into Limited Liability Companies: Assessing the Need to Protect Minority Investors’, 43 American Business Law Journal (2006) p. 609.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Charles J. Goetz and Robert E. Scott, ‘The Limits of Expanded Choice: An Analysis of the Interactions Between Express and Implied Contract Terms’, 73 California Law Review (1985) p. 261. As stated by Ribstein, supra n. 70, at p. 376 et seq., these advantages will apply less to companies whose problems are peculiar to themselves, since in these cases there will be a need for special solutions. There are areas, such as registration provisions, etc., which do not give rise to any problems of interpretation.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  67. See also Mette Neville, ‘The Nordic Company Law Reforms in an International Regulatory Perspective’, in Mette Neville and Karsten Engsig Sørensen, eds., The Regulation of Companies (Thomson/Sweet & Maxwell 2003); and Joseph A. McCahery, Erik P.M. Vermeulen, Masato Hisatake and Jun Saito, ‘The New Company Law: What Matters in an Innovative Economy’, in Joseph A. McCahery, Levinus Timmerman and Erik Vermeulen, eds., Private Company Law Reform — International and European Perspectives (The Hague, Asser Press 2010) p. 71.

  68. This will only happen if the gains from using a contractual provision exceed: (1) the parties’ transaction costs; (2) the value to the parties of withholding relevant information; and (3) the parties’ joint preference for the status quo. On the ‘status quo bias effect’, see William Samuelson and Richard Zechhauser, ‘Status quo in Decision Making’, 1 Journal of Risk and Uncertainty (1988) p. 7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  69. Legislators’ drafting of declaratory rules has been the subject of much attention in economic theory, and according to mainstream economic theory, legislation ought to function as a standard contract so as to minimise the parties’ transaction costs. The content of declaratory rules should reflect the agreement that rational fully informed parties would have entered into if they did not have to take into account the transaction costs of negotiating and drafting the agreement. Thus, a Hypothetical Bargaining Model should be used; see William J. Carney, ‘The Political Economy of Competition for Corporate Charters’, 26 Journal of Legal Studies (1997) p. 305; Easterbrook and Fischel, supra n. 68, and Easterbrook and Fischel ‘The Corporate Contract’, in Roberta Romano, ed., Foundations of Corporate Law (Foundation Press/Thomson 1993) p. 101; and Brian Cheffins, Company Law — Theory, Structure and Operation (Clarendon Press 1997), at p. 264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  70. See Mette Neville, ‘Konfliktløsning’, in Mette Neville and Karsten Engsig Sørensen, eds., Den nye selskabslov (Djoef Publishing 2009), at p. 209; and Morten Bennedsen and Kasper Nielsen, ‘Ejerstrukturer og kontrolallokering i unoterede danske virksomheder’, 139 Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift (2001) p. 237.

    Google Scholar 

  71. See Mette Neville, ‘Moderniseringsudvalgets udspil til ny selskabslov — ikke en lov i superliga for iværksættere og smÅ selskaber’, Nordisk Tidsskrift for selskabsret (2008) p. 94.

  72. The fact that small companies have a structure as described above has led many countries to introduce legislative provisions for private limited companies and their like according to which shares are not, in principle, freely transferrable. This applies, for example, to Norwegian private companies where, according to § 4–15, the agreement of the board is required for the transfer of shares and the other shareholders have pre-emption rights.

  73. See Martin Christian Kruhl, Ejeraftaler (Karnov Group 2008), at p. 57 et seq.

  74. See Dennis P. Coates, ‘Share Transfer and Transmission Restrictions in the Close Corporation’, 3 U.B.C. Law Review (1968) p. 98. Another risk is that the majority will identify the company’s interests with its own interests and will refuse to allow a transfer to a buyer who could disagree with them about the running of the company, whether or not the company is operated optimally; see the statement by the Norwegian Finansanalytikerforening in Ot.prp. No 19 1974–75, p. 44. See also Mette Neville, ‘Samtykkeklausuler i aktie- og anpartsselskaber’, in Torsten Iversen, Lars Hedegaard Kristensen and Erik Werlauff, eds., Hyldestskrift til Jørgen Nørgaard (Djoef Publishing 2003) p. 942.

    Google Scholar 

  75. For a more detailed discussion, see Neville supra n. 78.

  76. Neville, supra n. 76, at p. 215 ff.

  77. Cf. Gerner-Beuerle, Paech and Philipp, infra n. 93.

  78. If a company is required to choose or chooses to have a board, the majority of Member States follow the one-tier system, but some Member States (for example, the Czech Republic Denmark, Germany, Latvia, and Poland) allow private companies to set up a supervisory board. In some countries, a board is mandatory in some circumstances, and in some Member States the two-tier system is mandatory in certain circumstances, e.g., relating to the number of employees (employee representation) or shareholders.

  79. Neville/Nykredit, Ejerlederanalyse 2010. The study, a collaboration between Nykredit, a major Danish bank and mortgage lender, and the author, focuses on Danish owner-managed SMEs. It is based on telephone interviews with 1,040 owner-managers on the basis of a questionnaire. In 2010, the focus was on growth and professionalisation. All respondents were defined as being both owners and managers of their business. The study included all forms of company and all trade sectors except the primary industries of agriculture and fisheries. The study is close to being a representative sample, though, for a variety of reasons, the sample does not include firms with less than 4 employees.

  80. Studies show that the board, and in particular the use of external members, ensures greater focus on key management tasks; see Mette Neville, ‘The Role of Boards in Small and Medium Sized Firms’, 11 Corporate Governance (2011) p. 527. Studies also show that external board members help implement strategic changes; see Olof Brunninge, Mattias Nordqvist, Johan Wiklund, ‘Corporate Governance and Strategic Change in SMEs: The Effects of Ownership, Board Composition and Top Management Teams’, 29 Small Business Economics (2007) p. 295. On this basis, the Danish Business Authority (Erhvervsstyrelsen) published Den kompetente bestyrelse with a view to motivating owner-managers to use boards and external board members. This publication can be downloaded from: <http://www.ebst.dk/file/187801/den_kompetente_bestyrelse.pdf>.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  81. Mette Neville, ‘The Role of Boards in SMEs’, 11 Corporate Governance (2011) p. 527; and Bennedsen and Nielsen, supra n. 76. au90_See Neville, supra n. 76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  82. See Mette Neville, ‘The Many Roles of Boards in SMEs’, in Birkmose, Neville and Sørensen, supra n. 62, Chapter 8.

  83. See for a new study mapping directors’ duties and liabilities in the Member States, Carsten Gerner-Beuerle, Philipp Paech and Edmund Philipp Schuster, Study on Directors’ Duties and Liability, prepared for the European Commission DG Markt (April 2013).

  84. See Mette Neville, supra n. 92.

  85. Gerner-Beuerle, Paech and Schuster, supra n. 93.

  86. Ibid., at p. 63 et seq.

  87. Model Articles for Public and Limited Companies, Regulations 2008 No 3229, Article 4(1).

  88. Except in a limited range of matters where the statute requires the participation of large shareholders; see Paul Davies and Sarah Worthington, eds., Gower & Davies, Principles of Company Law, 9th edn. (Sweet & Maxwell 2012). In the UK, the division of powers between boards and shareholders is a matter for the company’s articles of association, and in SMEs it is quite possible for shareholders to play a larger role in decision making than in listed companies. Gower & Davies give the example of quasi-partnership companies, where shareholders want the system of governance that would apply if the entity were a partnership rather than a company.

  89. See Gerner-Beuerle, Paech and Schuster, supra n. 93, at pp. 64 and 21.

  90. Alfred Hueck and Christine Windbichler, Gesellschaftsrecht, 21st edn. (Verlag C.H. Beck München 2008), at p. 224.

  91. Only where following such instructions would entail breaching the national law of the Member State in which the company is registered, should the management body not follow them; see Article 23(2).

  92. On conflicts within SMEs, see Neville, supra n. 76, at p. 209 ff.; and Michael Harvey and Rodney Evans, ‘Family Business and Multiple Levels of Conflict’, 7 Family Business Review (1994) p. 331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  93. On the possible consequences of conflicts, see Neville, supra n. 76, and idem, ‘Conflicts in SMEs’, in Paul Krüger Andersen, Nis Jul Clausen and Rolf Skog, Shareholder Conflicts (Djoef Publishing 2006) p. 87.

  94. Conflicts need not be destructive. If handled properly, they can contribute to better decisions being made. This applies especially to conflicts about processes where people agree about what is to be done but disagree about how it is to be done. This distinction was made in K. E. Jehn, ‘A Qualitative Analysis of Conflict Types and Dimensions in Organizational Groups’, 42 Administrative Science Quarterly (1997) p. 252. See also Richard A. Cosier and Michael Harvey, ‘The Hidden Strengths in Family Business: Functional Conflict’, 11 Family Business Review (1998) p. 75, with further references there. There are also task-related conflicts, about the tasks and divisions of responsibilities between owner-managers. These can be prevented by job descriptions, etc.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  95. Troels Mogensen and Janus Rosted Gjesager, ‘Deadlock i joint ventures’, Masters Dissertation (2008), Aarhus School of Business. The research included an investigation of owner-managed undertakings, involving 1,423 respondents.

  96. For the reasons for the lack of such provisions, see Neville, supra n. 76, which contains a report on questionnaire research that showed, among other things, that many respondents had omitted such provisions because they relied on the legislation containing an appropriate solution.

  97. Harald Bartl, Angela Bartl, Helmar Fichtelmann, Detlef Koch and Michaela C. Schmitt, GmbH-Recht (Hüthig Jehle Rehm 2013), at p. 229.

  98. BVs are governed chiefly by Title 5 of Book II of the Civil Code. See new Act 299 Staatsblad van het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden (Official Gazette of the Kingdom of the Netherlands (5 July 2012)).

  99. Levinus Timmerman and Alexander Doorman, ‘Rights of Minority Shareholders in the Netherlands’, a report written for the XVIth World Congress of the International Academy of Comparative Law.

  100. Len Sealy and Sarah Worthington, Cases and Materials in Company Law, 8th edn. (OUP 2008), at p. 552, and Andrew Hicks and S.H. Goo, Cases and Materials on Company Law, 6th edn. (OUP 2008), at p. 440.

  101. Sealy and Worthington, ibid., at p. 560.

  102. See Scottish Co-operative Wholesale Society Ltd v. Meyer (1959) AC 324; Re City Branch Group Ltd (1985) 1 WLR 3505 (Court ofAppeal); and O’Neill v. Phillips (1999) 1 WLR 1092 (House of Lords).

  103. Gower & Davies, Principles of Modern Company Law, 8th edn. (Sweet & Maxwell 2008), at p. 705.

  104. Neville, supra n. 76.

  105. COM(2008) 396/3. However, in a compromise proposal put forward by the Presidency for Competitiveness Council (3/4.12.2009) Inter-institutional File: 2008/0130 (CNS), the provision on conflict resolution was removed so that it is now to be found in national laws. See Mette Neville, ‘Conflicts in the European Private Company (SPE)’, in Heribert Hirte and Christoph Teichmann, The European Private Company — Societas Privata Europaea (SPE), European Company and Financial Law Review, Special Volume 3 (2012)p. 193.

  106. § 4–24(1)(2) and (3), which states that a court, upon the request of a shareholder, shall order the redemption of the shareholder’s shares if there are important reasons for giving the shareholder the right to exit the company because: (1) a company organ or some other representative of the company has acted contrary to §§ 5–21 and 6–28; (2) some other shareholder in the company has abused his influence in the company; or (3) a serious and enduring conflict has arisen between the shareholder and another shareholder or shareholders concerning the running of the company.

  107. Neville, supra n. 76.

  108. This means that the majority uses its powers to deprive a shareholder of influence. Under the law, it is the majority that can appoint and dismiss the board and the chief executive officer. The CEO is responsible for hiring and firing employees, as well as, together with the shareholders in the general meeting, for declaring a dividend. As stated, SMEs are characterised by the fact that the shareholders participate in the management of the company and are employed in it. The company’s revenues are typically distributed in the form of salaries rather than dividends. By removing shareholders from the management, dismissing them from employment and perhaps following a conservative policy with regard to the distribution of dividends, their expectation of participating in the company will be disappointed and their income will be seriously affected, and they will often lose returns on their investment. Since their shares are de facto non-transferrable, their investment will be locked in the company and thus form part of the basis for the income which the majority draws from the company.

  109. For a comparative analysis of the duty of loyalty of SMEs, see Karsten Engsig Sørensen, ‘Duty of Loyalty for Shareholders — A Possible Remedy for Conflicts in SMEs’, in Neville and Sørensen, eds., supra n. 66, p. 127.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Neville, M., Sørensen, K.E. Promoting Entrepreneurship — The New Company Law Agenda. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 15, 545–584 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1017/S156675291400127X

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/S156675291400127X

Keywords

Navigation