Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Government Expenditure in India: Composition and Multipliers

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We estimate fiscal multipliers for total, capital (capex), and revenue (revex) Indian government expenditure using a two variable Structural Vector Auto-Regression (SVAR). Our quarterly data allows us to estimate both short- and long-run multipliers. We then extend and re-estimate the model including supply shocks and the monetary policy response sequentially and together and re-estimate the multipliers. The long-run capex multiplier remains much larger than the corresponding revex multiplier in all the estimations. The short run impact multiplier is the highest for revex, but does not rise after the first quarter. The capex peak multiplier in the 2nd quarter is 1.6–1.9 times larger. The cumulative multiplier is also the highest for capex, 2.4–6.5 times the size of the revex multiplier. Capex also reduces inflation more over the long-term. Despite this, capex shows greater volatility since it is more vulnerable to discretionary cuts. Monetary accommodation of capex and revex is allowed to differ. It varies in the absence/presence of supply shocks. The combination of a direct cut in capex and monetary tightening in response to a supply shock reduces the capex multiplier. The results are consistent with an elastic long-run aggregate supply. Disaggregated evaluation of spending policy, therefore, gives useful insights.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In an EME there is no well-defined business cycle, let alone several cycles, over which to measure the multiplier, but we find impulse responses for India stabilize in 2 years. The period of 15 years for which quarterly data is available is also short, although estimation is feasible.

  2. Following the Sixth Pay Commission, wages and salaries of government employees increased along with subsidies. Interest payments also rose on account of higher fiscal deficits.

  3. We also repeat the analysis using the GDP price deflator (Appendix A.3) with no change in results, possibly because rates of growth are similar.

  4. After the LAF was introduced in 2004, short term money market interest rates tend to move together. RBI (2014) argues CMMR is one of the best indicators of short term monetary policy since it reflects actions from liquidity constrained banks and it fluctuates only in the band specified by the LAF. The weighted average CMMR was recognized as an operating target for monetary policy.

  5. It is customary to deseasonalise government expenditure variables, given the much noted ’March Rush’, or concentration of expenditure at the end of the fiscal year. Seasonal unit roots may have given spurious results from the SVAR, which requires all variables to be stationary.

  6. The totex multipliers (peak and impact) are lower than both revex and capex multipliers because although the impulse response of total expenditure is similar to revex in the short run, this is multiplied by the ratio of GDP to expenditure and GDP/total expenditure is less than GDP/revex. In the long run, however, the totex multiplier is higher than revex multiplier as the large multiplier effects of capex have a strong cumulative effect on the economy even as the effect of revex subsides.

  7. The real rather than the nominal interest rate is used since that is the variable that affects output and therefore the multiplier and fiscal stabilization, our focus here.

  8. Since the Indian short rate did not adjust fully to volatile headline inflation, the real interest rate was often negative.

  9. A 4 variable SVAR where monetary policy is allowed to respond to capex in the long-run shows half the impact of capex on the real interest rate but it is still positive and qualitatively similar. Thus monetary policy does accommodate capex but the accommodation is lower compared to for revex because it neglects the impact of rising capex in reducing inflation expectations, while overall tightening occurs in response to the supply shocks. Results are available on request.

  10. As a referee points out teachers’ salaries (revex) could be as important as school buildings (capex) for generating long-run income streams, but we follow the government definition based on long run assets and find that revex and capex behave differently.

References

  • Ahmad, A.H., and Eric J. Pentecost. 2012. Identifying aggregate supply and demand shocks in small open economies: Empirical evidence from African countries. International Review of Economics & Finance 21 (1): 272–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, Alan and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2011. Fiscal multipliers in recession and expansion. NBER Working Paper No. 17747.

  • Baldacci, Emanuele, Sanjeev Gupta and Carlos Mulas-Granados. 2009. How effective is fiscal policy response in systemic banking crises? IMF Working Paper 09160 (July).

  • Batini Nicoletta, Luc Eyraud, Lorenzo Forni, and Anke Weber . 2014. Fiscal Multipliers: Size, Determinants, and Use in Macroeconomic Projections, IMF Technical Notes and Manuals, 14/04.

  • Batini, Nicoletta, Luc Eyraud and Anke Weber. 2014. A simple method to compute fiscal multipliers. IMF Working Paper No. 1493 (June).

  • Blanchard, Olivier J., and Danny Quah. 1989. The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. American Economic Review 79 (4): 655–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, Olivier J., and Roberto Perotti. 2002. An empirical characterisation of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1329–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 2011. When is the government spending multiplier large? Journal of Political Economy 119 (1): 78–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti Giancarlo, Andre Meier, and Gernot J. Müller. 2012. What Determines Government Spending Multipliers? IMF Working Paper, WP 12/ 150.

  • Cover, James P., Walter Enders and C. James Heung. 2004. Using the aggregate demand-aggregate supply model to identify structural demand-side and supply side shocks: results using bivariate VAR. University of Alabama, Finance and Legal Studies Working Paper (February).

  • Devarajan, Shantayanan, Vinaya Swaroop, and Heng-fu Zou. 1996. The composition of public expenditure and economic growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 37: 313–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gechert, Sebastian. 2015. What fiscal policy is most effective? A meta-regression analysis. Oxford Economic Papers 67 (3): 553–580.

  • Goyal, Ashima. 2012. Propagation mechanisms in inflation: governance as key. Chapter 3 in S. Mahendra Dev (ed.), India Development Report 2012, pp. 32–46, New Delhi: IGIDR and Oxford University Press.

  • Goyal, Ashima and Ayan K. Pujari. 2005. Identifying long run supply curve in India. Journal of Quantitative Economics Old Series 19(2), July 2003. New Series 3(2) (July).

  • Hemming, Richard, Michael Kell and Selma Mahfouz. 2002. The effectiveness of fiscal policy in stimulating economic activity – a review of the literature. IMF Working Paper No. 208.

  • Ilzetzki, Ethan, Enrique Mendoza and Carlos A. Vegh. 2011. How big (small) are fiscal multipliers? IMF Working Paper No. 1152 (March).

  • Ilzetzki, Ethan, and Carlos A. Vegh. 2008. Procyclical fiscal policy in developing countries: Truth or fiction? NBER Working Paper No. 14191.

  • Jain, Rajeev and Prabhat Kumar. 2013. Size of government expenditure multipliers in India: a structural VAR analysis. RBI Working Paper (September).

  • Karras, Georgios. 2014. Is fiscal policy more effective during cyclical downturns? International Economic Journal 28 (2): 255–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, Rajiv and Alamuru Soumya. 2010. Fiscal policy issues for India after the global financial crisis (2008-2010). ADBI Working Paper No. 249 (September).

  • Marattin, Luigi, and Simone Salotti. 2014. Consumption multipliers of different types of public spending: a structural vector error correction analysis for the UK. Empirical Economics 46 (4): 1197–1220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padoan, Pier Carlo. 2009. Fiscal policy in the crisis: impact, sustainability, and long-term implications. Asian Development Bank Working Paper No. 178 (December).

  • Perotti, R. 2005. Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD countries. Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

  • Qazizada, Walid, and Engelbert Stockhammer. 2015. Government spending multipliers in contraction and expansion. International Review of Applied Economics 29 (2): 238–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • RBI (Reserve Bank of India). 2014. Annual Report 2013-14. Available at https://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/AnnualReport/PDFs/RBIARE210814_FULL.pdf

  • Riera-Crichton, Daniel, Carlos A. Vegh, and Guillermo Vuletin. 2015. Procyclical and countercyclical fiscal multipliers: evidence from OECD countries. Journal of International Money and Finance 52: 15–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spilimbergo, Antonio, Steve Symansky and Martin Schindler. 2009. Fiscal multipliers. IMF Staff Position Note (November).

  • Strawczynski, Michael. 2009. Cyclicality of fiscal policy: permanent and transitory shocks. Bank of Israel (September).

  • Vinals, Jose. 2014. Back to the future: lessons from financial crises. Keynote Speech, Monetary and Capital Markets IMF (February).

Download references

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of the paper was presented at an IIM-Bangalore 2015 workshop. Valuable comments from Sanjeev Gupta, R.K. Pattanaik, Charan Singh and Parthasarathi Shome as well as from anonymous referees of this journal are gratefully acknowledged. We thank Reshma Aguiar for help with the word processing.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ashima Goyal.

Appendices

Appendices

A1. Stationarity of variables used in estimation

Variable

t-statistic

p-value

Capex growth

− 8.38117\(^{***}\)

0.00

Real interest rate

− 3.239939\(^{**}\)

0.0224

GDP growth

− 2.70917\(^{*}\)

0.0783

Revex growth

− 3.53444\(^{**}\)

0.0103

Totex growth

− 6.63957\(^{***}\)

0.00

Inflation

− 4.90293\(^{***}\)

0.0001

  1. ***Significant at 1% level of significance, **Significant at 5% level of significance, *Significant at 10% level of significance

Capex growth—Growth Rate of Central Government Capital Expenditure.

Revex growth—Growth Rate of Central Government Revenue Expenditure.

