Skip to main content
Log in

Monetary policy challenges: how central banks changed their modus operandi

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Eurasian Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 09 July 2015

Abstract

The financial crisis that started in August 2007 deeply changed the modus operandi of monetary policy on both sides of the Atlantic Ocean and stimulated a debate about how to formally define and practically implement newly relevant objectives, such as systemic stability, in the reaction function of the Monetary Authorities. This paper provides an assessment of the monetary policy decisions and interventions undertaken by the FED and the ECB, and evaluates the respective monetary policy regimes in place before and during the crisis according to the lessons derived from the theoretical literature on monetary policy developed in the last 2 decades.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The model is sketched in Sect. 4 where the treatment follows Di Giorgio and Rotondi (2010).

  2. Notice that, although clearly different from a conceptual point of view, in the practice operative targets may be confused with policy tools, given that central banks are endowed with sufficient power in the interbank market so as to reach rapidly the desired level of target variables.

  3. To tell the truth, even before 2003 the rate of growth of M3 was not de facto a true intermediate target. Broad money largely exceeded the target value without calling for correcting actions of the central bank. The ECB justified this inaction by relying on the second pillar of its monetary policy strategy, the so called economic and financial analysis (see the ECB web site for a complete description of the Eurosystem monetary policy regime).

  4. See Di Giorgio and Nistico (2007) and the literature quoted in that paper.

  5. See Shirai (2014) for a comprehensive assessment of recent monetary policy management in Japan and see Aysan (2014) and Oduncu (2014) for recent studies on monetary policy and its effects in developing countries.

  6. The artificial series generated by the counterfactual Taylor rule is obtained via the following formula: \( r_{t}^{TR} = 1,5 \cdot \pi_{t} + 0,5 \cdot \tilde{x}_{t} , \) where \( \pi_{t} \) is current inflation, computed as percentage variation from one year ago of CPI index, and \( \tilde{x}_{t} \) is output gap as measured by Congressional Budget Office.

  7. A complete list of such facilities is easily obtained (and carefully described) by visiting the websites of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. It includes the term securities lending facility, the term discount window facility, the term security lending facility options program, the ABCP money market fund liquidity facility, the commercial paper funding facility and other tools.

  8. This late response is in evident contrast with the forward looking behaviour often advocated by academics as a necessary ingredient for monetary policy management.

  9. See Bernanke and Gertler (2001), Cecchetti et al. (2002) and Di Giorgio and Nistico (2007).

  10. See for instance Taylor (2010), Walsh (2009) and Blinder (2010). The treatment here follows closely Di Giorgio and Rotondi (2010).

  11. See for instance Svensson (2002, 2003, 2005) and McCallum and Nelson (2005).

  12. See Driffill et al. (2006) for empirical evidence supporting the Fed’s reaction to basis risk based on an estimated Taylor-type rule.

  13. See Hull (2000) for a discussion on the validity of this assumption.

  14. Accordingly, rational agents expecting this behaviour from the central bank will find the basis risk reduced to zero. Clearly, such a policy rule would also imply no reaction to deviations of inflation or output from their trend level.

  15. Notice that the fraction terms are all positive if \( \left[ {\left( {1 + \beta } \right)\lambda_{\varDelta } + \hat{\lambda }_{r} } \right] > 0 \), which holds under the calibrated parameter values considered in Woodford (2003).

References

  • Aysan, A. F. (2014). Managing short-term capital flows in new central banking: unconventional monetary policy framework in Turkey. Eurasian Economic Review, 4(1), 47–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., (2004) The great moderation. In: The Meetings of the Eastern Economic Association. U.S.A. Washington, DC, 20 February 2004.

  • Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (2001). Should central banks respond to movements in asset prices? American Economic Review, 91(2), 253–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A., (2010). Quantitative easing: Entrance and exit strategies. Princeton University Working Papers, 1219.

  • Bullard, J., & Mitra, K. (2002). Learning about monetary policy rules. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(6), 1105–1129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti, S., Genberg, H., & Wadhwani, S. (2002). Asset prices in a flexible inflation targeting framework. In W. Hunter, G. Kaufman, & M. Pomerlano (Eds.), Asset price bubbles. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1661–1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (2002). A simple framework for international monetary policy analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(5), 879–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curdia, V., & Woodford, M. (2011). The central-bank balance sheet as an instrument of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 54–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Giorgio, G., & Nistico, S. (2007). Monetary policy and stock prices in an open economy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(8), 1947–1985.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Giorgio, G., Rotondi, Z., 2010. The Future of Monetary Policy: Exit Strategies between Art and Science. In: Fondazione Rosselli, Le Banche italiane sono speciali? Quindicesimo rapporto sul sistema finanzario italiano [Are Italian banks special? 15th Report on the Italian Financial System]. EDIBANK, Milano.

  • Di Giorgio, G., & Rotondi, Z. (2011). Financial stability, interest-rate smoothing and equilibrium determinacy. Journal of Financial Stability, 7(1), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driffill, J., Rotondi, Z., Savona, P., & Zazzara, C. (2006). Monetary policy and financial stability: what role for futures market? Journal of Financial Stability, 2(1), 95–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull, J. C. (2000). Options, futures and other derivatives (4th ed.). Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, H., (2002). Monetary policy frameworks and real equilibrium determinacy. Mimeo, University of Copenhagen. [pdf] Available at: http://www.econ.ku.dk/personal/henrikj/pdf/tandirules.pdf [Accessed 2 February 2014].

  • McCallum, B., & Nelson, E. (2005). Targeting vs. instrument rules for monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(5), 597–611.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oduncu, A. (2014). Effects of additional monetary tightening on exchange rates. Eurasian Economic Review, 4(1), 75–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sack, B. (2004). Extracting the expected path of monetary policy from futures rates. Journal of Futures Markets, 24(8), 733–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shirai, S. (2014). Japan’s monetary policy in a changing environment. Eurasian Economic Review, 4(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. E. O. (2002). Inflation targeting: should it be modeled as an instrument rule or a targeting rule? European Economic Review, 46(4–5), 771–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. E. O. (2003). What is wrong with Taylor Rules? Using judgment in monetary policy through targeting rules. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(2), 426–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. E. O. (2005). Targeting rules vs. instrument rules for monetary policy: what is wrong with McCallum and Nelson? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(5), 613–626.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39(1), 195–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J., (2007). Housing and monetary policy. NBER Working Paper, 13682.

  • Taylor, J. (2008). Getting off track. California: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J., (2010). An exit rule for monetary policy. Stanford University Working Paper, 09-009.

  • Walsh, C., (2009). Using monetary policy to stabilize economic activity. In: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Financial Stability and Macroeconomic Policy, Wyoming, USA, 20–22 August 2009.

  • Woodford, M. (2003). Optimal interest-rate smoothing. Review of Economic Studies, 70(4), 861–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author wish to thank Hakan Danis, Stefano Marzioni, Paul Johnson, and an anonymous referee for valuable comments. Any remaining mistake is only to him.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giorgio Di Giorgio.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Di Giorgio, G. Monetary policy challenges: how central banks changed their modus operandi. Eurasian Econ Rev 4, 25–43 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-014-0002-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-014-0002-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation