Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The conundrum of labour shortage in a labour surplus economy: an investigation of Nepal

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Social and Economic Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Nepal continues to be an agrarian economy with agriculture providing primary employment to 64% of the workforce and contributing 21.3% in the value-added according to the most recent figures available (World Bank, 2020a, 2020b). The pressure on agricultural land is also more than that in its neighbouring countries China and India, which are still regarded as surplus labour economies. While this cursory picture indicates that Nepal is also a labour surplus agrarian economy in the Lewisian sense (Lewis, 1954), recent literature has consistently referred to labour shortage in agriculture (e.g. Maharjan et al., 2013b; Pant, 2013; Sunam & Adhikari, 2016; Tuladhar et al., 2014 to mention few) and indicated the exhaustion of surplus labour (Pant, 2013; Tuladhar et al., 2014)—an apparent conundrum that warrants further analysis. The paper starts by statistically confirming the presence of surplus labour in Nepal based on the most recent household survey available for the country (Nepal Living Standards Survey 2010/11) despite recent reports of labour shortage in the sector. In the next part, the paper investigates the role of migration in explaining labour shortage following relevant literature on Nepal and other countries (Rozelle et al., 1999; Tuladhar et al., 2014). Towards this end, Propensity Score Matching estimation is carried out. The results indicate that though migration led to reduction in agricultural output, this reduction cannot be interpreted as labour shortage, thereby rejecting the hypothesis that migration can systematically explain the recent labour shortage in Nepal.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Calculated based on (Central Bureau Of Statistics(CBS), 2012; CBS 2013b).

  2. “Subsistence” level wage does not carry its literal meaning i.e. wage below which people cannot subsist, rather it is more of a basic income, lower than the wage received in formal sector (Fields 2004, p. 729).

  3. 1 USD (U.S. Dollar) = 74.35 NPR (buy) on 1st January 2010 (Nepal Rastra Bank 2010).

  4. Not accounted for migration to India as visa/permit is not necessary to travel to India. 4 million permits do not necessarily mean 4 million new migrants. Some might not migrate even after permits and returnee might migrate again.

  5. Nepal Household Risk and Vulnerability Survey (2016, 2017, 2018) Panel Data is another alternative data source. However, this data does not provide information on hired and exchanged labour days and therefore not used in this paper.

  6. More than 60 product values are aggregated at household level. We have imputed the missing price for harvest following similar methods of CBS (CBS 2011b, p. 37). Details will be provided on request.

  7. Livestock Unit is calculated based on FAO (2011).

  8. Belt includes ecological division of Nepal as Mountain, Hill and Terai (plain region).

  9. Note that using double hash, i.e. ## and then using ‘lincom’ STATA command to get the slope of variables at belt level gives the same result as using single hash, i.e. #, in our case. We have checked it. So, for our convenience we use single hash to get the slope at belt. Same holds for Eq. 3 as well.

  10. Analytical domain is the lowest level of aggregation for which the data is representative.

  11. Working age (15 ≤ age < 60) absentee are considered as migrant. NLSS-III defined absentee as individual “away from the household for more than 6 months out of the last 12 months, or has recently left and is expected to be away for more than 6 months, and will return to the same household in the future”, (CBS 2011a, p. 132).

  12. Turning Point is the point after which the difference between subsistence sector and modern sector wither away and whole economy begins to function under the logic of market economy. It is also the point where Marginal Product of Labour equals rural agriculture wage rate. Using latter condition, we calculate Equilibrium Labour in the Table 2.

  13. Bootstrap is the suggested method to calculate the standard errors when using ‘kmatch’ STATA command. Though ‘teffects’ STATA command is suggested to use for standard error, this command do not allow us to do kernel algorithm for PS matching.

  14. The Propensity Density Plot, Common Support Density Plot, Standard Difference of Mean and Variance ration, and sensitivity analysis has been reported in Appendix 2. The graphs and table show that estimated propensity score balance the covariates, satisfies overlap assumption and result is not very sensitive to ‘hidden bias’.

  15. Bias-corrected estimator is used as suggested in STATA manual.

References

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks the anonymous referees and Editor for their comments which helped sharpen the argument in this article. He is indebted to Dr. Anirban Dasgupta for his critical reviews and comments. This paper is part of the author’s ongoing PhD research in the Faculty of Economics at South Asian University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ishwor Adhikari.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author has no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix

Appendix 1: Descriptive statistics of covariates used in PSM exercise and Cobb–Douglas production function estimate

Table 5 presents the descriptive statistics of some important control variables used in regression analysis, specifically for the migration equation. The mean value of harvest is around NPR 43,309 over the agriculture calendar year. There is a negligible difference in the value of harvest between migrant and non-migrant households. This difference is not statistically significant. The migrant household has an older head than the non-migrant household before migration.  The head of the migrant household has more formal education and slighter bigger household size. Migrant households have less share of children and elderly, while more share of men and women than non-migrant households. Caste/ethnicity division of migrant and non-migrant households are almost the same.

Table 5 Mean of Sample over Migrant and non-Migrant Household, the difference in mean and statistical significance

Regarding ownership, on average, migrant households have 0.77 hectares of land under control while non-migrant households have 0.70 hectares, with more plots and better quality of the land. Migrant households’ local residence area seems more electrified than that of non-migrant households. Similarly, migrant households seem to reside closer to the agriculture input market than non-migrant households. Wage employment is more prevalent in non-migrant communities than in migrant communities at the district level, and the rest of the variables have negligible differences (Table 5).

Table 6 Cobb–Douglas Production function estimation

Appendix 2: Balance, overlap, sensitivity analysis for PSM and Nearest Neighbourhood matching estimates

The matching on the estimated propensity score balance in our data as the density plot for the matched samples is nearly indistinguishable (Fig. 1).

The box plot (Fig. 2)  also indicates that our matched data are properly balanced. The median, 25th percentiles, and 75th percentile appear to be the same for matched sample.

The graph (Fig. 3) displays the estimated density of the predicted probabilities that a migrant household do not send migrant and the estimated density of the predicted probabilities that non-migrant household do not send migrant.

Neither plot indicates too much probability mass near 0 or 1. There is no evidence that the overlap assumption is violated (Fig. 3).

The matched sample results in Table 7, indicate that matching on the estimated propensity score balanced the covariates. We can see in Table 7 that Standardized differences for matched sample is less than 0.10 in absolute term, which is the rule of thumb value. So, our matching estimate balances the covariates. Most of the ratio of variance in the matched sample is around 1.

Table 7 Covariate Balance Summary

We also calculated Rubin’s B and Rubin’s R to check the balance. We found Rubin’s B 18.2 and Rubin’s R 1.33. Rubin (2001) recommends that B be less than 25 and R be between 0.5 and 2 for the samples to be considered sufficiently balanced.

Though balanced in observed covariates, criticisms remain about unobserved covariates which might lead to hidden bias. “In an observational study, one could never assert with warranted conviction that the naïve model is precisely true” (Rosenbaum 2020, p. 85). “The sensitivity of an observational study to bias from an unmeasured covariate is the magnitude of the departure from the naïve model that would need to be present to materially alter the study’s conclusions.” (ibid.)

The first row, in Table 8, Γ = 1, is the usual randomization inference. To alter our conclusion that migration has negative impact on value of harvest, Γ should be 2.4, which permits a substantial departure from random treatment assignment. It, Γ = 2.4, implies that two households with the same observed covariates may not have the same chance of migration. One such household is almost two and half times more likely to be a migrant because they differ in terms of unobserved covariates. Till Γ = 2.3, our conclusion does not alter. So, our study is not very sensitive to unobserved or ‘hidden bias’ (Table 8).

Table 8 Sensitivity analysis
Table 9 Propensity Score and Nearest Neighbourhood matching using different algorithms

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Adhikari, I. The conundrum of labour shortage in a labour surplus economy: an investigation of Nepal. J. Soc. Econ. Dev. 24, 404–435 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-022-00196-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-022-00196-y

Keywords

Navigation