Skip to main content
Log in

Social science puzzles: a systems analysis challenge

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

As shown, a common source for a wide range of problems and complexities that arise in the social sciences is an unexpected loss of needed information. This includes concerns from social choice, economics, probability/statistics, etc. But by identifying the content of the lost information, negative assertions may be replaced with positive conclusions; this requires finding ways to reincorporate the missing information.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A positional method tallies ballots by assigning specified points to candidates according to how their ballot position. This example has seven different positional rankings; four have no ties.

  2. Whenever agents are to select an alternative, which is true of all Sen examples that I have seen, Sen’s non-cyclic condition becomes a special case of Arrow’s condition of a complete, transitive outcome.

  3. By examining the proof, it follows that this assertion holds for all settings with a cyclic outcome.

  4. If \(s<\frac{1}{2},\) these rankings are reversed. The \(s=\frac{1}{2}\) choice defines the Borda Count, which is immune to this symmetry distraction by having complete ties and agreeing with pairwise and the quadruple positional outcomes.

References

  • Arrow KJ (1951) Social choice and individual values. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargagliotti A, Saari DG (2010) Symmetry of nonparametric statistical tests on three samples. J MathStat 6(4):395–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1974) Excess demand functions. J Math Econ 1:15–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haunsperger D (1992) Dictionaries of paradoxes for statistical tests on k samples. JASA 87:149–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Jervis R (1998) System effects: complexity in political science and social life. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Katz L (2012) Why the law is so perverse. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantel R (1974) On the characterization of of aggregate excess demand. J Econ Theory 7:348–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1989) A dictionary for voting paradoxes. J Econ Theory 48:443–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1992) The aggregate excess demand function and other aggregation procedures. Econ Theory 2:359–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1995a) Basic geometry of voting. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1995b) Mathematical complexity of simple economics. Not AMS 42(2):222–230

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1999) Explaining all three-alternative voting outcomes. J Econ Theory 87:313–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (1999) Do we model the correct market information? In: Herings PJJ, Talman AJJ, van de Laan G (eds) Theory the, of markets. North Holland, New York, pp 83–108

  • Saari DG (2000a) Mathematical structure of voting paradoxes. Econ Theory 15:1–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2000b) Mathematical structure of voting paradoxes 2: positional voting. Econ Theory 15:55–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2001) Decisions and elections. Explaining the unexpected. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2008) Disposing dictators, demystifying voting paradoxes. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2014) Unifying voting theory from Nakamura’s to Greenberg’s Theorems. Math Social Sci 69:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2014) A new way to analyze paired comparison rules. Math Oper Res 39:647–655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari DG (2015) From Arrow’s Theorem to “dark matter,” to appear in British. J Polit Sci

  • Saari DG, Sieberg K (2004) Are partwise comparisons reliable? Res Eng Design 15:62–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein H (1972) Market excess demand functions. Econometrica 40:649–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1970) The impossibility of a Paretian liberal. J Polit Econ 78:152–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stearns M (2002) Constitutional process: a social choice analysis of supreme court decision making. University of Michigan Press, Michigan

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Donald G. Saari.

Additional information

This paper is an extended version of my presentation at an August 2014 workshop “Recent developments on geometrical and algebraic methods in Economics” at Hokkaido University, Sapporo, Japan. My thanks to Prof. Simona Settepanella for inviting me to participate and her hospitality while I was there. Also, my thanks for the several useful suggestions that were offered by two referees.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Saari, D.G. Social science puzzles: a systems analysis challenge. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 12, 123–139 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-015-0008-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-015-0008-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation