Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Routine-biased technological change and wage inequality: do workers’ perceptions matter?

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Eurasian Business Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Routine-Biased Technological Change (RBTC) has been regarded as a relatively novel technology-based explanation of social changes affecting job and wage polarization. In this paper, we investigate wage inequality between routine and non-routine workers along the wage distribution in Italy. Thanks to unique survey data, we can estimate the wage differential using both the actual and the perceived level of routine intensity of jobs to classify workers. We adopt semi-parametric decomposition techniques to quantify the importance of worker characteristics in explaining the gaps. We also employ non-parametric techniques to account for self-selection bias. We find evidence of a significant U-shaped pattern in the wage gap, according to both definitions, with non-routine workers always earning significantly more than routine workers. Results show that worker characteristics fully explain the gap in the case of perceived routine, while they account for no more than 50% of the gap across the distribution in the case of actual routine. Thus, the results highlight the importance of taking into account workers’ perceptions to reduce the set of omitted vaiables when analyzing determinants of wage inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In line with Rohrbach-Schmidt and Tiemann (2013) we use the terms “subjective” and “self-defined/self-assessed” interchangeably to define the definition of routine at the worker’s level and the term “objective” to define the actual level of routine at the occupational level.

  2. Sticky-floor refers to a situation in which the 10th percentile wage gap is higher than the estimated wage gap at the 50th percentile. Glass ceiling refers to a situation in which the 90th percentile wage gap is higher than the estimated wage gap at the 50th percentile.

  3. Also Stinebrickner et al., (2019a; 2019b) using job-level information from the the Berea Panel Study, find that current job-tasks significantly determine wages in the US.

  4. Even though it is possible that interviewees may have not the same understanding of the term as the RBTC, this is the general problem with self-assessed measures, while the main advantage is precisely capturing real individual perceptions, without any mediating factor.

  5. The self-assessed approach has a subjective nature and consists in asking workers about the educational requirements set by the firm to get the job or the level required for the job, according to their view, and comparing it with their actual level of education. For example, in the OECD’s Survey of Adult Skills (PIAAC), individuals are asked, relative to their own education, what level of education they think would be necessary to satisfactorily do their job. In a similar way, we follow a subjective approach by asking workers if their work can be considered routine.

  6. Many kernel functions can be used to the scope. In our exercise we chose the Gaussian kernel evaluated at (\(w - w_{i}\)) given the bandwidth h. Our choice of the kernel is due to its property of monotonicity of peaks and valleys w.r.t. changes in the smoothing parameters, which proves to be useful when comparing distributions (Sheather, 2004). For what concerns the bandwidth, our choice has fallen on the Cross Validation (CV) method: it is suitable as there is no need to make assumptions about the smoothness to which the unknown density belongs (Loader, 1999).

  7. The US O*Net database is based on the Dictionary of Occupational Titles (DOT hereafter), which since 1939 has provided information on occupations, with a specific focus on the skills required in the public employment service. The O*Net is based on the Standard Occupational Classification (SOC), providing for each elementary occupation variables on knowledge, skills, abilities, and tasks. The key dimensions included in the O*Net are the following: worker characteristics: permanent characteristics affecting workers’ performance as well as their propensity to acquire knowledge and skills; worker requirements: workers’ characteristics measured by means of experience and education; experience: characteristics mostly related to past work experience; occupation: a large set of variables referring to requirements and specific features of the various occupations.

  8. See also Barbieri et al. (2021), Bonacini et al. (2021) and Cirillo et al. (2020).

  9. In line with the literature (Autor and Dorn, 2013; Firpo et al., 2013; Goos et al., 2014) we calculate the RTI assuming rank-stability of tasks for the short-time span, since occupational task requirements are likely to be time invariant or to change at a very slow rate, thus leaving the rank of occupations substantially invariant.

  10. These figures differ from those presented in the regression analyses as many individuals are discarded for lack of characteristics.

  11. We included this variable because it is the only way to consider the household's wealth: therefore, the ability to make ends meet could be high even in the absence of sufficient wages. By the way, we used a different specification of the model by excluding this variable and results hold. Results are available from the authors upon request.

