1 Introduction

Marx and Engels seemed to be vindicated by the dynamics of the over-the-counter (OTC) derivativesFootnote 1 market during the Global Financial Crisis. In their Manifesto, they compared capitalism to ‘the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the netherworld whom he has called up by his spells’.Footnote 2 Indeed, the opaque network of credit derivatives which concentrated systemic credit risk into a few interconnected institutions was seen by policymakers as one of the main propellants of the Global Financial Crisis.Footnote 3 Still, the leaders of the Group of Twenty (G20) did not despond. In fact, in 2009 they pledged to introduce a clearing obligation for standardised OTC derivatives in order to contain credit risk within Central Counterparties (CCPs).Footnote 4 Since then, the volume of derivatives transactions cleared by CCPs has significantly increased worldwide.Footnote 5 However, the growing importance of these financial market infrastructuresFootnote 6 (FMIs) has meant that they have become a source of systemic risk themselves.Footnote 7 CCPs are now seen as too big to fail.Footnote 8 Accordingly, there is an ongoing effort to develop an effective CCP recovery and resolution regime to avoid enormous bailouts.Footnote 9 Furthermore, the Brexit saga has reignited the debate over third-country CCP regimes and locations.Footnote 10

Against this backdrop, this article focuses on a specific topic: the arrangements for the supervision of European Union-based CCPs (EU-CCPs). In particular, this paper will conduct a legal-institutional analysis of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation,Footnote 11 which was approved after two years of intense negotiations. This reform seeks to improve the supervisory arrangements contained in the 2012 European Market Infrastructure RegulationFootnote 12 (2012 EMIR). To this end, in 2017 the Commission proposed to centralise certain supervisory tasks in a new CCP Executive Session within the Board of Supervisors of the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA).Footnote 13 However, co-legislators have significantly watered down such a proposal by the Commission: instead of the decision-making CCP Executive Session, a merely internal CCP Supervisory Committee is going to be established within ESMA to foster supervisory convergence and cooperation between the increasing number of authorities involved in EU-CCP oversight. It is the intention of co-legislators that the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would secure swift decision-making, clarify areas of competences between authorities, and lead to a coherent and consistent supervisory approach to CCP supervision across the EU.

This article will argue that the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would not achieve such praiseworthy objectives. The development of a truly European approach to CCP supervision would be undermined by the continuing absence of loss mutualisation between Member States. Moreover, the new supervisory architecture would add another layer of complexity and confusion to the previous framework. If an agreement on loss mutualisation could be reached, this paper suggests instead to centralise EU-CCP supervision in two EU bodies along objective lines, at least in the euro area. While EU-CCP prudential supervision should be conferred upon the European Central Bank (ECB) within the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM), ESMA’s Board of Supervisors should be responsible for EU-CCP conduct of business supervision. As opposed to the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation (as well as to the initial proposal of the Commission), this framework would improve EU-CCP supervision and fit in with the current EU supervisory architecture at once.

This paper belongs to the legal-institutional literature which examines the governance of EU financial supervision after the crisis-era reforms.Footnote 14 Nevertheless, the analysis draws heavily upon the related political economy literature to explain the dynamics behind EU institutional reforms.Footnote 15 Moreover, this article relies on the legal and economic literature on CCPs to explain their inner workings and risks.Footnote 16

This paper is organised as follows: after this brief introduction, Sect. 2 considers how the presence or the absence of loss mutualisation between Member States has shaped the current EU supervisory architecture. Section 3 examines how fiscal considerations also informed the peculiar supervisory arrangements of the 2012 EMIR regime. Section 4 presents the shortcomings of such arrangements, and their reform as proposed by the Commission and then approved by co-legislators. Section 5 highlights three weaknesses of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation and advocates instead a centralised and objective-based framework for EU-CCP supervision. Section 6 concludes.

2 Fiscal Responsibility and Supervision

2.1 Setting the Scene

The optimal degree of centralisation for EU financial supervision has been at the centre of a long debate. On the one hand, it has been argued that decentralising supervision at Member State level would support regulatory innovation and local expertise as well as avoid the fiscal, political, legal, and accountability sensitivities associated with centralisation.Footnote 17 On the other hand, pan-EU supervisory authorities would bring the benefits of economies of scale, reduce regulatory capture and home biases.Footnote 18

Presently, two different types of financial supervisory arrangements coexist at the EU level.Footnote 19 The first one is the largely decentralised and sector-based European System of Financial Supervision (ESFS) recommended by the de Larosière Group.Footnote 20 This is a pan-EU network which comprisesFootnote 21: national competent authorities (NCAs), the European Systemic Risk BoardFootnote 22 (ESRB), three sectoral European Supervisory AuthoritiesFootnote 23 (ESAs) and their Joint Committee. The ESFS is the dominant model in EU financial markets supervision.Footnote 24 Even though the sectoral ESA—ESMA—is the pan-EU supervisor of trade repositoriesFootnote 25 and credit rating agencies,Footnote 26 the ‘home country control’ principle reigns supreme for the rest of financial markets supervision: NCAs of the Member State where intermediaries have obtained their respective authorisation remain primarily responsible for their day-to-day supervision.Footnote 27 However, ESMA has incisive quasi-regulatory and supervisory powers to foster supervisory convergence and cooperation between NCAs.Footnote 28

In principle, the decentralised ESFS also operates in the EU banking sector.Footnote 29 However, euro area countries have agreed to integrate further their banking supervisory arrangements by adopting a second framework. In particular, they have centralised banking prudential supervisionFootnote 30 in the ECB within the SSM.Footnote 31 Nevertheless, conduct of business supervision remains a national competence.Footnote 32

The coexistence of these divergent supervisory arrangements has its origins in fiscal concerns.

2.2 From Maastricht to the SSM

The in-depth reason for this divergence is the asymmetry of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) agreed in Maastricht.Footnote 33 A perfect Monetary Union governed by an independent central bank was established.Footnote 34 However, EMU was explicitly designed to avoid fiscal transfers between Member States.Footnote 35 Accordingly, monetary financing and sovereign bailouts were (and still are) prohibited.Footnote 36 However, the Economic Union lacked credible mechanisms to deal with asymmetric shocks and inconsistent national economic policies.Footnote 37 The dangers of this system were laid bare during the sovereign debt crisis. When the crisis hit, the euro area did not have a set of financing options to rapidly sever the sovereign debt-bank ‘vicious circle’:Footnote 38 the deterioration of public finances of certain euro area countries negatively affected the balance sheets of their banks, and vice versa.Footnote 39 In turn, this self-propelled circle severely hindered the monetary policy of the Eurosystem.Footnote 40 As a response, the Eurosystem had to employ unconventional monetary measuresFootnote 41 to save the Single Currency, thereby becoming the de facto lender of last resort of the euro area.Footnote 42 Meanwhile, unprepared governments had to arrange temporary and legally contentious rescue packages.Footnote 43 Member States finally concluded an international treaty establishing a permanent ‘fiscal backstop’ to mutualise losses: the European Stability MechanismFootnote 44 (ESM). Immediately after being established, the ESM lent € 39.5 billion to Spain to recapitalise its banking system.Footnote 45

Hence, the sovereign debt-bank circle was temporarily severed through significant fiscal transfers and the adoption (and the announcementFootnote 46) of unconventional monetary measures. However, these extraordinary responses shattered the EMU’s macroeconomic fiscal and monetary foundations.Footnote 47 Therefore, it was clear that the EMU needed long-term reforms.Footnote 48 One of these has been the centralisation of banking prudential supervision in the ECB within the SSM.Footnote 49 The establishment of the SSM was considered as the sine qua non for future fiscal transfers via the ESM by Member States such as Germany, the Netherlands, and Finland.Footnote 50 From the perspective of those countries, supervisory centralisation was needed because the decentralised model of the ESFS was seen as an insufficient guarantee against the moral hazard of recipient Member States.Footnote 51

2.3 Between Meroni and NCAs: ESMA

EU financial markets supervision did not experience a level of centralisation similar to the SSM. From a purely legal perspective, the ascent of a single European financial markets supervisor has been blocked by constitutional limitations. The establishment of the SSM could rely on a ready-made EU institution and on TFEU Article 127(6).Footnote 52 This provision empowers the Council to confer specific prudential supervisory powers over credit and financial institutions (apart from insurance undertakings) upon the ECB. In the financial markets, the only feasible solution was to create a new EU agency—ESMA—on the basis of TFEU Article 114.Footnote 53 This provision enables co-legislators to take measures to foster the integration of the Internal Market, including by establishing agencies.Footnote 54

However, such ‘agentification’ entails the restrictions of the Meroni case law,Footnote 55 which limits the extent to which executive powers can be delegated to EU agencies.Footnote 56 In one of its earliest rulings, the Court of Justice was asked to assess whether the High Authority of the European Coal and Steel Community could legally delegate some of its treaty-based powers to manage the ferrous-scrap market to two ‘Brussels agencies’ (formally two cooperative companies incorporated under Belgian law). The powers of such agencies were contested by Meroni—a steel company required to make contributions to the ferrous-scrap equalisation mechanism—because, inter alia, they had not been envisaged by the institutional framework of the Treaty of Paris. The Court stated that the allocation of powers enshrined in the Treaty had to be considered a fundamental guarantee for the undertakings dealing with the then Community, which had been founded on a constitutional ‘balance of powers’. Accordingly, treaty-based bodies cannot delegate their executive powers (provided that they have them in the first place) unless they can be ‘subject to strict review in light of objective criteria determined by the delegating authority’.Footnote 57 Consequently, Meroni prohibits the delegation of discretionary powers which ‘make possible the execution of actual economic policy’.Footnote 58 While doubts have been expressed over the scope—and the very meaning—of such a dated ruling under contemporary legislation, Meroni has exercised a decisive influence over EU agency-design ever since.Footnote 59

Nevertheless, the de Larosière Group expressly recommended that ESAs should have been empowered to challenge national supervisory decisions.Footnote 60 Therefore, ESMA has been endowed with potentially discretionary powers over NCAs and financial market participants: for example, ESMA can overrule NCAs should a breach of EU law occur, should the Council determine the existence of an emergency situation, or when NCAs irreconcilably disagree on the application of EU law.Footnote 61 However, these powers are in tension with the tight constraints of Meroni.Footnote 62 To solve this conundrum, ESMA has been equipped with exceptional governance arrangements.Footnote 63 While in a typical EU agency the technocratic component is separated from the oversight and representative internal bodies,Footnote 64 ESMA’s governance arrangements assign a decisive role to NCAs in ESMA’s governing body, the Board of Supervisors.Footnote 65 Since they are the only voting members of the Board of Supervisors, NCAs control and supervise ESMA’s decision-making process. As a consequence, ESMA’s effectiveness and legitimacy are built upon NCAs’ technical capacity.Footnote 66

Nonetheless, ESMA’s supervisory powers have still had to be subject to highly-detailed conditions and procedures to respect the ‘Meroni doctrine’.Footnote 67 As ESMA has lamented,Footnote 68 these constraints undermine the effectiveness of its action.Footnote 69 Moreover, Meroni renders ESMA’s powers prone to legal challenges.Footnote 70 For example, the United Kingdom asked the Court of Justice of the EU to assess whether ESMA’s short selling intervention powers were compatible, inter alia, with Meroni case law.Footnote 71 In particular, if NCAs fail to act adequately against extreme cross-border threats to the functioning and the integrity of EU financial markets, the financial stability of the Union, or a part thereof, the 2012 Short Selling Regulation empowers ESMA to restrict, prohibit, and order to disclose or notify short positions instead of NCAs.Footnote 72 Before acting, ESMA should consult with the ESRB and other relevant authoritiesFootnote 73 as well as duly take into account whether its intervention addresses the threat, negatively affects the efficiency of the markets, and creates the risk of regulatory arbitrage.Footnote 74 The reasoned decision to impose or renew such measures should be notified to NCAs with at least one day’s notice (if possible)Footnote 75 and published on ESMA’s website.Footnote 76 ESMA should review the decision at least every 3 months. If measures are not renewed, they expire automatically.Footnote 77 Nonetheless, the United Kingdom argued that such short selling intervention powers could allow ESMA to take discretionary decisions with relevant economic and financial implications against the principles of the ‘Meroni doctrine’. The Court disagreed: given the procedural and substantive constraints attached to such temporary powers,Footnote 78 the residual margins of discretion left to ESMA have been ‘precisely delineated and amenable to judicial review in light of the objectives established by the delegating authority’Footnote 79 in compliance with the ‘Meroni doctrine’.

2.4 Piercing the Veil of Meroni

While the Court of Justice of the EU ultimately upheld the legality of ESMA’s powers, it is worth noting that the United Kingdom itself started to question the short selling intervention powers on the basis of Meroni only at a late stage of the negotiations.Footnote 80 This fact reveals the in-depth reason why ESMA was not designed to be the single supervisor of EU financial markets: the concerns of many Member States over the split between supervisory competences and fiscal responsibility.Footnote 81 These concerns were often hidden behind Meroni.Footnote 82 During ESA negotiations, loss mutualisation was opposed by a wide and diverse coalition led by the United Kingdom.Footnote 83 This coalition included countries such as France, Germany, Ireland, and Luxembourg which years later consented (if not demanded) to establish the SSM.Footnote 84 In this alliance there were also many central and eastern European States, which were firmly against any form of supervisory centralisation.Footnote 85

Accordingly, ESMA’s supervisory powers are both de jure and de facto limited when the fiscal interests of Member States come into play: a ‘fiscal safeguard’ limits ESMA’s powers to act in emergency situations and to conclude binding mediations between NCAs.Footnote 86 Moreover, sovereign debt and sovereign credit default swapsFootnote 87 (CDSs) are not covered by ESMA’s short selling intervention powers.Footnote 88 Similarly, ESMA’s product intervention powers to restrict or prohibit financial activities, practices, financial instruments, and entering derivatives positionsFootnote 89 entail no significant fiscal risk.Footnote 90 Finally, the regulatees subject to ESMA’s direct supervision—credit rating agencies and trade repositories—pose limited fiscal risk.Footnote 91

Therefore, the current landscape of EU financial supervision has been heavily influenced by the presence or absence of loss mutualisation.Footnote 92 The establishment of the ESM ultimately led to the centralised SSM and its single ‘supervisory manual’.Footnote 93 On the other hand, given the continuing absence of loss mutualisation between Member States, NCAs have remained responsible for financial markets supervision within the decentralised ESFS. Against this backdrop, the supervisory arrangements of the 2012 EMIR regime are somewhat exceptional. Central clearing poses unique risks to fiscal and monetary stability. Therefore, the decentralised model of the ESFS has had to be adapted.

3 Supervising Central Clearing: The 2012 EMIR Regime

3.1 CCPs as a Solution: Mutualisation of Credit Risk

The Global Financial Crisis revealed that systemically important financial institutions were heavily exposed to each other through an opaque network of OTC derivatives contracts, notably CDSs.Footnote 94 The concentration of systemic credit risk in a limited number of interlinked institutions had dramatic consequences such as the bailout of AIG.Footnote 95 The failure of one of the major players of the CDS market would have jeopardised the risk management of all its counterparties with unforeseeable knock-on effects.Footnote 96 On the other hand, the $9 trillion OTC derivatives portfolio of Lehman Brothers was smoothly liquidated by the CCP LCH.Clearnet.Footnote 97

Indeed, CCPs are FMIs whose main function is to centralise the management of the credit risk of their clients,Footnote 98 the clearing members.Footnote 99 Bilateral contracts between clearing members are novatedFootnote 100 in favour of the CCP, which thus becomes ‘the buyer to every seller and the seller to every buyer’.Footnote 101 Consequently, CCPs stand at the centre of the cleared transactions between their clearing members. This makes multilateral netting possible,Footnote 102 which reduces credit and operational risk.Footnote 103 Moreover, the concentration of trade in CCPs imposes trade standardisation, thereby enhancing market liquidity and transparency.Footnote 104 Crucially, if a member has defaulted, the CCP would be able to guarantee the performance of open contracts for the benefit of the other clearing members so as to prevent cascades of defaults.Footnote 105

However, this is possible only if CCPs do not themselves fail by effectively absorbing the shock of defaults of clearing members. Therefore, CCPs must have robust default management processes. These can be described as a set of legal devices,Footnote 106 which ultimately allocates uncovered losses among CCPs and clearing members via a mutually financed default fund.Footnote 107 In particular, CCPs do not ordinarily assume market risk because they run a ‘matched book’: following novation, a CCP’s position with a contract ‘seller’ is offset by an opposite position with a contract ‘buyer’, and vice versa.Footnote 108 However, if a member defaulted, a CCP would need to close out its now unmatched positions.Footnote 109 In order to return to a matched book, the CCP would firstly try to liquidate the defaulter’s portfolio through an auction between the other clearing members.Footnote 110 However, if this was not sufficient or possible,Footnote 111 losses would be allocated according to the ‘default waterfall’.Footnote 112 This is the pool of resources available to CCPs to progressively share losses with clearing members. The first step of the default waterfall is to gather the collateral and the contribution to the default fund of the defaulter.Footnote 113 To mitigate the moral hazard of the CCP’s shareholders, the second step is their ‘skin in the game’, i.e. part of the CCP’s own capital.Footnote 114 If the skin in the game is not enough, losses are mutualised among non-defaulting clearing members through their contribution to the default fund.Footnote 115 As an extrema ratio before its failure, CCPs might call additional resources from the remaining members or tear-up contracts.Footnote 116

The mutualisation of credit risk via CCPs seemed to be an appropriate response to the systemic dangers of the OTC derivatives market.Footnote 117 In 2009, the G20 made the pledge that all standardised OTC derivatives should have been cleared through CCPs by the end of 2012.Footnote 118 Since then, this commitment has progressively been implemented worldwide.Footnote 119 In the EU, this so-called clearing obligation was introduced by the 2012 EMIR.Footnote 120

3.2 CCPs as a Danger: Mutualisation of Systemic Risk

The introduction of the clearing obligation and its progressive enlargementFootnote 121 have had transformative effects on important segments of the EU OTC derivatives market. For example, only 25% of interest rate derivatives were centrally cleared in the EU before the 2012 EMIR entered into force.Footnote 122 This figure stood at 63% at the end of 2018.Footnote 123 Most of these contracts are cleared by EU-CCPs.Footnote 124

These data demonstrate the success of the reform. However, while the amount of contracts cleared has steadily risen, the number of EU-CCPs is stuck at thirteen.Footnote 125 Moreover, not all asset classes are cleared by all EU-CCPs: for example, just two EU-CCPs are authorised to clear credit derivatives such as CDSs.Footnote 126 Furthermore, EU-CCPs are increasingly interconnected with one another either directly via interoperability arrangementsFootnote 127 or indirectly via their clearing members.Footnote 128 In particular, only a limited number of systemically important institutions can meet the strict requirements to be a clearing member.Footnote 129 For example, the Commission noted that ‘24 globally systemically important banks (G-SIBs) are members of [the German-CCP] Eurex, BNP Paribas is a member of at least five EU CCPs’.Footnote 130

The fact that systemic credit risk is concentrated in a limited number of interlinked CCPs has become a source of concern for EU macro-prudential stability. Financial and liquidity distress experienced by one single EU-CCP could be transferred to others through interoperability arrangementsFootnote 131 and common clearing members. These could be asked to mutualise losses via the default waterfall, thereby deteriorating their financial position.Footnote 132 This would happen when they can ‘least afford them’ because the default waterfall’s exceptional solidity would be endangered only when a systemic crisis is already occurring.Footnote 133 Indeed, a ‘CCP-bank nexus’ could be triggered.Footnote 134 The outright failure of a CCP ‘would deprive market participants of certain basic functions, such as trade processing, thereby entailing the shutdown of entire markets’.Footnote 135 Moreover, disruptions of clearing services could hinder the ‘smooth functioning of euro area payment systems. This could lead to increased demand for central bank liquidity and possible challenges in implementing the Eurosystem’s single monetary policy. In addition, such disturbances can impair the functioning of financial market segments that are key to the transmission of monetary policy’.Footnote 136

Accordingly, there is a growing awareness that CCPs cannot fail.Footnote 137 Since a CCP resolution framework is still under development,Footnote 138 public funds would be employed to rescue failing CCPs.Footnote 139 In the past, governments and Central Banks already had to intervene to rescue CCPs. During the crash of 1987, the Federal Reserve had to provide exceptional liquidity support to the US-CCP CME to avoid its failure.Footnote 140 In the same year, the Hong Kong Government had to employ HKD 2 billion to try to avoid the failure of a Hong Kong CCP.Footnote 141 Today figures are even more appalling: in 2018 the total notional amount of interest rate derivatives cleared by LCH Group’s SwapClear surpassed USD 1 quadrillion.Footnote 142 However, the EU-CCP home Member State would not be the only one to bear the costs stemming from CCP bail-outs. Indeed, CCPs’ losses would be mutualised among clearing members via the default waterfall. In turn, their respective Member States would ‘need to provide these participants with financial support if they are faced with large payment obligations due to CCP losses’.Footnote 143

Unfortunately, CCP failures are not unheard of.Footnote 144 These FMIs face a wide range of risks,Footnote 145 notably credit and liquidity risks.Footnote 146 Indeed, CCP solvency can be threatened by defaults of relatively small clearing members.Footnote 147 As recently as 2018, an EU-CCP needed to be bailed-in by its members after the failure of an individual to meet its margin calls.Footnote 148

3.3 The Supervisory Architecture of the 2012 EMIR Regime

CCP failures date back to a time when CCPs were not so systematically important as today. When the clearing obligation was introduced, the EU decided to move away from the prior mostly self-regulatory regime.Footnote 149 EU-CCPs are now subject to a granular and ever-growing EU rulebook. The 2012 EMIR regime implements and expands the standards agreed in international forums.Footnote 150 In turn, EMIR’s prudential, organisational, and conduct of business requirementsFootnote 151 are specified by a vast set of administrative rulesFootnote 152 and ESMA’s soft law.Footnote 153

Nevertheless, EMIR has left fiscal responsibility for EU-CCPs at the national level.Footnote 154 Member States opposed the suggestion of the de Larosière Group to centralise EU-CCP supervisionFootnote 155 because of the above-mentioned concerns over the split between supervisory duties and fiscal responsibility.Footnote 156

However, the decentralised model of the ESFS has been adapted to take into account the systemic risk posed by CCPs.Footnote 157 Accordingly, EMIR has mandated collegial procedures for some important supervisory decisions: the granting and extension of authorisation, and the approval of interoperability arrangements.Footnote 158 In particular, an enhanced form of the college of supervisors must be established by the home NCAFootnote 159 within 30 days from the application for authorisation.Footnote 160 In addition to the chairing home of the NCA, colleges originally comprisedFootnote 161: ESMA; NCAs of the clearing members established in the three Member States with the largest contributions to the default fund; NCAs of the trading venues served by the EU-CCP; NCAs of other EU-CCPs with which interoperability arrangements have been established; NCAs of linked central securities depositories; the members of the ESCB responsible for the applicant and the interlinked EU-CCPs; and the central banks of issue (CBIs) of the most relevant Union currencies of the financial instruments cleared. The establishment and the functioning of the college are based on written agreements between its members.Footnote 162

Unlike other fields of EU financial markets supervision where the home country control principle reigns supreme,Footnote 163 the home NCA cannot unilaterally grant or refuse the authorisation (and its extension), but must wait for the college’s opinion.Footnote 164 To this end, the college must receive a report on the risks posed by the applicant from the home NCA.Footnote 165 Detailed voting thresholds are set to take into account the cross-border implications of the decision.Footnote 166 If the college’s opinion matches with the conclusion of the report, the decision of the home NCA is adopted.Footnote 167 However, if college members (excluding the authorities of the home State) jointly issue a negative opinion, the home NCA cannot grant the authorisation. The matter could only be referred to ESMA for binding mediation.Footnote 168 If only two-thirds of the members express a negative opinion, any authority concerned can ask ESMA to conclude binding mediation.Footnote 169 If the home NCA does not comply with these EMIR requirements (and more generally with EU law), ESMA is empowered to take direct action against NCAs and financial market participants.Footnote 170Mutatis mutandis, the same procedure applies for the approval of interoperability arrangements.Footnote 171

Once the CCP is authorised, college members must keep on exchanging information and cooperating closely, especially in emergency situations.Footnote 172 For example, any member can ask the home NCA to review whether an EU-CCP remains in compliance with authorisation requirements.Footnote 173 Similarly, the home NCA must take into account the reservations of the other college members before withdrawing the authorisation.Footnote 174 College members might also delegate tasks to others.Footnote 175 For example, one NCA delegated ESMA to oversee the compliance of its CCP with EMIR prudential requirements until the end of 2017.Footnote 176 Moreover, colleges must issue opinions on significant changes to CCP risk models, which must also be validated by ESMA.Footnote 177

Indeed, the 2012 EMIR regime had assigned a significant role to ESMA even before the recent reform was approved. ESMA must coordinate colleges and NCAs to build a single ‘supervisory culture and consistent supervisory practices’.Footnote 178 Accordingly, ESMA has been a (non-votingFootnote 179) member of all EMIR colleges, whose workings it must facilitate.Footnote 180 Moreover, ESMA has adopted a set of supervisory convergence measures, which include opinions on ECB’s role in collegesFootnote 181 and on common indicators for the exercise of certain NCAs’ powers.Footnote 182 Furthermore, EMIR requires ESMA to conduct pan-EU CCP stress tests and (at least annually) NCA peer reviews.Footnote 183

Nevertheless, EU-CCP supervision has mostly remained in the hands of home NCAs.Footnote 184 Moreover, the 2012 EMIR framework has not harmonised supervisory and enforcement powers: NCAs must only have supervisory and investigatory powers that are necessary for exercising their functions.Footnote 185 As ESMA’s peer reviews have revealed, these supervisory arrangements have been suffering from significant shortcomings.

4 Renovating the EMIR Supervisory Architecture

4.1 Cracks in the 2012 EMIR Supervisory Architecture

The supervisory arrangements of the 2012 EMIR regime have been the result of a political compromise. As seen above, the macro-prudential risks posed by CCPs have led to the creation of EMIR colleges. On the other hand, the decentralised model of the ESFS has been retained because fiscal responsibility has remained at the national level.

ESMA’s peer reviews have shown that this hybrid supervisory architecture has been under strain. While home NCAs seem to take into account the inputs from other members during the authorisation process, afterwards colleges risk becoming mere forums for exchanging information and not an ‘effective supervisory tool’.Footnote 186 Furthermore, over the years there have been cases where home NCAs did not share necessary information with other college members in a proactive and timely manner.Footnote 187 In turn, these reacted either by abstaining or by voting against the college’s opinion.Footnote 188 In other instances, home NCAs did not consider it necessary to inform other NCAs of their decisions.Footnote 189 Moreover, colleges comprise a cumbersome number of authorities with different mandates: over twenty members in certain instances.Footnote 190 This fact has inevitably meant that there are different degrees of participation in college discussions.Footnote 191 Overall, home NCAs have retained their often idiosyncratic approach to supervision and enforcement.Footnote 192

In light of these peer reviews, the Commission concluded that the supervisory arrangements of the 2012 EMIR framework were inadequate to address the growing macro-prudential risk of EU-CCPs. Regardless of EMIR colleges and ESMA, NCAs’ diverging supervisory approaches ‘create risks of regulatory and supervisory arbitrage, jeopardising financial stability and allowing for unhealthy competition’.Footnote 193 Moreover, effective decision-making has been compromised by the large number of authorities which sit in the colleges.Footnote 194 Furthermore, the 2012 EMIR regime did not sufficiently reflect the risk of misalignments between CCP supervisory actions and monetary policy imperatives. In the colleges, central banks sit alongside supervisory authorities without a clear division of competences.Footnote 195

Such concerns were shared by the European Parliament and the Council.Footnote 196 However, co-legislators profoundly disagreed with the Commission on how to improve this sub-optimal state of affairs: while the former have decided to retain an EMIR college-based framework, the latter proposed to centralise EU-CCP supervision at the EU level.

4.2 The 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal

In the opinion of the Commission, the centralisation of EU-CCP supervision in ESMA would have significantly improved the 2012 EMIR framework as well as fostering the broader Capital Markets Union agendaFootnote 197 (CMU). The centralisation of EU-CCP supervision in ESMA would have streamlined decision-making, clarified competences between central banks and supervisory authorities, and led to a single approach to EU-CCP supervision.Footnote 198

In particular, a new CCP Executive Session would have been established within ESMA’s Board of Supervisors.Footnote 199 This new body would have had five permanent members:Footnote 200 a voting Head and two voting Directors, a non-voting representative of the ECB, and a non-voting representative of the Commission. Moreover, the CCP Executive Session would have also included non-permanent, CCP-specific members:Footnote 201 one voting representative of home NCAs and one non-voting representative of CBIs. However, CBIs could have vetoed certain home NCA draft decisions on prudential requirements (e.g. liquidity risk controls and collateral requirements) on the basis of monetary stability concerns.Footnote 202

The CCP Executive Session would have substituted the Board of Supervisors in the tasks already conferred upon ESMA by the 2012 EMIR framework.Footnote 203 Furthermore, the CCP Executive Session’s permanent members would have been ex lege voting members of EMIR colleges (apart from the non-voting Commission representative).Footnote 204 Moreover, EMIR colleges would have been chaired by the Head of the CCP Executive Session instead of the home NCA.Footnote 205

Most importantly, home NCAs would have needed the consent of the CCP Executive Session to adopt decisions on:Footnote 206 granting, extending, and withdrawing CCP authorisation; capital requirements; a review and evaluation of the CCP’s regulatory compliance; a review of qualified shareholders; outsourcing; a review of CCP risk models; the approval of interoperability arrangements; and access to the CCP and to trading venues. In these instances, consent would have been deemed as given, unless the CCP Executive Session had put forward objections or amendments to the draft decision of home NCAs.Footnote 207 If amendments had been proposed, the home NCA would have been bound by them. If the CCP Executive Session had objected, the draft decision would have been rejected. The home NCA could have made a final appeal against the decision to ESMA’s Board of Supervisors.Footnote 208 The CCP Executive Session’s decisions would have been adopted under a simple majority vote (the Head would have had the casting vote).Footnote 209

Moreover, the CCP Executive Session could have demanded specific supervisory actions from NCAsFootnote 210 as well as information directly from regulatees.Footnote 211 If home NCAs had not complied with the decisions of the CCP Executive Session, this body could have exercised direct supervisory powers towards financial market participants.Footnote 212 More generally, an amendment to the Proposal would have conferred the powers of the Board of Supervisors to conclude binding mediations and to take actions against NCAs for breaches of EU law on CCP matters upon the CCP Executive Session.Footnote 213

Therefore, the establishment of the CCP Executive Session would have centralised EU-CCP supervisory decision-making in a supranational body. If the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal had been passed in its original form, the home country control principle would have been significantly weakened in key areas of EU-CCP supervision. However, the final outcome of the legislative process to reform the 2012 EMIR framework has been rather different.

4.3 The 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation

Co-legislators have adopted an opposite approach from the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal to address the shortcomings of the 2012 EMIR regime. Instead of centralising EU-CCP supervision at the supranational level, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation extends and proceduralises EMIR college-based arrangements.Footnote 214 Accordingly, the competences of the colleges have been increased:Footnote 215 they are now required to express their opinion also on qualified shareholdingsFootnote 216 and approvals of significant outsourcing agreements of risk management activities.Footnote 217

Moreover, active participation in the meetings is encouraged.Footnote 218 To prevent colleges from becoming mere occasions, each member is empowered to add points to the agenda of the meetingsFootnote 219 as well as to request the insertion of specific recommendations on EU-CCP’s risk management in the collegial opinion.Footnote 220 On the other hand, any significant deviation from the college’s opinion must be thoroughly explained by the home NCA in its final decision.Footnote 221 Consequently, the written agreements regulating the functioning of the colleges must be improved by inserting granular rules on, inter alia: the procedures for determining the agenda as well as the frequency of the meetings; the format, the scope, and modalities for exchanging information between members; and the congruous timeframes to allow college members to analyse the documentation sent by home NCAs.Footnote 222

Additionally, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation seeks to enhance the co-ordinating role of the colleges by broadening their membership.Footnote 223 Subject to the home NCA’s consent, NCAs of any clearing member as well as CBIs of any EU currency can participate in the meetings of the collegeFootnote 224 in a non-voting capacity.Footnote 225 Notably, the composition of colleges has been adapted to take into account the major institutional novelty of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation: ESMA’s new CCP Supervisory Committee,Footnote 226 whose Chair and two independent members must alternatively take over ESMA’s non-voting seat in the colleges.Footnote 227

Such CCP Supervisory Committee is designed as the hub where information and best practices are going to be collected and shared across the network of NCAs, colleges, and CBIs to promote CCP supervisory coordination and convergence.Footnote 228 The Chair and the two independent members of this permanent internal body are going to be appointed by ESMA’s Board of Supervisors—subject to the confirmation of the European ParliamentFootnote 229—for five-year terms (renewable once).Footnote 230 Alongside the CCP-specific NCA, these three independentFootnote 231 experts would be the only voting membersFootnote 232 of the CCP Supervisory Committee.Footnote 233 However, CBIs can request to take part in the CCP Supervisory Committee’s discussions on Union-wide stress tests and market developments relating to EU-CCPs,Footnote 234 albeit in a non-voting capacity.Footnote 235 Moreover, the Chair can invite the remaining members of EMIR colleges as non-voting observers.Footnote 236

The tasks of the CCP Supervisory Committee include promoting exchanges of information and discussions among all the authorities involved in EU-CCP supervision.Footnote 237 Furthermore, the CCP Supervisory Committee is entrusted with conducting NCA peer reviews and coordinating EU-CCP stress tests on (at least) an annual basis.Footnote 238 On the other hand, NCAs and EMIR colleges have to promptly provide the CCP Supervisory Committee with all the information necessary to fulfil its tasks.Footnote 239

Nevertheless, the main mechanism supporting the supervisory convergence role of the CCP Supervisory Committee is the introduction of a new ex ante consultation procedure.Footnote 240 On the one hand, home NCAs are obliged to submit a wide set of draft decisions to ESMA before their formal adoption.Footnote 241 Indeed, this obligation covers most supervisory areas not related to the ‘default waterfall’: access to CCP and trading venues, the granting and extension of CCP authorisation, record keeping requirements, a review of qualifying shareholdings, conflict of interest management, outsourcing agreements, fair treatment requirements towards clearing members and clients, and the approval of interoperability arrangements.Footnote 242 On the other hand, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation permits home NCAs to voluntarily submit any other draft decisions to the CCP Supervisory Committee.Footnote 243 In either case, the CCP Supervisory Committee should assess whether the home NCA’s draft decision impinges on the consistent application of specific EMIR requirements.Footnote 244 If so, the CCP Supervisory Committee must provide home NCAs with its detailed opinion within twenty days from the receipt of the draft decision.Footnote 245 However, while home NCAs must duly take into consideration the opinion eventually issued and inform ESMA of their subsequent conduct,Footnote 246 the content of the final decision remains at their ‘full discretion’.Footnote 247 Similarly, colleges are free ‘to determine the content of their opinion at their own discretion’Footnote 248 despite any contrary advice by the CCP Supervisory Committee. Nonetheless, if such consultation procedure or the other workings of the CCP Supervisory Committee have revealed the persistence of idiosyncratic supervisory practices, ESMA’s Board of Supervisors is empowered to issue the necessary guidelines, recommendations, or opinions on its own initiativeFootnote 249 or at the request of the CCP Supervisory Committee.Footnote 250 Furthermore, the CCP Supervisory Committee could always issue opinions on the Board of Supervisors’ draft decisions on the application of EMIR by NCAs,Footnote 251 save for those on breaches of EU law and binding mediations.Footnote 252

Hence, unlike the Commission’s original proposal, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation leaves the home country control principle intact. Notably, however, the reform is essentially aligned with the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal on two important aspects: the absence of loss mutualisation between Member States and the third-country CCP supervisory arrangements. With regard to the former, co-legislators and the Commission did not want to challenge the original choice of the 2012 EMIR regime to leave fiscal responsibility at the national level.Footnote 253 Accordingly, neither the decision-making CCP Executive Session nor—a fortiori—the internal CCP Supervisory Committee were designed to overrule home NCAs’ decision on fiscally sensitive areas such as the default waterfall.

The other similarity between the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal and the final text agreed by co-legislators concerns the introduction of a new third-country CCP supervisory framework. The reason behind such an agreement is the decision of the United Kingdom to withdraw from the EU: EMIR supervisory arrangements have had to be adapted to take into account the fact that vast amounts of transactions denominated in Union currencies are going to be cleared by third-country CCPs.Footnote 254 Like the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal,Footnote 255 the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation seeks to improve third-country CCP supervisory arrangements by establishing a sliding scale of supervisory and regulatory regimes. Accordingly, ESMA is empowered to determine whether a third-country CCP is (or is likely to be) systemically important.Footnote 256 If it is not (Tier 1), the third-country CCPs would be subject to an equivalence regime.Footnote 257 If it is judged to be systematically important (Tier 2), a third-country CCP would need to abide by the EU regimeFootnote 258 under the supervision of the CCP Supervisory Committee.Footnote 259 Supported by a third-country CCP college,Footnote 260 the CCP Supervisory Committee will prepare the draft supervisory and enforcement decisionsFootnote 261 on third-country CCPs for their final adoption by ESMA’s Board of Supervisors.Footnote 262

The external implications of EMIR reform are outside the scope of this article.Footnote 263 However, the new third-country CCP supervisory framework also has internal repercussions for the division of competences between ESMA and the ESCB.Footnote 264 In particular, the CCP Supervisory Committee must consult with the CBIs of all Union currencies of the financial instruments cleared (or to be cleared)Footnote 265 by a Tier 2 CCP before submitting its draft decisions on margin and collateral requirements, liquidity risk controls, settlement arrangements, and the approval of interoperability arrangements.Footnote 266 While the original proposal of the Commission envisaged that CBIs could veto such draft decisions on the basis of monetary stability concerns,Footnote 267 the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation states that ESMA is not bound by the eventual objections or amendments put forward by any CBI.Footnote 268 However, the CCP Supervisory Committee must duly explain eventual deviations therefrom to the CBI concerned and ESMA’s Board of Supervisors.Footnote 269

Moreover, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation empowers each CBI to impose a specific number of additional obligations which Tier 2 CCPs must meet in order to be recognised. Accordingly, a Tier 2 CCP might be requested to provide the CBI with information that is otherwise unavailable from ESMA as well as to cooperate during stress tests.Footnote 270 Additionally, a Tier 2 CCP might be asked to open (or notify the intent to open) an overnight deposit with the CBI.Footnote 271 Finally, if ‘temporary systemic liquidity risks affecting the transmission of monetary policy or the smooth operation of payment systems’ have materialised, any CBI might impose additional conditions on collateral and margin policy,Footnote 272 settlement and interoperability arrangements, and liquidity risk control of a Tier 2 CCP. However, co-legislators have not given CBIs complete carte blanche. In fact, such requirements are designed to be exceptional and non-permanent: they can be applied only for up to six months (extendable once) and cannot cover ‘other areas of prudential supervision’ than those explicitly mentioned.Footnote 273 Moreover, these measures cannot result in atypical burdens, but they must be in line with the requirements which supervisory authorities can already apply under EMIR to ensure the ‘efficiency, soundness and resilience’ of CCPs.Footnote 274 Furthermore, an ex ante consultation procedure applies: the CBI must explain to ESMA, the third-country CCP college, and all the other relevant members of the ESCB why imposing or extending such exceptional requirements is going to be necessary and proportionate to achieve their monetary policy tasks.Footnote 275 In turn, ESMA and the other members of the ESCB can propose amendments to the draft decision of the CBI.Footnote 276 In the case of an extension, the European Parliament and the Council must be informed as well.Footnote 277

Notably, the power to impose the relocation of Union-denominated business in the EU is not included among the additional conditions which can be applied to Tier 2 CCPs by CBIs. In fact, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation makes it clear that the order to open an overnight deposit ‘should not amount to an obligation to relocate all or part of the clearing services of the CCP’.Footnote 278 Indeed, relocation is envisaged as a last resort measure,Footnote 279 which is not up to CBIs to decide autonomously. Only if a recommendation of ESMA’s Board of Supervisors deems a Tier 2 CCP (or some of its services) to pose unmitigable risks can the Commission deny its recognition; in this case, the only alternative for a Tier 2 CCP would be to relocate in the EU.Footnote 280 CBIs can only put forward amendments or objections to the draft recommendation.Footnote 281 However, CBIs’ amendments or objections are binding only in relation to the currency they issue and ‘not to the recommendation as a whole’.Footnote 282

Such an important but constrained role of central banks in CCP oversight is the final outcome of a spectacular inter-institutional querelle, which has exposed the first of the three weaknesses of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation.

5 Three Weaknesses and One Counterproposal

5.1 ‘Whatever It Takes’

Given the importance of CCPs for both monetary and financial stability, preventing dangerous interest misalignments between supervisory authorities and central banks has been one of the main objectives of the EMIR reforming effort. Accordingly, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation aims at clarifying the spheres of competences of central banks—especially the ECBFootnote 283—in relation to CCPs. However, there seems to be tension between the supervisory arrangements of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation and the monetary constitution of the EMU.

As mentioned above,Footnote 284 the Monetary Union is founded on an independent central bank.Footnote 285 In particular, the definition of the monetary policy of the euro area is reserved to the ECB’s Governing Council.Footnote 286 This body enjoys a wide margin of discretion to accomplish its mandate.Footnote 287 As seen above,Footnote 288 CCPs’ distress might have significant repercussions for monetary stability. Accordingly, the ECB has shown a keen interest in CCPs since it came into operation. As early as 2001, the ECB developed a CCP oversight policy.Footnote 289 In 2011, this framework was updated to include a CCP ‘location policy’. In particular, the ECB could have compelled ‘off shore’ CCPs to relocate their euro-denominated business in the euro area if certain thresholds were exceeded.Footnote 290 Now, as then, a great amount of euro-denominated transactions were cleared by CCPs established in the United Kingdom, thus outside the euro area.Footnote 291 Consequently, the United Kingdom brought three cases against this ECB policy before the General Court. The judges ultimately held that the TreatiesFootnote 292 do not confer explicitly or implicitly an ‘autonomous regulatory competence in respect of all clearing systems’ but only of ‘payment clearing systems’ upon the ECB.Footnote 293 However, the Court also noted that the Treaties envisage a simplified procedure to amend the Statute of the ECB. If the ECB had considered an amendment ‘necessary for the proper performance’ of its tasks, it could have recommended to do so to the co-legislators.Footnote 294

The ECB issued this recommendation after the presentation of the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal. While the ECB had welcomed the Commission’s initiative,Footnote 295 in its opinion the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal did not adequately reflect the risks posed by CCPs to the monetary stability of the euro area.Footnote 296 As noted earlier,Footnote 297 the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal envisaged that CBIs could only veto a supervisory decision taken by ESMA. For the ECB, this regime would have not sufficiently addressed the growing systemic importance of CCPs and the Brexit-related risks. Accordingly, it recommended to amend its Statute to empower the Eurosystem ‘to adopt binding assessments and require remedial action’ on its own.Footnote 298 Moreover, the ECB should have been given additional powers—outside the EMIR framework—over CCPs clearing significant amounts of euro-denominated transactions.

Consequently, co-legislators agreed to amend the ECB’s Statute. However, following the advice of the Commission,Footnote 299 they added significant restrictions on the recommended amendment. The ECB would not have had any new authority over EU-CCPs. Instead, the ECB would have received only a specific number of additional powers over systematically important third-country CCPs. These circumscribed exceptional powers should have been exerted within the framework of the revised EMIR. Accordingly, they should have been exercised only over third-county CCPs deemed systematically important by ESMA.Footnote 300 Notably, the ECB could have not ordered third-country CCPs to relocate their euro-denominated business in the euro area. As seen above, these tight constraints were transposed almost verbatim in the final text of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation.

The Governing Council unanimously considered these limitations unacceptable and withdrew its recommendation.Footnote 301 Exercising its powers within the constraints set by secondary legislation would have deprived the ECB of the ‘discretion to adopt measures which are necessary to carry out the Eurosystem’s basic tasks, and would thus violate the ECB’s functional independence, established in the Treaties’.Footnote 302 Moreover, the ECB noted that it could have exercised these powers only over third-country CCPs deemed to be Tier 2 by ESMA. This fact would ‘limit the scope of the ECB’s competence to address risks to monetary policy or the smooth functioning of payment systems, in a way that infringes its independence, as the ECB’s competence would be based on decisions taken by another authority (ESMA) on the basis of criteria which are distinct from the ECB’s primary mandate’.Footnote 303 Furthermore, the ECB pointed out that both the amendment to the Statute agreed by co-legislators and the text of what would become the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would have required central banks to ensure the ‘efficiency, soundness and resilience of clearing systems for financial instruments’ when they exercise their powers.Footnote 304 For the ECB, these provisions ‘may imply that the ECB must prioritise the objectives of the prudential supervisory framework when carrying out its own tasks, notwithstanding its central banking objectives under the Treaties’.Footnote 305

Therefore, the framework of the CCP Supervision Regulation does not seem to take adequately into account the monetary implications of central clearing. Nevertheless, the next section will argue that the CCP Supervision Regulation would also fail to sufficiently meet the just-mentioned objectives of prudential supervision.

5.2 He Who Pays the Piper Calls the Tune

Fostering the development of a ‘coherent and consistent’Footnote 306 European approach to EU-CCP supervision is another objective of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation. For co-legislators, the establishment of a CCP Supervisory Committee would address the need to counter supervisory idiosyncrasies by reinforcing ‘ESMA’s ability to promote convergence in the supervision of CCPs’.Footnote 307 However, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation does not address the primary source of such inconsistencies, namely the absence of loss mutualisation between Member States.

During the negotiations of the 2012 EMIR regime, Member States decided to allocate EU-CCP fiscal responsibility at the national level. As seen earlier,Footnote 308 this choice has shaped EMIR supervisory arrangements, which have left EU-CCP supervision mostly in the hands of home NCAs. The decentralised ESFS was just adapted by creating the inadequate EMIR colleges. As a necessary consequence, NCAs have not developed a single approach to EU-CCP supervision. In fact, some members of the Board of Supervisors have shown some apprehension for the supervisory convergence role played by ESMA under the 2012 EMIR regimeFootnote 309 and for any further centralisation.Footnote 310

The 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would not change this state of affairs. As in the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal,Footnote 311 fiscal responsibility remains at the national level. Accordingly, the new ex ante mandatory consultation procedure has been designed so as to ensure ‘that that the final content of the respective decision would remain at the full discretion of the CCP’s competent authority’,Footnote 312 regardless of any objection by the CCP Supervisory Committee. Furthermore, such a procedure does not cover home NCAs’ measures on the default waterfall, which is the most sensitive aspect of EU-CCP supervision. As seen earlier,Footnote 313 the mutualisation of losses via the default waterfall is central clearing’s main benefit and greatest danger at once. Nevertheless, home NCAs would remain totally responsible for the supervision of the main source of the macro-prudential risk of EU-CCPs as under the 2012 EMIR framework. As ESMA’s peer reviews have shown, this could lead to idiosyncratic supervisory practices.

Indeed, past experience has demonstrated that it would be impossible to create arrangements ensuring a single supervisory approach without a prior agreement on loss mutualisation. As noted above,Footnote 314 the centralisation of banking prudential supervision in the ECB was only possible after the establishment of the ESM. The SSM was envisaged as a guarantee against future fiscal transfers between Member States via the ESM. Accordingly, loss mutualisation has led to what appears to be a solid centralised framework based on a single supervisory manual.Footnote 315 Quite revealingly, the Commission acknowledged that a truly single CCP supervisor would be required to ‘address effectively the need for supervisory convergence’; by its own admission, this choice was not possible because ‘supervisory and fiscal responsibilities would not be fully aligned’.Footnote 316

Therefore, it is questionable that the CCP Supervisory Committee could effectively deliver an European supervisory approach to counter the macro-prudential risk of CCPs. However, it could be contended that the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would at least streamline supervisory decision-making. As the next section will argue, this is not the case.

5.3 Duplications

One of the main reasons for revising the 2012 EMIR regime was simplifying its decision-making. Paradoxically, the centralised framework envisaged by the initial 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal of the Commission would have added another layer of complexity to the EMIR supervisory architecture.Footnote 317 The centralisation of certain supervisory decisions in the CCP Executive Session would not have totally abolished the 2012 EMIR supervisory arrangements. Home NCAs would have retained a decisive role, especially in relation to the most fiscally sensitive tasks. Moreover, EMIR colleges would have continued to exist because of the cross-border, cross-sectoral importance of EU-CCPs. Indeed, their unwieldiness would have been increased by the addition of the permanent members of the CCP Executive Session. Furthermore, the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal would have left final decision-making to ESMA’s Board of Supervisors. This was a forced choice. As mentioned above, ESMA’s governance arrangements points to the Board of Supervisors as the ultimate location of decision-making in order to respect the EU constitutional ‘balance of powers’ as defined by the Meroni doctrine. Indeed, the supervisory powers of the CCP Executive Session would have needed to be tightly circumscribed and proceduralised to avoid the legal uncertainties associated with Meroni.Footnote 318 However, ESMA itself has repeatedly lamented that the formal and substantial constraints attached to its powers undermine its supervisory action.Footnote 319 Nevertheless, the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal did not seem to address this issue.Footnote 320

Instead, as denounced by the entire EU-CCP industry, the result of the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal would have been redundant and opaque supervisory arrangements.Footnote 321 Even ESMA’s Chair himself publicly declared that he did not support the reform put forward by the Commission. The 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal would have made ‘ESMA’s governance top-heavy and inefficient’ and there would have been ‘the risk of uncoordinated decisions, strategies, and communication’ between the Board of Supervisors and the CCP Executive Session.Footnote 322

While it is difficult to see how the CCP Executive Session could have streamlined decision-making, the 2017 CCP Supervision Proposal might be interpreted as a failed attempt by the Commission to increase the supranational grip on ESMA.Footnote 323 The CCP Executive Session’s Head and Directors would have been shortlisted by the Commission.Footnote 324 Together with the Commission representative in the CCP Executive Session, they would have increased the Commission’s influence over regulates and NCAs. However, this intention of the Commission clashed with the realities of ESMA’s governance arrangements. As already mentioned,Footnote 325 ESMA is built upon NCAs. Despite the risk of remaining ‘national-minded bureaucrats’,Footnote 326 the NCAs sitting on the Board of Supervisors have been able to develop a consistent and responsive approach to EU financial markets regulation and supervision.Footnote 327 Transplanting a hierarchical supranational bureaucracy into an NCA-based framework could have altered this equilibrium, especially since the CCP Executive Session could have forced NCAs to take fiscally sensitive decisions.Footnote 328

Co-legislators foresaw this risk of the initial proposal of the Commission. The final text of the reform could not be clearer: the three technocratic permanent members of the ‘internal’Footnote 329 CCP Supervisory Committee will be shortlisted by ESMA’s Board of Supervisors,Footnote 330 which however retains ‘final decision-making power’Footnote 331 alongside NCAs, EU-CCP colleges, and CBIs. According to the rapporteur of the European Parliament, this framework ‘would be a more proportionate option than this of a wholly new ESMA configuration such as the executive session proposed by the Commission’.Footnote 332

Indeed, even though the CCP Supervisory Committee ‘should not constitute a precedent for the ESAs’,Footnote 333 the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation appears to be in line with the broader reform of ESMA’s governance proposed by Professor Moloney to streamline ESMA’s decision-making. She has suggested to establish a committee framework within ESMA. These committees would comprise members of the Board of Supervisors. They would be tasked with preparing draft decisions for later adoption by the qualified majority of the Board of Supervisors. Moreover, an independent ‘Monitoring Board’ would be created to constructively assist the Board of Supervisors in developing its supervisory strategies.Footnote 334

However, a closer look at the 2019 CCP Supervisory Regulation reveals that this piece of legislation shares just a superficial resemblance with such sensible adjustments. In fact, co-legislators have made EU-CCP supervisory arrangements even more burdensome. While home NCAs remain primarily responsible for EU-CCP supervision, the persisting college-based framework has been further complicated by the introduction of the CCP Supervisory Committee. Lacking decision-making powers, this internal body is designed as a hub where ‘additional reaction’ is given by a ‘group of supervisors specialised and experienced in the supervision of CCPs’.Footnote 335 However, such experienced supervisors would already have the opportunity to exchange their views in EMIR colleges, which comprise all the authorities sitting in the CCP Supervisory Committee. Indeed, colleges have seen their competences extended to cover most of the same supervisory areas subject to the new ex ante mandatory consultation procedure.Footnote 336 Moreover, no enforcement novelties underpin such procedural duplication: the NCA-dominated Board of Supervisors remains the ultimate arbiter of which national supervisory idiosyncrasies must be sanctioned.Footnote 337

On the other hand, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would accentuate the pre-existing flaws of EMIR colleges by extending their membership. As ESMA’s peer reviews have exposed, the effectiveness of the colleges is hindered by the cumbersome number of authorities participating in the meetings, each with its own peculiar mandate, distinct expertise, and national sensitivities.Footnote 338 Nonetheless, the reform empowers NCAs of any clearing member as well any CBIs to ask to take part in the colleges.Footnote 339 While home NCAs must consent, peer dynamics and the ‘comply-or-explain’ mechanism backing the requestFootnote 340 make an eventual refusal unlikely. Indeed, co-legislators have recognised that such enlargement of college composition could obstruct an ‘appropriate, effective and swift decision-making process’.Footnote 341 In their opinion, such a risk could be prevented by depriving the members, on request, of the right to vote. However, their title of members would still empower them to participate in the college discussions, which would inevitably be time-consuming considering the increasing number of authorities sitting in the meetings. If this was not the case and the members on request passively received information without any active contribution to the college discussions, the reform would accelerate the negative tendency of EMIR colleges to be mere forums for information exchange rather than ‘effective supervisory tools’.Footnote 342

Therefore, far from simplifying supervisory decision-making, neither the centralised framework envisaged by the initial Commission proposal nor the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation would streamline EU-CCP supervisory arrangements. In fact, maintaining the home country control principle alongside EMIR colleges would hamper the effectiveness of any central supervisory body, be it a CCP Executive Session or a CCP Supervisory Committee. Moreover, even admitting that it might be possible to improve the decision-making process under such conditions, there would still be the need for an European approach to EU-CCP supervision which could adequately take into account the monetary implications of central clearing. In order to achieve such objectives, a modest counterproposal is put forward in the next section.

5.4 The Counterproposal

The counterproposal is to centralise EU-CCP supervision in two EU bodies along objective lines. On the one hand, EU-CCP prudential supervision should be conferred upon the ECB. Accordingly, EU-CCPs should be subject to ECB supervision in relation to the matters already included in the SSM framework (e.g. authorisation, qualified holdings, capital and liquidity requirements, governance requirements, the review of risk models).Footnote 343 However, the scope of the SSM should be adapted to the peculiar mechanics and risks of central clearing. Therefore, the ECB should be empowered to supervise EU-CCPs’ default waterfall, default procedures, and interoperability arrangements.Footnote 344 On the other hand, EU-CCP conduct of business supervision should be conferred on ESMA’s Board of Supervisors. In particular, ESMA should ensure that CCPs act transparently, fairly, and professionally in light of the best interests of their clients. Therefore, ESMA should supervise EU-CCP conflict of interest requirements, participation requirements, record-keeping requirements, account segregation and portability requirements.Footnote 345 Given its acquired technical capacity, ESMA could also be involved in CCP stress testing together with ECB.

While the conferral of conduct of business supervision upon ESMA could be based on TFEU Article 114, entrusting the ECB with EU-CCP prudential supervision is somewhat more problematic. Given the failed attempt to reform the ECB’s Statute, a possible legal basis could be the same provision which enabled the establishment of the SSM, namely TFEU Article 127(6).Footnote 346 It has been contended that the scope of this provision is not bound by the definitions provided by secondary legislation.Footnote 347 However, it is worth considering whether CCPs can already fall within the definition of the ‘financial institutions’ named in this provision. EMIR suggestively, but imprecisely, defines CCPs as ‘the buyer to every seller and the seller to every buyer’.Footnote 348 In turn, the EU’s capital requirements regime defines ‘financial institutions’ as undertakings whose principal activity is, inter alia, ‘trading for own account or for account of customers’ in ‘exchange and interest-rate instruments’.Footnote 349 These contracts form the majority of the OTC derivatives subject to EMIR clearing obligations.Footnote 350 Accordingly, it can be argued that CCPs are par excellence financial institutions. Their very raison d’être is to trade (to buy and to sell in the words of EMIR) derivatives including exchange and interest-rate instruments for the account of their customers (the clearing members).Footnote 351 Indeed, there might be grounds to include EU-CCPs even in the category of ‘credit institutions’ since the German CCP Eurex as well as the French CCP LCH SA are so authorised.Footnote 352

Adopting such a centralised and objective-based framework would bring the benefits that the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation (as well as the initial proposal of the Commission) tries to achieve to no avail, but without its shortcomings.

First, as already recognised by some—including the Commission—, the full centralisation of EU-CCP supervision at the EU level would be necessary to develop an effective single supervisory approach.Footnote 353 In this regard, while pragmatically making good use of national expertise, the SSM has proved to be a solid and unitarian framework for prudential supervision.Footnote 354 In turn, ESMA has acquired unique knowledge in the field of conduct of business supervision thanks to its multiple roles already played in this field.Footnote 355

Second, the SSM framework already contains established internal mechanisms to conciliate supervisory actions with monetary policy.Footnote 356 In particular, the ECB’s Governing Council can veto decisions of the Supervisory Board on the basis of monetary stability concerns.Footnote 357 In case of disagreement, NCAs could request the intervention of a Mediation Panel.Footnote 358

Third, decision-making would be effectively streamlined. On the one hand, the SSM already contains relatively effective and ‘Meroni-free’ decision-making procedures.Footnote 359 On the other hand, ESMA’s decision-making process—especially if enhanced by Professor Moloney’s committee framework—would not be burdened by the constraints of the home country control principle and EMIR collegial procedures.

Fourth, the most fiscally sensitive supervisory decisions would be conferred upon an EU institution with relatively adequate accountability arrangements. While ESMA’s accountability mechanisms are still developing,Footnote 360 the ECB has been able to build a constructive (although perfectible) dialogue with the representatives of the EU people.Footnote 361

Fifth, the eventual expansionist tendencies of the Behemoth represented by the ECB could be counterbalanced by ESMA.Footnote 362 Indeed, also the ECB has expressed its preference for a single counterparty in financial markets supervision.Footnote 363

Finally, this new supervisory framework would be a significant step towards the desired European ‘Financial Union’Footnote 364 and the envisaged pan-EU ‘Twin Peaks’Footnote 365 model, which could lead to responsive and consistent supervision across the Single Market.Footnote 366

Nevertheless, this reform would not be without its challenges, and a certain number of criticisms can be anticipated.

Firstly, it could be pointed out that such reform would require that Member States—at least those in the euro area—decide to mutualise losses. Indeed, the different outcomes of ESFS and SSM negotiations have confirmed that the centralisation of supervisory tasks is possible only after an agreement on loss mutualisation. However, the current institutional and political situation has proved to be particularly propitious for overhauls of the EMIR framework: Brexit has meant that the EU has lost the fiercest opponent of CCP supervisory centralisation.Footnote 367

Furthermore, linking EU-CCP supervision to the SSM could be questioned. It could be argued that the cross-border risks posed by EU-CCP require a prudential framework covering the whole EU from the beginning. Moreover, it could be contested that this reform would be another attempt by euro area countries to impose their objectives over the Internal Market project.Footnote 368 Indeed, establishing a pan-EU framework from the start would be the outcome desired by this paper. Nevertheless, the history of EU integration is marked by a pragmatic and incremental recycling of existing rules.Footnote 369 The counterproposal advanced here would be in line with that history. Given the great efforts made for establishing the SSM, creating a whole new prudential supervisory framework would be neither realistic nor efficient. Furthermore, a significant part of EU-CCP operations would still be supervised by a pan-EU authority such as ESMA, which would inject an Internal Market perspective into the framework. Moreover, it is worth noting that after Brexit only three EU-CCPs are currently established outside the euro area.Footnote 370 Therefore, it can be argued that EU-CCP supervision is mostly going to be an issue affecting the euro area. In addition, if non-euro area countries wanted to reap the benefits of this model, they could always ask for a close cooperation agreement under the SSM framework.Footnote 371

Employing TFEU Article 127(6) as a legal basis can be questioned too. Indeed, the exact scope of the ‘specific tasks’ mentioned by that provision has been the object of a long querelle between those in favour of an extensive readingFootnote 372 and those advancing a restrictive interpretation.Footnote 373 However, even admitting that the latter group is right, conferring EU-CCP prudential supervision upon the ECB remains ceteris paribus a more sensible solution than the supervisory arrangements of the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation for the reasons listed above.

Indeed, this diatribe on TFEU Article 127(6) has its origin in the discussions between its drafters. In particular, some of them feared that entrusting a central bank with prudential supervision would have prejudiced its monetary functions.Footnote 374 While this is a sustainable position also with regard to CCPs, it is worth noting that there is not yet an established consensus on this issue.Footnote 375 Moreover, as noted above, the SSM already contains mechanisms to conciliate supervisory decisions with monetary policy. They seem to work smoothly.Footnote 376

The drafting of Article TFEU 127(6) has been influenced by another concern, which resurfaced when the SSM was established: the risk of concentrating too much power in the statutorily independent ECB.Footnote 377 However, this legitimate preoccupation must be reconsidered in light of EU-CCP industry. In particular, there are just thirteen CCPs established in the EU.Footnote 378 The ECB already directly supervises many of the euro area credit institutions which can meet the stringent requirements for being clearing members. Accordingly, the ECB is already part of EMIR colleges which supervise the few EU-CCPs.Footnote 379 Given these tasks already conferred upon the ECB, it can be argued that entrusting the ECB with EU-CCP prudential supervision would not significantly move the existing balance of powers. Moreover, as noted above, the ECB has been ready to refine its accountability arrangements for its supervisory tasks.Footnote 380

6 Conclusion

CCPs have gone rapidly from being a solution to a problem. There is a growing awareness worldwide that the concentration of large volumes of OTC derivatives transactions into few interconnected FMIs could have dramatic consequences in the future. Nevertheless, the risks posed by CCPs are particularly dangerous for the EU. Financial distress experienced by one EU-CCP could reverberate across the EMU with unpredictable knock-on effects. Indeed, the sovereign debt crisis is a testament to the fragility of the Union.

Therefore, the EU-CCP supervisory architecture must be built on robust foundations. EMIR supervisory arrangements have proved to be too burdensome and fragmented to effectively address the challenges of CCPs. The EU must be praised for recognising the dangers of inaction. Nevertheless, the 2019 CCP Supervision Regulation creates more problems than it solves. While NCAs might keep on maintaining their idiosyncratic supervisory practices, EMIR supervisory arrangements would become even more unwieldy. Furthermore, ESMA’s new powers are in tension with the high level of independence enjoyed by the ECB as a central bank.

The centralised and objective-based model proposed by this paper for EU-CCP supervision might seem more ambitious, but it would exploit the potential of the current EU supervisory architecture. The SSM has proved to be a solid and unitary framework for prudential supervision. The ECB has developed smooth decision-making procedures and relatively adequate accountability arrangements. On the other hand, this framework would put to good use ESMA’s expertise in conduct of business supervision. Moreover, ESMA might represent the necessary counterbalance to possible expansionist tendencies of the ECB. Finally, the fruitful cooperative relationship developed by NCAs within ESMA’s Board of Supervisors would not be endangered by an alien supranational bureaucracy as in the original proposal of the Commission.

Past experience has shown that such a reform might only be possible after an agreement on loss mutualisation between Member States. However, Member States should be wary of inaction. The decision made in Maastricht of having a Monetary Union without a truly complete Economic Union has had dramatic consequences decades later. However, Member States have proved to be ready to agree on ambitious supervisory reforms, at least when they are pressured to do so. The establishment of the SSM was possible only after a crisis which put into question the existence of the Union. The hope expressed by this paper is that an adequate reform of EMIR supervisory arrangements would not require such a trauma.