Totex growth—Growth Rate of Central Government Total Expenditure.

Inflation—WPI Inflation Rate

Real interest rate—Short-term real interest rate

The CMMR variable is stationary at 5% level of significance using the DF-GLS test.

Null hypothesis: CMMR has a unit root

Exogenous: Constant

Lag length: 0 (Automatic-based on SIC, maxlag=10)

 

t-Statistic

Elliott-Rothenberg-Stock DF-GLS test statistic

− 2.231382

Test critical values: 1% level

− 2.602794

5% level

− 1.946161

10% level

− 1.613398

A2. Structural VAR Analysis

See Figs. 4, 5, 6 and Tables 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10

Fig. 4
figure 4figure 4

IRF Capex a Including supply shocks. b IRFs Revex: including supply shocks

Fig. 5
figure 5figure 5

a IRFs revex: including monetary shocks. b IRFs Capex: including monetary shocks

Fig. 6
figure 6figure 6

a IRFs Revex: including monetary and supply shocks. b IRFs Capex: including monetary and supply shocks

Table 5 VDA Capex: Including supply shocks
Table 6 VDA Revex: including supply shocks
Table 7 VDA Revex: including monetary shocks
Table 8 VDA Capex: including monetary shocks
Table 9 VDA Revex: Including monetary and supply shocks
Table 10 VDA Capex: including monetary and supply shocks

A3. Robustness Checks:

See Figs. 7, 8 and Tables 11, 12

1. Introduction of additive dummy variable for the crisis period between 2008Q1 to 2009Q4

The GFC of 2008, triggered by the sub-prime mortgage crisis in the U.S. and the collapse of Lehman Brothers, saw an increase in fiscal expenditure by the Government in order to insulate the economy from the headwinds of downturn. It is thus necessary to check if this fiscal expansion and its exit, however slow and partial, starting 2010, influence the multiplier analysis.

A dummy variable ‘Crisis_Dum’ is introduced in the basic two-variable SVARs to see if the values and the behaviour of the multipliers and the IRFs change drastically once the crisis-led fiscal expansion is accounted for as an exogenous event in the model.

Fig. 7
figure 7

IRFs a Total Central Expenditure Growth and GDP Growth. b Capex Growth and GDP Growth. c Revenue Expenditure Growth and GDP Growth

Fig. 8
figure 8

IRFs a Total Central Expenditure Growth and GDP Growth. b Capex Growth and GDP Growth. c Revenue Expenditure Growth and GDP Growth

Accounting for this variable marginally increases the impact and peak multipliers for revex and leads to a significant increase in the cumulative multiplier. This increase can be attributed to the reduction in the fluctuations in impulse responses of revex to shocks to itself, since the crisis dummy accounts for a significant amount of movement in the revex growth (which is not the case for capex growth).

It is evident that despite accounting for the crisis dummy variable, the peak and cumulative multipliers for capex are larger than revex, implying that the long-run cumulative impact of capex is stronger even in the face of adverse exogenous shocks to the economy. The inclusion of this variable in the model does not alter the nature and magnitude of the impulse response of GDP growth to shocks in expenditure variables either.

2. Analysis with expenditure series deflated by GDP deflator series

The implicit GDP deflator series for the period 1998Q1 – 2014Q2 has been retrieved from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank’s Economic Research website (https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/INDGDPDEFQISMEI). The base year is 2010-11 and the series has been seasonally adjusted.

The growth variables are derived from the expenditure variables deflated by the above series. The average GDP to real total expenditure ratio in this scenario for 1999 Q1 to 2014 Q2 was 3.39, for real revex it was 3.97, for real capex the average ratio it was 25.93. The ratios are lower than that for WPI deflated series due to the differences in the values of WPI series (base year = 1993–1994) and the implicit GDP deflator series (base year = 2010–2011).

The Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) to structural one standard deviation innovations and two standard deviation error bands are given in Fig. 8a–c.

Table 11 Multipliers with short-run restrictions
Table 12 Multipliers with short-run restrictions

The IRFs do not show any marked difference in direction and magnitude from the original real expenditure variables (deflated by WPI series). The multiplier values also show the same behaviour, with the ratio of capex Multipliers to their revex counterparts being in the same range as observed in Table 1. The values are lower on account of lower magnitude of average output to spending ratio. Nevertheless, this analysis also confirms our major finding that the capex multipliers are much larger in the long-run as compared to revex multipliers.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Goyal, A., Sharma, B. Government Expenditure in India: Composition and Multipliers. J. Quant. Econ. 16 (Suppl 1), 47–85 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-018-0122-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40953-018-0122-y

Keywords

JEL classification code:

Navigation