  12. In the regression analysis many observations (i.e. many individuals) are discarded because of lack of information on used covariates. This is why the number of observations in the regressions is different from that in the Table 4.

  13. There could be some variables which could suffer from potential endogeneity: in particular, this could be the case of the variables “make ends meet”, “stress” and “training”: nonetheless, both the regression analyses and the Oaxaca decomposition do not show significant differences when these variables are discarded. This is to be interpreted as a sign of weak or virtually absent endogeneity. This “leave-them-out” approach has been chosen due to the lack of feasible instruments within our cross-sectional database. In the case of the Oaxaca decomposition, the wage differential explained by endowments is 77% of the total when those variables are included and only slightly decrease to 73% when those are excluded. Results of these analyses are available upon request.

  14. It should be noted that methods like RIF-regressions are not unproblematic due to their strong assumptions. As argued in Kassenboehmer and Sinning (2014) RIF-regression implies that the respective feature of the outcome distribution depends on the marginal distribution of the covariates only through their mean.

  15. The clusterization of standard errors at the occupational level does not produce significant changes in the estimates. Results are available from the authors upon request.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (1998). Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1055–1089.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Autor, D. H. (2011). Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings. In Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 4b, Ch. 12.

  • Addison, J. T. (2020). The consequences of trade union power erosion. IZA World of Labor. https://doi.org/10.15185/izawol.68.v2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonczyk, D., DeLeire, T., & Fitzenberger, B. (2010). Polarization and rising wage inequality: Comparing the U.S. and Germany. Econometrics, 6(2), 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arntz, M., Gregory, T., & Zierahn, U. (2017). Revisiting the risk of automation. Economics Letters, 159, 157–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atalay, E., Phongthiengtham, P., Sotelo, S., & Tannenbaum, D. (2018). New technologies and the labor market. Journal of Monetary Economics, 97, 48–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. (2008). The changing distribution of earnings in OECD countries. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H. (2013). The “task approach” to labor markets: An overview. Journal of Labour Market Research, 46(3), 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H., & Dorn, D. (2013). The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1553–1597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H., & Handel, M. J. (2013). Putting tasks to the test: Human capital, job tasks, and wages. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(S1), S59–S96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D., Levy, F., & Murnane R. J. (2003). The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1279–1333.

  • Autor, D. H., Katz, L. F., & Kearney, M. S. (2008). Trends in U.S. wage inequality: Revising the revisionists. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2), 300–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., Hanson, G. H., & Song, J. (2014). Trade adjustment: Worker-level evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4), 1799–1860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbieri, L., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2019). R&D, embodied technological change, and employment: Evidence from Italian microdata. Industrial and Corporate Change, 28(1), 203–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbieri, T., Basso, G., & Scicchitano, S. (2021). Italian workers at risk during the COVID-19 epidemic. Italian Economic Journal. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-021-00164-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basso, G. (2020). The evolution of the occupational structure in Italy, 2007–2017. Social Indicators Research: An International and Interdisciplinary Journal for Quality-of-Life Measurement, 152, 673–704. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02460-2

  • Blinder, A. (1973). Wage discrimination: Reduced form and structural estimates. Journal of Human Resources, 8(4), 436–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogliacino, F., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). R&D and employment: An application of the lsdvc estimator using European microdata. Economic Letters, 116, 56–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogliacino, F., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). The job creation effect of R&D expenditures. Australian Economic Papers, 51, 96–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonacini, L., Gallo, G., & Scicchitano, S. (2021). Working from home and income inequality. Risks of a “new normal” with COVID-19. Journal of Population Economics, 34(1), 303–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, M., Fracasso, A., Scicchitano, S., Traverso, S., & Tundis, E. (2021). Stop worrying and love the robot: An activity-based approach to assess the impact of robotization on employment dynamics, GLO Discussion Paper, No. 802, Global Labor Organization (GLO), Essen.

  • Cassandro, N., Centra, M., Guarascio, D. et al. (2021). What drives employment–unemployment transitions? Evidence from Italian task-based data. Economia Politica, 38, 1109–1147. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-021-00237-5

  • Cirillo, V. (2014). Patterns of innovation and wage distribution. Do “innovative firms” pay higher wages? Evidence from Chile. Eurasian Business Review, 4, 181–206. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-014-0010-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cirillo, V., Evangelista, R., Guarascio, D., & Sostero, M. (2020). Digitalization, routineness and employment: An exploration on Italian task-based data. Research Policy,. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0048733320301578?via%3Dihub

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cortes, G. M. (2016). Where have the middle-wage workers gone? A study of polarization using panel data. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(1), 63–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Rica, S., Gortazar, L., & Lewandowski, P. (2020). Job tasks and wages in developed countries: Evidence from PIAAC. Labour Economics, 65, 101845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Destefanis, S., & Mastromatteo, G. (2015). The OECD beveridge curve: Technological progress, globalisation and institutional factors. Eurasian Business Review, 5, 151–172. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-015-0019-z

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiNardo, J., Fortin, N., & Lemieux, T. (1996). Labor market institutions, and the distribution of wages, 1973–1992: A semi-parametric approach. Econometrica, 64, 1001–1044.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolton, P., & Vignoles, A. (2000). The incidence and effects of over-education in the UK graduate labour market. Economics of Education Review, 19(2), 179–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evangelista, R., & Savona, M. (2003). Innovation, employment and skills in services. Firm and sectoral evidence. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 14, 449–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, M., & Hagsten, E. (2021). Innovation intensity and skills in firms across five European countries. Eurasian Business Review, 11, 371–394. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-021-00188-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Firpo, S., Fortin, N. M., & Lemieux, T. (2013). Occupational Tasks and Changes in the Wage Structure. University of British Columbia Working Paper.

  • Firpo, S., Fortin, N., & Lemieux, T. (2018). Decomposing wage distributions using recentered influence function regressions. Econometrics, 6(2), 28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzini, M., & Raitano, M. (2019). Earnings inequality and workers’ skills in Italy. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 51, 215–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goos, M., & Manning, A. (2007). Lousy and lovely jobs: The rising polarization of work in Britain. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1), 118–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goos, M., Manning, A., & Salomons, A. (2014). Explaining job polarization: Routine-biased technological change and offshoring. American Economic Review, 104(8), 2509–2526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, F., & Zhu, Y. (2010). Over qualification, job dissatisfaction, and increasing dispersion in the returns to graduate education. Oxford Economic Papers, 62(4), 740–763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haile, G., Srour, I., & Vivarelli, M. (2017). Imported technology and manufacturing employment in Ethiopia. Eurasian Business Review, 7, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartog, J. (2000). Over-Education and Earnings: Where Are We, Where Should We Go? Economics of Education Review, 19, 131–147. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0272-7757(99)00050-3

  • Hirano, K., Imbens, G.W., & Ridder, G. (2003). Efficient estimation of average treatment effects using the estimated propensity score. Econometrica, 71, 1161–1189. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00442

  • Jann, B. (2008). The Blinder-Oaxaca decomposition for linear regression models. The Stata Journal, 8(4), 453–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kampelmann, S., & Rycx, F. (2013). The dynamics of task-biased technological change: The case of occupations. Brussels Economic Review, 56(2).

  • Kassenboehmer, S. C., & Sinning, M. G. (2014). Distributional changes in the gender wage gap. ILR Review, 67(2), 335–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, L. F., & Murphy, K. M. (1992). Changes in relative wages, 1963–1987: Supply and demand factors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1), 35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loader, C. R. (1999). Bandwidth selection: Classical or plugin? The Annals of Statistics, 27(2), 415–438. https://doi.org/10.1214/aos/1018031201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marcolin, L., Miroudot, S., & Squicciarini, M. (2018). To be (routine) or not to be (routine), that is the question: A cross-country task-based answer. Industrial and Corporate Change, 28(3), 477–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuinness, S. (2006). Overeducation in the labour market. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(3), 387–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuinness, S., Pouliakas, K., & Redmond, P. (2018). Skill mismatch: Concepts, measurement, and policy approaches. Journal of Economic Surveys, 32(4), 985–1015.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melly, B. (2005). Decomposition of differences in distribution using quantile regression. Labour Economics, 12, 577–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra, A., & Jha, A. K. (2015). Innovation and employment: A firm level study of Indian industries. Eurasian Business Review, 5, 45–71. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-015-0015-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munoz-de Bustillo, R., Sarkar, S., Sebastian, R., & Antón, J. I. (2018). Educational mismatch in Europe at the turn of the century: Measurement, intensity and evolution. International Journal of Manpower, 39(8), 977–995.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naticchioni, P., Ragusa, G., & Massari, R. (2014). Unconditional and Conditional Wage Polarization in Europe. IZA Discussion Paper No. 8465. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2502325

  • Oaxaca, R. (1973). Male-female differentials in urban labor markets. International Economic Review, 14(3), 673–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2018a). Is innovation destroying jobs? Firm-level evidence from the EU. Sustainability, 10(4), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2018b). Technological change and employment: Is Europe ready for the challenge? Eurasian Business Review, 8, 13–32. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-017-0100-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohrbach-Schmidt, D., & Tiemann, M. (2013). Changes in workplace tasks in Germany—Evaluating skill and task measures. Journal for Labour Market Research, 46, 215–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2020). The effect of intensive margin changes to task content on employment dynamics over the business cycle. ILR Review, 86, 001979392091074.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacchi, S. (2018). The Italian welfare state in the crisis: Learning to adjust? South European Society and Politics, 23(1), 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1080/13608746.2018.1433478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scicchitano, S., Biagetti, M., & Chirumbolo, A. (2020). More insecure and less paid? The effect of perceived job insecurity on wage distribution. Applied Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, 52(18), 1998–2013.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheather, S. J. (2004). Density estimation. Statistical Science, 19, 588–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spenner, K. I. (1990). Skill: meanings, methods, and measures. Work and Occupations, 17(4), 399–421. https://doi.org/10.1177/0730888490017004002

  • Spitz-Oener, A. (2006). Technical change, job tasks, and rising educational demands: Looking outside the wage structure. Journal of Labor Economics, 24(2), 235–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stinebrickner, R., Stinebrickner, T., & Sullivan, P. (2019a). Job tasks, time allocation, and wages. Journal of Labor Economics, 37(2), 399–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stinebrickner, R., Stinebrickner, T., & Sullivan, P. (2019b). Beauty, job tasks, and wages: A new conclusion about employer taste-based discrimination. The Review of Economics and Statistics. MIT Press, vol. 101(4), pp. 602–615.

  • Töpfer, M. (2017). Detailed RIF decomposition with selection: the gender pay gap in Italy (No. 26–2017), Hohenheim Discussion Papers in Business, Economics and Social Sciences.

  • Utar, H. (2018). Workers beneath the floodgates: Low-wage import competition and workers’ adjustment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 100(4), 631–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M. (2013). Technology, employment and skills: An interpretative framework. Eurasian Business Review, 3, 66–89. https://doi.org/10.14208/BF03353818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M. (2014). Innovation, employment and skills in advanced and developing countries: A survey of economic literature. Journal of Economic Issues, 2014(48), 123–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M., & Pianta, M. (2000). The Employment Impact of Innovation: Evidence and Policy. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Branko Milanovic, Pascual Restrepo, Paolo Severati, participants at 16th Annual Conference of the ESPAnet Europe, 30 August–1 September, 2018, Vilnius, at the II Astril Annual Conference “Technology, Employement, Institutions”, University Roma Tre, 13-14 December, at the Tasks V: Robotics, Artificial Intelligence and the Future of Work, organized by IAB, BIBB and ZEW, Bonn, Germany, 7-8 February 2019, at the European Meeting on Applied Evolutionary Economics (EMAEE) 2019 “Economics, Governance and Management of AI, Robots and Digital Transformations”, SPRU, University of Sussex, 3-6 June 2019, for useful comments. We also like to thank the Editor in Chief and the two referees for many useful comments that have significantly improved the paper. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Institutions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sergio Scicchitano.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

See Appendix Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10; Figs. 3, 4, 5, 6.

Table 3 The structure of the Routine Task Index
Table 4 Summary statistics for the whole sample and by subjective and objective routinarity
Table 5 Kolmogorov–Smirnov test for comparison between routine and non-routine workers, for both definitions
Table 6 Mincerian wage regression, subjective routine = no
Table 7 Mincerian wage regression, subjective routine = yes
Table 8 Mincerian wage regression, objective routine = no
Table 9 Mincerian wage regression, objective routine = yes
Table 10 Counterfactual decomposition using unconditional quantile regression based on a recentered influence function (RIF)
Fig. 3
figure 3

Source: OECD Employment Outlook (2017). European Labour Force Survey, Labour force surveys for Canada (LFS), Japan (LFS), Switzerland (LFS), and the United States (CPS MORG)

Job polarization in Europe.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Observed differences in non-routine/routine workers’ wage distributions

Fig. 5
figure 5

a, b Actual vs counterfactual wage distribution (using non-parametric estimation). Subjective routinarity (top panel) and objective routinarity (bottom panel)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Decomposition of differences in distribution using quantile regression (semi-parametric). Subjective routine at the occupational-4 digit level

Appendix B

2.1 Blinder Oaxaca and quantile-regression based decompositions

By means of the Blinder-Oaxaca (B-O) decomposition, a researcher can explain how much of the difference in the mean wage across two groups is due to group differences in the levels of explanatory variables, and how much is due to differences in the magnitude of regression coefficients (Blinder, 1973; Oaxaca, 1973). If N and R are the two groups of non-routine and routine workers, the mean wage difference to be explained \((\Delta \overline{y }\)) is simply the difference in the mean wage for observations in those two groups, denoted \({\overline{y} }_{n}\) and \({\overline{y} }_{r}\), respectively:

$$\Delta \overline{y} = \overline{ y}_{n} - \overline{y}_{r}$$
(9)

In the context of a linear regression, the mean wage for group W \(=N,R\) can be expressed as \(\overline{y}_{W} = \overline{X}^{\prime}_{W} \hat{\beta }_{W}\), where \({\overline{X} }_{\text{W}}\) contains the mean values of explanatory variables and \(\hat{\beta }_{W}\) the estimated regression coefficient. Hence, \(\Delta \overline{y }\) can be rewritten as:

$$\Delta \overline{y} = \overline{{X^{\prime}}}_{n} \hat{\beta }_{n} - \overline{{X^{\prime}}}_{r} \hat{\beta }_{r}$$
(10)

The twofold approach splits the mean outcome difference with respect to a vector of non-discriminatory coefficients \(\hat{\beta }_{R}\). The wage difference in (10) can then be written as

$$\Delta \overline{y} = { }\left( {\overline{X}_{{\text{n}}} - \overline{X}_{{\text{r}}} { }} \right){^{\prime}}\hat{\beta }_{{\text{n}}} + \overline{X^{\prime}}_{{\text{n}}} { }\left( {\hat{\beta }_{{\text{n}}} - \hat{\beta }_{{\text{r}}} } \right) + \overline{X^{\prime}}_{{\text{r}}} \left( {\hat{\beta }_{{\text{r}}} - \hat{\beta }_{{\text{n}}} } \right)$$
(11)

In Eq. (11) the first term is the explained component, while the sum between the second and the third term is the unexplained component.

While the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) method provides estimates for the conditional mean exclusively, the Quantile Regression (QR) technique allows for the estimation of the whole conditional wage distribution. Moreover, QR estimates capture changes in the shape, dispersion and location of the distribution, while OLS estimates do not. This can be a source of misleading relevant information on the wage distribution for routine and non-routine workers. Put in another way, the QR method (Koenker & Bassett, 1978), seems to be more interesting, and more appropriate in this context: the θth quantile of a variable conditional on some covariates can be accounted for and the effect of those covariates at selected quantiles of the distribution can be estimated.

Being \(y_{i}\) the dependent variable and \(x_{i}\) the vector of the chosen explanatory variables, the relation is given by:

$$y_{i} = x_{i} \beta \left( \theta \right) + \varepsilon_{i} \,\,{\text{ with }}\,\,F_{\varepsilon }^{ - 1} \left( {\theta |X} \right) = 0$$
(12)

where \(\, F_{\varepsilon }^{ - 1} \left( {\theta |X} \right)\) represents the θth quantile of ε conditional on x. The estimated θth quantile is obtained by solving the following equation:

$$\mathop {\min }\limits_{\beta \left( \theta \right)} \left\{ {\sum\limits_{{\left( {i:y_{i} \ge x_{i} \beta \left( \theta \right)} \right)}}^{N} {\theta \left| {y_{i} = x_{i} \beta \left( \theta \right)} \right| + \sum\limits_{{\left( {i:y_{i} \le x_{i} \beta \left( \theta \right)} \right)}}^{N} {\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left| {y_{i} = x_{i} \beta \left( \theta \right)} \right|} } } \right\}$$
(13)

and β(θ) is chosen to minimize the weighted sum of the absolute value of the residuals.

Once the QR coefficients have been estimated, the differences at the selected quantiles of the wage distribution between the two groups can be divided into one component based on the differences in characteristics and another based on the differences in coefficients across the wage distribution. As argued by Melly (2005), in the classic Blinder-Oaxaca (B-O) decomposition procedure, the exact split of the average wage gap between two groups is due to the assumption that the mean wage conditional on the average values of the regressors is equal to the unconditional mean wage. In other words, if one chooses to frame the QR with the B-O methodology, he/she will elicit biased results. For this reason, we chose to apply a procedure to single out the two above mentioned components from the decomposed differences at given quantiles of the unconditional distribution. Firstly, the conditional distribution is estimated through the Q; secondly it is integrated over the range of covariates.

Representing with \(\hat{\beta } = \left( {\hat{\beta }\left( {\theta_{1} } \right),....\hat{\beta }\left( {\theta_{j} } \right),....\hat{\beta }\left( {\theta_{J} } \right)} \right)\) the vector of quantile regression parameters estimated at J different quantiles \(0 < \theta_{j} < 1\) with j = 1,……..J and integrating over all of the quantiles and observations, an estimator of the τth unconditional quantile of the (log monthly) wage is given by:

$$q\left( {\tau ,x,\beta } \right) = \inf \left\{ {q:\frac{1}{N}\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{N} {\sum\limits_{j = 1}^{J} {\left( {\theta_{j} - \theta_{j - 1} } \right)1\left( {x_{i} \hat{\beta }\left( {\theta_{j} } \right) \le q} \right) \ge \tau } } } \right\}$$
(14)

where 1(.) is the indicator function. Thus, the counterfactual distribution can be estimated by replacing either the computed parameters of the distribution of characteristics for routine or non- routine workers. The difference at each quantile of the unconditional distribution can be decomposed into the two above mentioned components as follows:

$$q\left( {\theta ,x^{n} ,\beta^{n} } \right) - q\left( {\theta ,x^{r} ,\beta^{r} } \right) = \left[ {q\left( {\theta ,x^{n} ,\beta^{n} } \right) - q\left( {\theta ,x^{n} ,\beta^{r} } \right)} \right] + \left[ {q\left( {\theta ,x^{n} ,\beta^{r} } \right) - \left( {\theta ,x^{r} ,\beta^{r} } \right)} \right]$$
(15)

The right hand term in the first brackets constitutes the difference in rewards that the two groups of workers receive for their labor market characteristics (i.e. the counterfactual distribution), while that in the second brackets is the effect of differences in labor market characteristics between routine and non-routine workers. This is a semi-parametric-method because the QR framework does not need any distributional assumption, while at the same time allows the same covariates to have an influence all over the conditional distribution.

To estimate the standard errors and confidence intervals, the bootstrap method can be used to replicate the above procedure. In this study 200 replications were performed.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vannutelli, S., Scicchitano, S. & Biagetti, M. Routine-biased technological change and wage inequality: do workers’ perceptions matter?. Eurasian Bus Rev 12, 409–450 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-022-00222-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-022-00222-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation