Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Food deserts and location economics

  • Original Article
  • Published:
SN Business & Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

People who must travel more than one mile to purchase fresh and healthy food are defined by the US Department of Agriculture as living in a ‘food desert’. An extensive literature has evolved on the subject, but it lacks an economic model or empirical evidence to explain food deserts. This paper estimates an economic location model to explain the occurrence of 4066 ‘food desert’ census tracts in 363 urban areas. The model determines the radius of a circular market area of the smallest profitable supermarket in each area, based on shoppers’ travel cost, household food purchases, and supermarket fixed costs. The model parameters are estimated for each urban area, and the mean radius is 3.25 miles, which suggests the present food deserts one mile definition is not well-grounded since the average distance in a circular market is 2/3 its radius. The number of food desert census tracts is very sensitive to the market size radius of the smallest supermarkets, with an elasticity of − 4.17, and the presence of a Walmart increases the count of food deserts by 20.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A Google Scholar search of ‘Food Deserts’ on October 15, 2021 returned 16,900 references.

  2. Allcott et al. (2019) conduct a detailed investigation of the relationship between food deserts and nutritional inequality and note that “…our results do allow us to conclude that policies aimed at eliminating food deserts likely generate little progress toward a goal of reducing nutritional inequality (p. 1840).” This suggests that even trying to eliminate food deserts may not be justified.

  3. 2012 is the year that the USDA conducted its national Food Access Purchase Survey.

  4. Food retailing is an old-fashioned industry and the ‘new geography’ focus on entrepreneurship, high-technology startups and agglomeration effects offers little insight into the ‘food deserts’ question.

  5. Betancourt and Malanoski (op. cit.) find constant marginal cost with respect to output (transactions) and declining marginal cost with respect to services (e.g., bagging).

  6. Profit maximization requires -1/2tDU)(mk) + πDU2 = 0.

  7. Capozza and Attaran (1976) also show that in this type of model the mill price is an increasing function of F, k and t, which also comports with non-spatial economic models.

  8. The area of a hexagon is 2.6S2, where S is the length of one side of the hexagon and is 1.15 times as long as its radius or apothem which is the same as the radius of the inscribed circle. Average distance = 0.6079S (Stone, 1991).

  9. Thus, m + q dm/dq = k, and m = F/q + k. The number of firms is denoted N and q = D/NQ/N; dm/dq = dU/dq∙dm/dU = -2t/πDU.

  10. FoodAPS also surveyed rural households, but they are not included in the present study.

  11. All Other trips include small (11), medium (60) and large (70) grocery stores, 35 Dollar Stores, and 9 Convenience Store. The remaining trips include drug stores, farmer markets, and military shops and not specified.

  12. A Super Store is defined as a large footprint supermarket. A supermarket is a full-line, self-service stores with annual sales of at least $2 million. A Club or warehouse store usually requires a membership fee and stacks merchandise on pallets or racks, rather than shelves.

  13. About 6% of respondents did not provide income data, and the amount recorded is imputed by FAPS.

  14. The publicly available FoodAPS data do not give the location below the level of region.

  15. The mean number of transaction per week per square mile is 415. Annual data are converted to weekly because store fixed costs are weekly amounts.

  16. The instrumental variables are the same used in Table 4.

References

  • Allcott H, Diamond R, Dube J-P, Handbury J, Rahkovsky I, Schnell M (2019) Food deserts and the causes of nutritional inequality. Q J Econ 134(4):1793–1844

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaumont J, Lang T, Leather S, Mucklow C (1995) Report from the Policy Sub-Group to the Nutrition Task Force Low Income Project Team of the Department of Health. Institute of Grocery Distribution, Radlett

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckmann M (1968) Location theory. Random House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Betancourt R, Malanoski M (1999) An estimable model of supermarket behavior: prices, distribution services and some effects of competition. Empirica 26:55–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitler M, Haider SJ (2010) An economic view of food deserts in the United States. J Policy Anal Manag 30(1):153–176

    Google Scholar 

  • Capozza DR, Attaran K (1976) Pricing in urban areas under free entry. J Reg Sci 16(2):167–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capozza DR, Van Order RT (1977) A simple model of spatial pricing under free Entry. Southern Econ J 44:361–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capozza DR, Van Order R (1978) A generalized model of spatial competition. Am Econ Rev 68(5):896–908

    Google Scholar 

  • Chain Store Guide (2013) 2013 GIMS report in excel. Chain Store Guide Co, Atlanta

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson PB (2016) The evolution of the supermarket industry: from A & P to Wal-Mart. In: Basker E (ed) Handbook of the economics of retail and distribution. Edward Elgar, Northampton, pp 368–391

    Google Scholar 

  • Erlenkotter D (1989) The general optimal market area model. Ann Oper Res 18:45–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Food Marketing Institute (2012) The Food retailing industry speaks 2012. Food Marketing Institute, Arlington

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1986) Spatial competition and the location of firms. In: Arnott R (ed) Location theory. Harwood Academic Publishers, New York, pp 1–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh-Dastidar M, Hunter G, Collins RL, Zenk SN, Cummins S, Beckman R, Nugroho AK, Sloan JC, Wagner L (2017) Does opening a supermarket in a food desert change the food environment? Health Place 46:249–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2012) Econometric analysis, 7th edn. Pearson Education Ltd., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML (1956) Plant location in theory and practice. The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML (1974) A theory of the firm in economic space. Lone Star Publishers, Austin

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML (1976) An empirical evaluation of the equilibrium size and shape of market areas. Int Econ Rev 17(1):172–190 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML (1995) Location economics, theoretical underpinnings and applications. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd, Aldershott

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML, Hwang MJ (1979) Estimates of fixed costs and the sizes of market areas. Environ Plan A 11:993–1009 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis WA (1945) Competition in retail trade. Economica XII:202–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo Re M, Parente F, Annunziata S (2021) Economic networks in the complexity of Covid-19 emergency: a qualitative approach for an actor-network model. L’industria 42(1):27–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Losch A (1954) The economics of location. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Monarca U, Cassetta E, ReMeleo LMLU (2019) A network analysis of the intersectoral linkages between manufacturing and other industries in China and Italy. Glob J Emerg Mark Econ 11(1):80–97

    Google Scholar 

  • National Household Food Acquisition and Purchase Survey (FoodAPS) (2016) Users Guide to survey design, data collection and overview of datasets. U.S Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (November)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhone A, Ver Ploeg M, Dicken C, Williams R, Breneman V (2017) Low-income and low-supermarket-access census tracts, 2010–2015, EIB 165, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (January)

  • Rhone A, Ver Ploeg M, Williams R, Breneman V (2019) Understanding low-income and low-access census tracts across the nation: subnational and subpopulation estimates of access to healthy food. EIB-209, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (May)

  • Salop SC (1979) Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J Econ 10(1):141–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl K (1987) Theories of urban business location. In: Mills ES (ed) Handbook of regional and urban economics. North Holland, New York, pp 759–820

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone RE (1991) Some average distance results. Transp Sci 25(1):83–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ver Ploeg M, Mancino L, Todd JE, Clay DM, Scharadin B (2015) Where do Americans usually shop for food and how do they get there? EIB 138, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (March)

  • von Thunen JH (1875) Der Isolierte Statt, 3rd edn. Schumacher Zarchlin, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber A (1929) The Theory of the Location of Industries. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Wendt M, Kinsey J, Kaufman P (2008) Food accessibility in the inner city: what have we learned? Working Paper 08-01. The Food Industry Center, University of Minnesota, , Minneapolis

Download references

Funding

The author received no outside funding to prepare this research paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Donald F. Vitaliano.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author has no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or with animals.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 15 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vitaliano, D.F. Food deserts and location economics. SN Bus Econ 2, 21 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s43546-021-00183-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s43546-021-00183-1

JEL Classification

Navigation