Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Which firms survive in a crisis? Investigating Gibrat’s Law in Greece 2001–2014

  • Published:
Journal of Industrial and Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper employs a panel dataset of more than 40,000 Greek firms over the period 2001–2014 to examine the size-related patterns of survival and turnover growth before and after the financial and debt crisis that hit Greece in 2010. Our findings suggest that larger-size firms were, in general, more likely to survive in the market than smaller size ones and this relative advantage only grew further during the crisis. However, the rate of growth in turnover for the surviving firms is negatively associated with their size, thus refuting Gibrat’s Law in Greece.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 2

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 3

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 4

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 5

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 6

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 7

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 8

Source: Hellastat database

Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other legal types (including local branches) cover less than ten percent of our original sample and are, therefore, left out from the present analysis.

  2. We exclude cases (i.e. specific firm-years) that violate at least one of the following conditions: (a) total assets ≥ current assets > 0, (b) total assets ≥ equity, (c) turnover > 0, (d) age > 0, where age = current year − year of establishment + 1. We do not filter-out firm-years with negative equity records, as they may signal cases where firms face insolvency or big debt issues, but still manage to survive and publish regular reports. Firms with reporting discontinuities were excluded, thus cutting the sample by 10% to 18% of the initial size.

  3. Such information is available online from 2011 onwards via the Hellenic Statistical Authority's website. Source: Data are from www.statistics.gr.

  4. For example, the rapid increase in the number of firms in 2002 appears in UFS and also in FS.

  5. The classification in the Greek statistical system is STAKOD-03.

  6. The three terciles are calculated from the filtered sample (FS) using all firm-year observations, not just those of each specific year. This is the reason that they remain constant over subsequent years. Every year, the population of each size category sums up to the total number of firms, as shown in Table 1 (for the filtered sample, FS) and Fig. 6. The different number of firms in each size class is due to the combined impact of (i) more frequent exits of relatively smaller firms and (ii) upward or downward shifts in the size of firms remaining in the market.

  7. A zero or statistically insignificant coefficient on the size in the typical Gibrat's equation specification would imply that turnover is not related to growth. Assuming that no firms enter or exit the market, the above finding suggests that the number of small-sized firms becoming medium-sized equals the number of medium-sized ones growing larger, (ΔNS and ΔNM respectively, with Δ denoting first-difference). Hence, the number of large firms increases, while that of medium-sized firms remains constant as ΔNM = ΔNS, and, finally, the number of small firms decreases. At first glance, this is not in line with the evidence shown in Fig. 3a, because firms are further affected by the number of firms’ entering and exiting the market as well as the levels of size-terciles, computed on total firm-year observations.

  8. In 2012, tourist arrivals fell short from expected due to the political uncertainty produced by two successive general elections in May and June amid speculation of an eventual exit from the Eurozone.

  9. A surprisingly high outlier in 2002 for the construction sector is explained by the response of existing firms to new legislation on public projects companies. Adjusting to the new eligibility criteria envisaged by Law 2940/2001, about half of them merged in 2002. Reported in daily Kathimerini (4/2/2003). https://www.kathimerini.gr/141902/article/oikonomia/epixeirhseis/alla3e-shmantika-to-topio-ston-xwro-twn-ergolhptikwn

  10. Lacking information on current liabilities, we cannot construct a direct liquidity measure. Our analysis may only indirectly condition on liquidity via the combined effect of other indicators, such as leverage and/or fixed investment.

  11. Values of the leverage variable above one occur because of negative equity values in our dataset. These stem probably from significant losses reported in the income statements, which enter the balance sheets. We do not rule out such cases, provided that negative equity is not too substantial in magnitude compared with the rest of the sample. An extreme value analysis indicated that values higher than three rarely occur in the sample, so we considered them as misprints and treated as missing.

  12. For most sectors, the correlation coefficient is not too significant as the firm's size is in logarithms and market-size in percentage terms.

  13. In “Appendix”, we report results from other estimation set-ups that alternatively allow for serial correlation in the disturbance term, size-related heteroscedasticity and alternative probability link functions, such as the complementary double logarithmic function. We also estimated other semi-parametric and fully parametric survival models such as the Cox proportional hazard model (semi-parametric) and the exponential survival model (fully parametric). These results are qualitatively similar to the ones reported here (Table 6).

  14. Briefly stated, the correction via the inclusion of IMR in (4) works as follows: if u was subject to selection bias, Wooldridge (2002) shows (under normality and suitable assumptions), that \(\left({u}_{i,t+1}|{{\Omega}}_{t}, {{s}_{i}^{(t+1)}}=1\right)= \gamma {{IMR}_{i}^{(t+1)}}\), where γ stands for a constant parameter. The method, therefore, adds an otherwise omitted (but relevant) variable in the model, \({IMR}_{i}^{\left(t+1\right)}\), rendering the disturbance term u uncorrelated with the explanatory variables included in the model.

  15. The choice of a maximum number of lags excludes weak instruments from the estimation. Unreported partial autocorrelation estimates die out for most of the variables used after three to four lags, rendering further lags weak in instrumenting current variables. A possible reason for this may be that given the specific period covered in our sample, lags higher than five correspond to the pre-crisis levels of the variables, which exhibit weaker correlation with the post-crisis ones.

  16. Since the estimate of the lagged size is already statistically significant, it is unnecessary to employ alternative GMM methods (such as system-GMM) to increase the precision of the estimates, at a possible cost of increasing estimation bias.

  17. Using more instruments increases precision (efficiency) but may introduce biased estimates and vice versa.

References

  • Agarwal, R. (1998). Small firm survival and technological activity. Small Business Economics, 11, 215–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal, R., & Audretsch, D. B. (2001). Does entry size matter? The impact of the life cycle and technology of firms survival. Journal of Industrial Economics, 49, 21–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1995a). Firm profitability, growth, and innovation. Review of Industrial Organization, 10, 179–588.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1995b). Innovation, growth and survival. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 441–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Klomp, L., Santarelli, E., & Thurik, A. R. (2004). Gibrat's law: Are the services different? Review of Industrial Organization, 24, 301–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axtell, R. L. (2001). Zipf distribution of US firm sizes. Science, 293, 1818–1820.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balthrop, A. T. (2020). Gibrat's law in the trucking industry. Empirical Economics. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01851-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss, C. I. (1935). The calculation of the dosage-mortality curve. Annals of Applied Biology, 22, 134–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeri, T., & Bellmann, L. (1995). Post-entry behaviour and the cycle: Evidence from Germany. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 483–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S., Hoeffler, A., & Temple, J. 2001. GMM estimation of empirical growth models. Economics Papers 2001-W21, Economics Group, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.

  • Bond, S.R., Nauges, C., & Windmeijer, F. 2005. Unit roots: Identification and testing in micro panels. CEMMAP Working Paper.

  • Box, M. (2008). The death of firms: exploring the effects of environment and birth cohort on firm survival in Sweden. Small Business Economics, 31, 379–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L., & Matta, J. (2003). On the evolution of the firm size distribution: Facts and theory. American Economic Review, 93, 1075–1090.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canarella, G., & Miller, S. M. (2018). The determinants of growth in the US information and communication technology (ICT) industry: A firm-level analysis. Economic Modelling, 70, 259–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Capasso, M., & Cefis, E. (2012). Firm size and growth rate variance: The effects of data truncation. Review of Industrial Organizaion, 41, 193–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesher, A. (1979). Testing the law of proportionate effect. Journal of Industrial Economics, 27(4), 403–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christodoulakis, N. (2016). Greek crisis in perspective: Origins, effects and ways-out. In G. Jones (Ed.), Banking crises: Perspectives from the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (pp. 119–143). Hampshire: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. 2019. Annual report on European SME 2018/2019.

  • Cox, D. R. (1972). Regression models and life tables. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 34, 187–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daunfeldt, S.-O., & Elert, N. (2013). When is Gibrat's law a law? Small Business Economics, 41, 133–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dinlersoz, E., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Hyatt, H., & Penciakova, V. 2019. Leverage of the life cycle and implications for firm growth and shock responsiveness. NBER Working Paper 25226.

  • Distante, R., Petrella, I., & Santoro, E. (2018). Gibrat’s law and quantile regressions: An application to firm growth. Economics Letters, 164, 5–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donati, C. (2015). Firm growth and liquidity constraints: evidence from the manufacturing and service sectors in Italy. Applied Economics, 48(20), 1881–1892.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., & Nelson, R. (2010). Technical change and industrial dynamcis as evolutionary processes. In B. A. Hall & N. Rosenberg (Eds.), Handbook of economics and innovation (pp. 52–126). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, P., & Hughes, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42(2), 115–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Union Legislation. 2003. Commission Recommendation of 6 May 2003 concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises (2003/361/EC).

  • Evans, D. S. (1987). The relationship between firm growth, size, and age: Estimates for 100 manufacturing industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 567–581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fort, T. C., Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S., & Miranda, J. (2013). How firms respond to business cycles: The role of firm age and firm size. IMF Economic Review, 61, 520–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fotopoulos, G., & Giotopoulos, I. (2010). Gibrat's law and persistence of growth in Greek manufacturing. Small Business Economics, 35, 195–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fotopoulos, G., & Louri, H. (2000a). Determinants of hazard confronting new entry: Does financial structure matter? Review of Industrial Organization, 17, 285–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fotopoulos, G., & Louri, H. (2000b). Location and survival of new entry. Small Business Economics, 14, 311–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. 1999. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. CEPR Discussion Papers.

  • Geroski, P. (2005). Understanding the implications of empirical work on corporate growth rates. Managerial and Decision Economics, 26(2), 129–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibrat, R. (1931). Les inegalites economiques. Paris: Librairie du Recueil Sirey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giotopoulos, I., & Fotopoulos, G. (2010). Intra-industry growth dynamics in the Greek services sector: Firm-level estimates for ICT-producing, ICT-using and non-ICT industries. Review of Industrial Organization, 36, 59–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorg, H., & Spaliara, M. E. (2014). Financial health, exports and firm survival: Evidence from UK and French firms. Economica, 81, 419–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2012). Econometric analysis. Harlow: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guarilia, A., Spaliara, M. E., & Tsoukas, S. (2016). To what extent does the interest burden affect firm survival? Evidence from a panel of UK firms during the recent financial crisis. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 78, 576–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S., & Miranda, J. (2013). Who creates jobs? Small versus large versus young. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 347–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayakawa, K. (2009). First difference or forward orthogonal deviation-which transformation should be used in dynamic panel data models?: A simulation study. Economics Bulletin, 29, 2008–2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higson, C., Holly, S., Katturman, P., & Platis, S. (2004). The business cycle, macroeconomic shocks and the cross-section: The growth of UK quoted companies. Economica, 71, 299–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutchinson, J., Konings, J., & Walsh, P. P. (2010). The firm size distribution and inter-industry diversification. Review of Industrial Organization, 37, 65–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kontolaimou, A., Giotopoulos, I., & Mpalikou, H. (2017). Access to finance and firm growth of Greek SMEs before and during the economic crisis. Athens: Center of Planning and Economic Research, Greek Economic Outlook.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kudlyak, M., & Sanchez, J.M.. 2016. Revisiting the behavior of large and small firms during the 2008 financial crisis. Working Paper, Federeal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

  • Lopez-Zapata, E., Garcia-Muina, F. E., & Garcia-Moreno, S. M. (2019). Analysing the relationship between diversification strategy and firm performance: The role of the economic cycle. Cuadernos de Gestión (Instituto de Economía Aplicada a la Empresa (IEAE)), 19(2), 15–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2009). Defending Gibrat’s Law as a long-run regularity. Small Business Economics, 32, 31–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Louri, H., & Fotopoulos, G. 2001. Determinants of firm growth: An integrated empirical assessment. AUEB Working Paper.

  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat's law, innovation and the growth of firms. The American Economic Review, 57, 1023–1051.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzucato, M. (2000). Firm size, innovation and market structure: The evolution of industry concentration and instability. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meisenzahl, R. R. (2016). Can financing constraints explain the evolution of the firm size distribution? Review of Industrial Organization, 48, 123–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–1426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oke, B. O. (2018). Testing the Gibrat's law: A dynamic panel analysis of firm size and firm growth Nexus in Nigeria. Nigerian Journal of Mangement Studies, 18(2), 77–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira, B., & Fortunato, A. (2006). Testing the Gibrat's Law: An empirical evidence from a panel of Portuguese manufacturing firms. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 13(1), 65–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peric, M., & Vitezic, V. (2016). Impact of global economic crisis on firm growth. Small Business Economics, 46, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters, B., Dachs, B., Duenser, M., Hud, M., Koehler, C., & Rammer, C. 2014. Firm growth, innovation and the business cycle. Background Report for the 2014 Competitiveness Report, Austrian Institute of Technology.

  • Quah, D. (1993). Empirical cross-section dynamics in economic growth. European Economic Review, 37(2–3), 426–434.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ribeiro, E. P. (2007). The dynamics of firm size distribution. Brazilian Review of Econometrics, 27, 199–223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rincor-Aznar, A., Robinson, C., & Loveridge, P. (2009). Sectoral growth drivers and competitiveness in the European Union. Background Studies to the Competitiveness Report, 2008, 113–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. The Stata Journal, 9, 86–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruiz-Fuensanda, M. J., & Bellandi, M. (2019). Entrepreneurship dynamics and economic cycles: An analysis for local systems and industrial districts. European Planning Studies, 27, 1727–1747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santarelli, E., Klomp, L., & Thurik, A. R. (2006). Gibrat's Law: An overview of the empirical literature. In E. Santarelli (Ed.), Entrepreneurship, growth, and innovation: the dynamics of firms and industries (pp. 41–73). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Semikyna, A., & Wooldridge, J. (2013). Estimation of dynamic panel data models with sample selection. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 28, 47–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spescha, A., & Woerter, M. (2018). Innovation and firm growth over the business cycle. Industry and Innovation, 26(3), 321–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teruel-Carrizosa, M. 2006. Firm growth, persistence and multiplicity of equilibria: an analysis of spanish manufacturing and service industries. PhD Thesis, Universitat Rovira i Virgili.

  • Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (2010). Gibrat's Law and the learning process. Small Business Economics, 34, 355–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vlachvei, A., & Notta, O. 2008. Firm growth, size and age in greek firms. In Proceedings of international conference on applied economics, pp. 915–21.

  • Wawro, G. (2002). Estimating dynamic panel data in political science. Political Analysis, 10(1), 25–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to two anonymous referees for useful suggestions on an earlier draft. Comments and discussions by seminar participants at the AUEB, the Bank of Industrial Development in Greece (ETVA), and the HO in London are thankfully acknowledged. The research was made possible only after Kantor SA, Athens, made available the dataset on Greek enterprises and provided us with helpful insights. None of the organizations bears responsibility for the views expressed in the paper or the way the data are presented.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christos Axioglou.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: alternative estimations of survival probability models

Appendix: alternative estimations of survival probability models

Ιn this section we investigate how deviations from our panel data Probit estimation setup may affect robustness of our results. As we have used a ‘population averaged’ Maximum Likelihood estimator, our results are robust to unobserved heterogeneity across firms (Wooldridge 2002, Ch.15, pp. 486). We have also allowed for an unstructured within group correlation; this makes our results robust to possible presence of serial correlation. Compared to the simple Pooled Probit estimates with robust standard errors, shown in Table

Table 11 Pooled probit estimation of survival effects

11 in this Appendix, our coefficient estimates are quite similar, with few differences found to be larger than 5% in absolute value (the standard errors differ significantly, nevertheless). More specifically, for Manufacturing and Recreation firms the coefficient estimates of all effects (except those of year dummy variables) show negligible differences. The same holds for the (point) estimates of the effects of size, leverage, profitability and market share across all sectors. This implies that, at least for these cases, unobserved heterogeneity and/or serial correlation do not bias our results.

We also allowed for a specific form of heteroscedasticity that depends on firm size. This is equivalent to a Probit model with transformed data so that each explanatory variable is divided by the square root of firm size. Results are shown in Table

Table 12 Heteroscedastic Pooled Probit estimation of survival effects

12 in this Appendix and show substantial differences, regarding the magnitude of the estimated effects and their standard errors. The estimates for the Trade sector are affected the most, indicating that this sector is most sensitive to this particular data transformation, perhaps because it consists of relatively larger firms than the other sectors (see Fig. 9). Nevertheless, the estimated effects remain roughly similar in direction to our previous results.

As another robustness check we experimented on a different link function and estimated a complementary log–log model as in Gorg and Spaliara (2014) and Guarilia et al. (2016). According to this setup, the link function Φ(.) is specified as 1 − exp[− exp(.)], which is a non-symmetric function in the interval [0, 1] and may better therefore characterize more extreme events. The Population Averaged Maximum Likelihood estimates under unspecified within group correlation is shown in Table

Table 13 Complementary log–log model estimation of survival effects

13 in this Appendix. Similar to our previous results, these are robust to unobserved heterogeneity and serial correlation. As shown in Table 13, the results are quite similar to our initial Probit estimates. Positive size effects after 2008 are found to be statistically significant in more sectors, leaving only Recreation and TLC sectors with statistical insignificant size effects after the beginning of the crisis.

The duration of firms’ survival up to their exit (or end of the sample) is incorporated in the model via inclusion of firms’ age in the set of explanatory variables. Nevertheless, the exact period each firm enters the sample may convey important information for firm survival and is not taken explicitly into account in the current setup. To account for this we employ two typical survival models, which are closely related in our current discrete time setup. The first is the Cox (1972) proportional hazard model applied in discrete time as in Box (2008). This is a frequently used semi-parametric approach that estimates the hazard function \(h\left(t\right)={h}_{0}(t)\mathrm{exp}(.)\), where t is survival time and the arguments (.) in the exponential function coincide with those in the Probit function Φ(.) in (1). \({h}_{0}(t)\) is a baseline hazard function, which remains unspecified. Estimation results are shown in Table

Table 14 Cox proportional hazard model estimation of survival effects

14 in this Appendix; the direction of the effects remains roughly similar to our Probit estimation. Notice that the model estimates firm hazard (not survival) rates and therefore the effects have the opposite signs from those in the Probit model.

The second survival model is a fully parametric one and assumes that the previous baseline hazard function \({h}_{0}(t)\) is exponential. We also allow for random effects in order to capture unobserved firm specific heterogeneity. Results are shown in Table

Table 15 Exponential proportional hazard model estimation

15 in this Appendix and are similar to the Cox proportional hazard model, remaining therefore consistent with our initial Probit model estimates.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Axioglou, C., Christodoulakis, N. Which firms survive in a crisis? Investigating Gibrat’s Law in Greece 2001–2014. J. Ind. Bus. Econ. 48, 159–217 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-020-00176-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-020-00176-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation