1 Introduction

In 2001 Roger Lowenstein noted that the Fed’s initiative to organise a private bailout of hedge fund management firm Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) was not done out of sympathy for LTCM nor to prevent losses to exposed financial institutions.Footnote 1 Instead, the driving concern was ‘the broader notion of “systemic risk”; if Long-Term failed, and if its creditors forced a hasty and disorderly liquidation, [the Fed] feared that it would harm the entire financial system, not just some of its big participants’.Footnote 2 Still, with the last financial meltdown dating back to the 1930s, it was unclear whether ‘systemic risk’ presented a real threat. Lowenstein noted that it was a ‘parlor topic, not something the bankers wanted to spend $250 million on’.Footnote 3

Any residual doubt about the threat posed by systemic risk was dispelled 10 years later when the onset of the Global Financial Crisis necessitated large-scale government intervention to prevent the markets from collapsing.

The Global Financial Crisis painfully demonstrated deficiencies in the regulation, supervision and resolution of financial institutions. Not only in the traditional banking sector but also in other parts of the financial system. Indeed, systemic risk manifested itself to a large degree outside the traditional banking sector, especially in the lightly regulated shadow banking sector. The latter refers, quite ominously, to market-based credit intermediation outside the banking sector. Due to a lack of comprehensive regulation and supervision, banks increasingly shifted activities to the shadow banking sector in order to avoid tax, disclosure and capital requirements.Footnote 4 Such behaviour, which is designed to evade more stringent regulation and supervision or to evade regulation and supervision altogether, is known as regulatory arbitrage. The exploitation of regulatory gaps, however, creates risks to financial stability and puts paid to the notion of a level playing field.

To strengthen financial stability, we propose that non-bank financial institutions which are systemically relevant should be subjected to European prudential regulation and to a European supervisor and a European resolution authority.Footnote 5

Our proposals exclude banks as they are already subject to stricter prudential regulation under the Capital Requirements Directives (CRD IV) and Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) and, within the Member States participating in the European Banking Union (EBU), are subject to the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) and the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM). Within the SSM, significant banks are directly supervised by the ECB and resolved by the Single Resolution Board (SRB).Footnote 6

In accordance with the approach of the Financial Stability BoardFootnote 7 and the US Dodd-Frank reforms,Footnote 8 we advocate that the EU’s sectoral approach to financial regulation, supervision and resolution be complemented by a more risk-based identification, regulation, supervision and resolution of non-bank systemically important financial institutions. Any non-bank financial institutionFootnote 9 which could pose a threat to financial stability—referred to as non-bank systemically important financial institutions (non-bank SIFIs)—should therefore be subject to commensurate supervision, regulation and resolution, regardless of the legal categorisation of the non-bank financial institution.Footnote 10 This would entail partial reform and extension of supervision, regulation and resolution of financial institutions in the EU, which is presently organised largely along sectoral lines, and a move towards a more pan-sectoral regime for non-bank SIFIs. A cross-sectoral supervisory and resolution regime for non-bank SIFIs would correspond with the increasingly blurred distinction between markets, financial institutions and products.Footnote 11 It would also help to reduce regulatory arbitrage activities and gaps in coverage, as it would ensure that the risks posed by a non-bank SIFI are subject to commensurate regulation, regardless of the legal form of the entity. In order to properly identify non-bank SIFIs, robust monitoring of the entire European financial sector is necessary.

The proposed regime is in line with financial reform proposals issued by the Financial Stability Board (FSB), which call for a level of supervision proportionate to the potential destabilisation risk that a financial firm poses to the financial system.Footnote 12 Additionally, the FSB requires an effective resolution regime for all financial institutions which could be systemically significant or critical if they fail.Footnote 13

For the development of such a regime we draw on the experiences in the US. There, non-bank financial companies can already be designated as systemically important. Such designation puts them under federal supervision and, reflecting their importance to the financial system, makes them subject to specific prudential and living will requirements. Additionally, non-bank financial institutions posing a systemic risk may be subjected to a specialised resolution regime.

This article seeks to contribute to the discussion on the development within the European Union of a regulatory regime which adequately addresses and mitigates the risk to financial stability posed by non-bank SIFIs. Section 2 therefore highlights the relevance of the problem by reiterating lessons learned from the Global Financial Crisis, especially in respect of the systemic risk posed by non-bank financial institutions. Section 3 examines recommendations made by international bodies, most notably the Financial Stability Board (FSB), in response to the Global Financial Crisis, to increase regulation, supervision and resolution in the financial sector. Section 4 draws inspiration from the US regime, which is of special interest as it already provides for the designation and consequential supervision and resolution of non-bank SIFIs. Section 5 considers the existing body of European financial regulation. We assess what has already been accomplished since the Global Financial Crisis and provide context to our proposed regime of non-bank SIFI supervision and resolution. Section 6 makes suggestions and explores legal possibilities for enhancing the existing body of European financial regulation by including designation, supervision and resolution of non-bank SIFIs at the European level. Section 7 contains our concluding remarks.

2 Systemic Risk

The Global Financial Crisis highlighted a number of structural weaknesses in the worldwide financial system and economies. One of the most important lessons was the, generally unforeseen, possibility of systemic risk originating from non-bank financial institutions.

Systemic risk is the risk that a national, regional or the global, financial system will break down.Footnote 14 Systemic risks manifest themselves where a localised shock—such as the failure of a financial institution—has repercussions that adversely affect the broader economy.Footnote 15 It thus poses a threat to financial stability.Footnote 16 Systemic risk can manifest itself in many different forms and within a range of financial institutions. As noted by Anabtawi and Schwarcz, systemic risks do not distinguish between financial market participants.Footnote 17 Systemic risk should therefore be regarded as an elusive concept, not confined to certain institutions, markets or products.Footnote 18 Accordingly, financial regulation should have an equally flexible and open scope.

Despite the regulatory focus, it turned out that systemic risk was not confined to the (retail) banking sector. Non-bank financial institutions such as Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM), American International Group (AIG) and Reserve Primary proved equally capable of creating systemic risk. This realisation is reflected in the European Systemic Risk Board Regulation, which acknowledges that all types of financial intermediaries, markets and infrastructure may potentially be systemically important to some degree.Footnote 19 Additionally, both the legislative proposal of the European Commission (Commission) on a framework for the recovery and resolution of central counterparties (CCPs)Footnote 20 and its proposal for the creation of a new supervisory mechanism for CCPs aim to regulate and supervise the systemic risk posed by CCPs.Footnote 21 This illustrates our premise that non-bank financial institutions are equally capable of posing systemic risks.Footnote 22 Asset management activities are another example of a potential source of non-bank systemic risk which has recently attracted attention.Footnote 23

The Commission’s proposal for the establishment of a Capital Markets Union (CMU) is also of interest as the envisaged growth of non-bank credit intermediation makes overarching checks on systemic risks even more pressing.Footnote 24 Designed to increase the supply of alternative sources of financing—thereby reducing dependence on funding through the banking sector—the CMU proposal looks to increase the role of non-bank financial intermediaries.Footnote 25 Such diversification of funding improves the allocation of capital and diversification of risk and thereby strengthens the European financial system. At the same time, as recognised by the ‘Five Presidents’ Report’, closer integration of capital markets and gradual removal of remaining national barriers necessitates an expansion and strengthening of the available tools to manage financial players’ systemic risks prudently (macro-prudential toolkit) and to strengthen the supervisory framework to ensure the solidity of all financial actors.Footnote 26 This should, according to the report, ultimately lead to a single European capital markets supervisor.Footnote 27

This shows that systemic risk can occur in different sectors, or indeed across different sectors, and have a variety of distinct characteristics. Therefore it might be difficult to identify such risks. It is therefore of great importance for jurisdictions to have a broad monitoring system in place, capable of identifying systemic risk throughout the entire financial sector.

2.1 Deregulation and Growth of the Financial Sector

As this article aims to contribute to the discussion on how to alleviate systemic risk, specifically in regard to non-bank financial institutions, a short consideration of the role of such entities in the manifestation of systemic risk, especially during the Global Financial Crisis, is in order.

By the mid-1990s the financial sectors in the EU and US were thriving. Technological advances, for instance in information services, led to economy-of-scale benefits.Footnote 28 Additionally, the perception that some of the largest financial institutions were Too-Big-To-Fail provided them with implicit guarantees, thereby generating additional confidence and growth.Footnote 29

At the same time, financial institutions, notably banks, successfully advocated deregulation and the removal of obstacles to growth and competition.Footnote 30 In 1994 this led the US to allow bank holding companies to acquire bank subsidiaries in all states.Footnote 31 In 1999 this was followed by the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act which repealed the restriction on affiliations between banks and securities firms imposed by the Glass–Steagall Act. As a consequence, banks were allowed to underwrite and sell securities and insurance products. Conversely, it allowed securities firms and investment banks to take deposits. Such developments paved the way for large-scale consolidation and growth within and across the banking, securities and insurance sector.Footnote 32 Boosted by progress in the creation of an internal market—specifically through the abolition of obstacles to the free flow of goods, persons, services and capital and the creation of the euro in 1999—a similar trend of increased cross-border activities, consolidation, and growth of financial institutions was evident in the European Union.Footnote 33

The financial supervisory and regulatory regimes remained, however, highly fragmented both geographically and sectorally. In the US, competition between supervisors led to a race to the bottom and, in the absence of a robust consolidated supervisor, regulators failed to identify excessive risks and unsound practices in non-bank financial institutions.Footnote 34 Securities firms, for example, were allowed to attract FDIC-insured deposits without becoming subject to supervision by the Fed.Footnote 35 Likewise, in the EU, financial prudential regulation and supervision was focused on banks.Footnote 36 In consequence, regulators failed to identify the build-up of excessive risk in the financial markets and non-bank financial institutions.

2.2 The Rise of Shadow Banking

The limited perimeter of prudential regulation, the focus on bank supervision and the lack of prudential regulation in the shadow banking sector were informed by the belief that only the banking sector could pose systemic risk. Infamous bank runs clearly contributed to this belief. As shadow banking institutions do not attract insured deposits ‘[t]here was little concern of a bank run’ regarding such institutions.Footnote 37 The reasoning was that such an institution could be left to fail. Furthermore, in a worst-case scenario the government was not liable to refund the insured deposits. Investors who contracted with these firms were supposedly aware of the risks. Indeed, it was thought that an increase in market-based credit intermediation, supplementing the credit provision by banks, would diminish systemic risk.Footnote 38 This proved incorrect.

Financial institutions, eager to take advantage of regulatory gaps, increasingly moved financial intermediation outside the regulatory perimeter of the traditional banking sector.Footnote 39 There they could perform bank-like maturity and liquidity transformation combined with highly leveraged funding structures, while largely unchecked by prudential regulation and oversight. In so far as regulation was present—mostly through securities and insurance regulation—it predominantly focused on market efficiency, transparency, integrity, and consumer and investor protection.Footnote 40 Moreover, as these activities fell outside the regulatory perimeter of banks, regulators were poorly equipped to spot the systemic risks they presented.Footnote 41 The premise that systemic risk was limited to the banking sector led to gaps in regulation and supervision in the financial sector.Footnote 42 Indeed, banking regulation, such as the Basel capital frameworks, did not account for, and thus encouraged, the shifting of risks off the balance sheet.Footnote 43

While precise definitions of ‘shadow banking’ vary, we will adopt the Financial Stability Board’s definition, namely ‘the system of credit intermediation that involves entities and activities outside the regular banking system’.Footnote 44 The FSB propagates a ‘wide net’ approach to defining the shadow bank sector, focusing on ‘credit intermediation that takes place in an environment where prudential regulatory standards and supervisory oversight are either not applied or are applied to a materially lesser or different degree than is the case for regular banks engaged in similar activities’.Footnote 45 This includes inter alia money market funds, hedge funds, insurance companies, mutual funds, structured investment vehicles and pension funds.

The shadow banking sector expanded rapidly in the years leading up to the crisis. Using a broad definition of non-bank credit intermediaries, the FSB gauged that the total assets in the global shadow banking sector had increased from $26 trillion in 2002 to $62 trillion in 2007.Footnote 46 More recently, the FSB assessed the total assets of non-bank financial intermediation of 20 jurisdictions and the euro area at $137 trillion, representing about 40% of total financial system assets.Footnote 47 In addition to its wide net approach, the FSB developed a narrow measurement methodology to narrow down shadow bank monitoring to those elements of non-bank credit intermediation where important risks may exist or are most likely to emerge. According to this measure, shadow banking amounted to $34 trillion at the end of 2015 for 26 jurisdictions.Footnote 48 This is 3.2% more than in the previous year. In the EU, the size of the broadly defined shadow banking sector amounted to €37 trillion in total assets at the end of 2015. This equals 36% of the total EU financial sector assets and constitutes a growth of 27% since 2012.Footnote 49

Just as in the traditional banking sector, credit intermediation in the shadow banking sector revolves around the transformation of maturities.Footnote 50 Short-term debt is used to fund securitised assets such as Asset-Backed Securities (ABS). However, a key characteristic of shadow banking is that it does not fund itself with deposits. Instead, funds are attracted through a variety of wholesale short-term borrowing markets. These include commercial paper, asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP), unsecured interbank lending, and secured repo borrowing.Footnote 51

2.3 The Risks of Shadow Banking

Credit intermediation which is performed through the shadow banking sector and is not driven by regulatory arbitrage can generate economic valueFootnote 52 and render the financial system more resilient by providing an alternative to bank funding.Footnote 53 However, when non-bank institutions perform bank-like activities—i.e. engage in maturity and liquidity transformation and employ leverage—without being subject to prudential regulation and supervision, financial stability may be jeopardised.Footnote 54 Shadow banking activities that derive their value (exclusively) from avoiding costly regulation thus proved to be a central weakness of the financial system.Footnote 55 It follows that the less stringent—or even lack of—regulation and supervision of the shadow banking sector was not in accordance with the systemic risks posed by it.Footnote 56 These risks manifested themselves in 2008 when the lack of proper oversight, regulation and a fiscal backstop, in combination with high leverage and maturity mismatches, created such vulnerabilities that a relatively small shock could trigger widespread panic in the financial markets.

Such a shock occurred in 2007–2008 when a downturn in the US housing and mortgage market, provoked by excessive credit provision, led to losses on subprime mortgages and associated financial products.Footnote 57 Although the losses on subprime mortgages were substantial, running into the hundreds of billions of dollars, they were relatively small in the context of the total financial system. For example, the losses from subprime mortgages were no larger than those suffered when the Dotcom Bubble burst.Footnote 58 However, the consequences were substantially worse. This was because the subprime mortgage crisis interacted with and exposed deeper systemic vulnerabilities in the financial systemFootnote 59 in ways which did not occur in the case of the Dotcom Bubble.Footnote 60

Financial institutions had, through innovative financial engineering, created highly complex financial products. As the market shifted from an originate-to-hold to an originate-to-distribute model, loans were packaged as securities and sold to other financial institutions. Although such products can be used to allocate resources to where they are of most value, it can also reduce the stability of the financial system.Footnote 61 Their complexity makes it hard to assess the risks involved, leading to investment in financial products which, in hindsight, were highly toxic.Footnote 62 Additionally, and crucially, many risky financial instruments were held on the balance sheets of financial institutions.Footnote 63 Subsequent losses on subprime-related financial products proved devastating for the highly leveraged financial firms which held them on their balance sheets. Those losses extended well beyond the banking sector. Shadow bank entities such as investment funds, insurance companies (including monoline insurers which guaranteed mortgage securities) and other institutional investors all experienced massive losses related to the subprime mortgage market. It should be recalled that banks and shadow banking entities are highly interconnected as many different financial institutions are involved at various stages of the credit intermediation process.Footnote 64 Banks shifted risks off their balance sheets and into shadow bank entities in order to take advantage of regulatory arbitrage. However, when these entities failed, banks sometimes preferred to support them beyond their contractual obligation or equity ties, mainly to avoid reputational risks.Footnote 65 This is referred to as ‘step-in’ risk, as it provides an additional channel of contagion between the banking and the shadow banking system.Footnote 66 As a consequence, the systemic relevance of shadow bank entities stems for a large part from their connectedness with the rest of the financial system.Footnote 67

During the Global Financial Crisis, authorities were forced to take a range of unconventional measures to provide liquidity and stability to the financial markets, starting with their traditional function of lender of last resort. In the US the Fed provided a discount window to eligible commercial banks. This proved ineffective as concerns of being stigmatised made banks hesitant to use it.Footnote 68 Furthermore, for the purposes of the broader financial system, the Fed normally relied on the banks to lend part of the received liquidity to solvent non-bank institutions. But this did not happen to the extent that it had in the past.Footnote 69 This led to a number of programmes for the provision of liquidity to primary dealers.Footnote 70 Despite these efforts, Lehman Brothers—a shadow bank—filed for bankruptcy on 15 September 2008.Footnote 71

After Lehman Brother’s bankruptcy the markets for the rollover of short-term debt, through interbank lending, repo and ABCP, froze.Footnote 72 Uncertainty about the institutions’ health and about the prices of posted collateral caused lenders to stop extending credit.Footnote 73 Reserve Primary Fund, a money market fund (MMF), had heavily invested in commercial paper issued by Lehman Brothers. During the days following Lehman’s bankruptcy, redemption requests to Reserve Primary constituted about half of the fund’s liabilities. This caused Reserve Primary to ‘break the buck’ on 16 September 2008 when shares were redeemed below their 1$ face value. This caused money market funds to experience run-like behaviour.Footnote 74 This in turn left the US Department of Treasury no other option than to guarantee a net asset value of $1 on the shares of all MMFs in order to relieve panic in the financial markets.

Another notorious example of underperforming supervision, and the systemic risks posed by a shadow bank entity, was apparent in the case of American International Group (AIG). AIG’s Financial Products subsidiary sold enormous amounts of credit default swaps. Being adept at regulatory arbitrage, it managed to select the regulator least likely to restrict its practices: the Office of Thrift Supervision.Footnote 75

As has been extensively noted, the consequences of Lehman’s bankruptcy were more severe than imagined.Footnote 76 After Lehman, the scale and number of government programmes rapidly increased.

Most significantly, US Congress appropriated $700 billion for the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) on 3 October 2008, which allowed the Treasury to inject equity into failing financial institutions.Footnote 77 Consequently—between the liquidity facility, lending programs and asset purchasing programs by the Fed and the guarantees provided by the FDIC and the US Treasury—a near complete backstop was created during the crisis for the shadow banking sector.Footnote 78 In this regard Barry Eichengreen noted that ‘the failure to endow the Treasury and the Fed with the authority to deal with the insolvency of non-bank financial institutions was the single most important policy failure of the crisis’.Footnote 79

Meanwhile, Europe lacked a robust pan-European approach to failing financial institutions. National governments were left to their own devices. However, this fragmentation along national borders was not reflected by financial institutions. Benefiting from the unification of the European markets, they had stretched their operations over many countries. In 2008, panic on the financial markets culminated in a joint commitment by the EU leaders to support the major financial institutions and avoid their bankruptcy by providing sufficient liquidity, funding and capital resources.Footnote 80 As a consequence, between 2008 and 2012 national authorities spent a total of €1.5 trillion on state aid in support of the financial system.Footnote 81

Many of the financial institutions which had to be bailed out because of the systemic risk consequences—commonly referred to as Too-Big-To-Fail—were in fact non-bank financial institutions. They ranged, inter alia, from investment banks (e.g. Bear Stearns and Merrill Lynch) and insurance companies (AIG)Footnote 82 to asset managers (Reserve Primary Fund).

In conclusion, the belief that shadow banking activities did not pose systemic risks proved to be false. One of the important lessons from the Global Financial Crisis was that the failure of non-bank financial institutions can—and has—created systemic risk, especially through their interconnectedness with and contagion of the wider financial system.Footnote 83 Financial institutions which deal in bank-like risks by providing maturity and/or liquidity transformation, and high leverage are particularly susceptible to shocks. Shadow banks relied heavily (although not exclusively) on short-term liabilities for funding.Footnote 84 Short-term funding, typically through (overnight) asset-backed commercial paper and repos, requires the institution to roll over its debt when it matures. This rendered shadow banking entities vulnerable to runs on their short-term funding, equivalent to bank runs.Footnote 85 Indeed, lacking funding through insured deposits they were even more vulnerable to runs, whereby panic could easily lead to contagion.Footnote 86 Risks posed by shadow bank entities were aggravated by the fact that such institutions were only subjected to light regulation and supervision. In consequence, the belief that no fiscal backstop to the shadow banking sector was necessary proved equally false: during the crisis large publicly funded bailouts proved necessary.

While the foregoing illustrates the enormous threat posed by the shadow banking sector as exemplified during the Global Financial Crisis, it must be stressed that the financial sector is constantly changing and evolving. Specific risks which manifested themselves in the past may diminish, while other, new, risks materialise.Footnote 87 Future financial crises will probably not mirror previous crises and have different roots. It is therefore crucial to have a forward-looking system in place for identifying potential systemic risks in the financial sector. And once such risks have been identified, they must be brought within a commensurate regulatory perimeter.Footnote 88

3 International Initiatives to Address Systemic Risk Posed by Non-Bank Financial Institutions

As seen above, systemic risk is not confined to the banking system. This calls into question the notion that systemic risk can be controlled by focusing chiefly on bank regulation and supervision. Shadow banks operating outside the regulatory perimeter for banks were able to accumulate systemic risks virtually unchecked. Unlike the jurisdiction of financial supervisors, the build-up of systemic risk was not confined to particular countries or sectors. Furthermore, by focusing on the micro-prudential health, the authorities overlooked and neglected supervision of the safety of the financial system as a whole. This is not to say that the regulation and supervision of banks did not need improving, as it clearly did, but a one-sided focus on bank regulation failed to take account of the risks and consigned them to the shadow sector.

A range of international initiatives designed to increase financial stability were undertaken in response. During the G20 London summit in 2009 it was agreed, among other things, that regulators and supervisors must reduce the scope for regulatory arbitrage. To this end, regulation and oversight should extend to ‘all systemically important financial institutions, instruments and markets’.Footnote 89 A few months later, at the G20 Pittsburgh summit, the world leaders reiterated that ‘all firms whose failure could pose a risk to financial stability must be subject to consistent, consolidated supervision and regulation with high standards’.Footnote 90 It is, therefore, important to have an adequate regulatory perimeter which ensures that all financial activities and institutions that may pose systemic risk are appropriately regulated.Footnote 91 The supervision of individual financial institutions has to take into account—and be complemented by—supervision of the robustness of the financial system as a whole. This is referred to as macroprudential supervision.Footnote 92

The G20 tasked a new organ, the Financial Stability Board (FSB), with the development and coordination of a comprehensive framework for global regulation and oversight of the global financial system.Footnote 93 As part of this task, the FSB has been designing policy recommendations addressing the Too-Big-To-Fail problem of SIFIs, while at the same time preventing regulatory arbitrage as stricter regulation in one sector might lead to migration of risky activities elsewhere.Footnote 94

In order to alleviate Too-Big-To-Fail, the FSB requires a number of integrated policies comprising:

  • Resolution instruments which enable authorities to resolve financial institutions in an orderly manner.

  • Resolvability assessments and recovery and resolution planning for global systemically important financial institutions, and for the development of institution-specific cross-border cooperation agreements.

  • Requirements for financial institutions determined to be globally systemically important to have additional loss absorption capacity tailored to the impact of their default.

  • More intensive and effective supervision of all SIFIs.Footnote 95

According to the FSB, the crisis revealed that some supervisors failed to make appropriate risk assessments leading to an unwarranted assertion that institutions were highly capitalised and liquid, even as some later failed. In consequence, the FSB assessed that the supervision of SIFIs ‘must clearly be more intense, more effective, and more reliable’.Footnote 96

This resulted in a number of recommendations in regard to supervision of SIFIs, including the following:

  • National supervisory authorities should have the powers to apply differentiated supervisory requirements and intensity of supervision of SIFIs based on the risk they pose to the financial system.

  • All national supervisory authorities should have appropriate mandates, independence and resources to identify risks early and intervene to require changes within an institution, as needed, to prevent unsound practices and take appropriate counter-measures to safeguard against the additional systemic risks.

  • Jurisdictions should provide for a national supervisory framework that enables effective consolidated supervision by addressing ambiguities of responsibilities, impairments related to information gathering and assessment when multiple supervisors are overseeing the institution and its affiliates.Footnote 97

3.1 Determining Systemic Risk

Reducing the systemic and moral hazard risks posed by SIFIs starts with the identification of such institutions. For this purpose international methodologies have been created for identifying global systemically important banks (G-SIBs) and insurers (G-SIIs). Furthermore, in March 2015 the FSB and the International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) released a second consultative document regarding the assessment methodologies for identifying Non-Bank Non-Insurer Global Systemically Important Financial Institutions.Footnote 98

The latter aims to provide a framework for determining whether a non-bank non-insurer financial entity is globally systemically relevant (NBNI G-SIFI). The proposed methodologies are designed to identify NBNI financial institutions whose distress or disorderly failure, because of their size, complexity and systemic interconnectedness, would cause significant disruption to the wider financial system and economic activity at the global level.Footnote 99 Besides giving sector specific indicators, it provides basic impact factors that should be taken into account. These are a financial institution’s size, interconnectedness, substitutability, complexity and global, cross-jurisdictional, activities.

In regard to asset management activities, the FSB recently presented policy recommendations to address structural vulnerabilities from asset management activities.Footnote 100 As illustrated by the demise of Long Term Capital Management (LTCM), a leveraged hedge fund, and the run on MMFs during the 2008 crisis, asset management structures can pose systemic risk.Footnote 101 The FSB identified four important structural vulnerabilities: (i) liquidity mismatch between fund investments and redemption terms and conditions for open-ended funds;Footnote 102 (ii) leverage; (iii) operational risk and challenges in transferring investment mandates in stressed conditions; (iv) securities lending activities of asset managers and funds.

Besides developing NBNI G-SIFI methodology and making sector-specific recommendations, the FSB has provided a framework for the detection of elevated systemic risk posed by non-bank entities. To this end, it proposes a two-pronged strategy, entailing (1) enhanced monitoring and (2) strengthening of oversight and regulation.Footnote 103 The FSB finds that, when necessary to ensure financial stability, relevant authorities should have the power to bring non-bank financial entities into regulatory and supervisory oversight. Therefore authorities should, as a key prerequisite, have a regime to define, expand, and keep up to date the regulatory perimeter necessary to ensure financial stability.Footnote 104

3.1.1 Monitoring Non-Bank Financial Entities That Could Pose Financial Stability Risks

The FSB has adopted a monitoring framework designed to identify the build-up of systemic risks in the shadow banking system. It provides both for a wide-net approach, which captures all non-bank credit intermediation, and a narrow approach. The latter allows authorities to focus on the subset of non-bank credit intermediation where there are (i) developments that increase systemic risk (in particular maturity/liquidity transformation, imperfect credit risk transfer and/or leverage), and/or (ii) indications of regulatory arbitrage that is undermining the benefits of financial regulation.Footnote 105

The monitoring of systemic risk must take an risk-based approach in which the extent of a firm’s involvement in shadow banking has to be judged by its underlying economic activities, rather than legal names or forms.Footnote 106 This is especially relevant as any non-bank financial institution could perform shadow banking activities.Footnote 107 Such a functional approach allows for a consistent assessment of shadow banking activities and the risk they pose to financial stability. It allows new structures and innovations to fall within the monitoring scope. A comparable approach is present in the FSB’s classification of non-bank financial entities into five different economic functions (see Table 1).

Table 1 Classification by economic functions.

The FSB finds that jurisdictions should establish a systematic process involving all relevant domestic authorities in order to review shadow banking risks posed by non-bank financial entities or activities, and ensure that any entities or activities that could pose material risks to financial stability are brought within the regulatory perimeter.Footnote 108 However, in its 2016 thematic review the FSB finds that few jurisdictions have such a systemic process in place. It recommends that, where such a process does not exist, there ‘may be merit for jurisdictions to establish a systematic process to ensure that non-bank financial entities that could pose financial stability risks are brought within the regulatory perimeter in a timely and proactive manner’.Footnote 109

The US is an example of a jurisdiction which does have in place a systematic process for reviewing the regulatory perimeter and bringing non-bank financial companies within (additional) regulatory and supervisory oversight. The US system will be discussed in more detail in Sect. 4 below.

3.2 Regulating Non-Bank Systemically Important Financial Institutions

As stated previously, while shadow bank entities might create systemic risk on their own, risks may also emerge indirectly through the interconnectedness of the shadow and regular banking sectors. Indeed, shadow banks tend to be closely connected with the regulated banking sector due to ownership linkages and explicit and implicit guarantees and as direct counterparties.Footnote 110 For example, the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) assesses that approximately 9% of the euro area credit institutions’ assets are loans to the euro area investment funds and Other Financial Institutions (OFI), or debt securities, equity and investment fund shares issued by those entities. Conversely, deposits from euro area investment funds and OFI constitute 7% of credit institution’ liabilities.Footnote 111

Regulatory response has thus developed broadly along two, not mutually exclusive, lines. First, efforts have been made to impose regulatory limits on the exposure of the traditional banking sector to the shadow banking sector. And, second, efforts are made to expand the regulatory perimeter to capture non-bank financial institutions.

In regard to the former, the Basel Committee for Banking Supervision has issued a final standard which sets out a supervisory framework for measuring and controlling large exposures.Footnote 112 The Basel exposure framework aims to serve as a backstop to risk-based capital requirements, as it should ensure that the maximum possible loss a bank could incur if a single counterparty or group of connected counterparties were to suddenly fail would not endanger the bank’s survival. In effect, this means that the total exposure of a bank to a single counterparty or to a group of connected counterparties must not exceed 25% of the bank’s total amount of Tier 1 capital.Footnote 113 Jurisdictions must implement the large exposure framework in full by 1 January 2019.

In the EU, limits to large exposures are specified in the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR), which by and large matches the Basel exposure framework.Footnote 114 Additionally, the CCR mandates the European Banking Authority (EBA) to provide guidelines for setting appropriate aggregate limits on shadow banking exposures or tighter individual limits on exposures to shadow banking entities which carry out banking activities outside a regulated framework. In its consultation paper on its draft guidelines, the EBA recognised that the Global Financial Crisis ‘has revealed previously unrecognised fault lines which can transmit risk from the shadow banking system to the regulated banking system, putting the stability of the entire financial system at risk’.Footnote 115 In its final guidelines, which came into effect on 1 January 2017, the EBA requires banks and investment firms to identify their individual exposures to shadow banking entities and the potential risks and the impact of those risks arising from these exposures.Footnote 116 These risks must, subsequently, be taken into account within the institution’s Internal Capital Adequacy Assessment Process (ICAAP) and capital planning.

In regard to step-in risks—i.e. financial support granted by a bank to a troubled non-bank financial entity, beyond any contractual obligations—the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision has published a consultative document on guidelines for the identification and management of such risks.Footnote 117

3.2.1 Non-Bank SIFI Regulation

In regard to the expansion of the regulatory perimeter to ensure that it encompasses non-bank financial institutions and activities that could pose financial stability risks, the FSB has developed policy recommendations for strengthening the oversight and regulation of shadow banking sectors.Footnote 118

The FSB presents a policy framework, consisting of overarching principles that authorities should apply for all economic functions and a specific toolkit for each economic function, in order to mitigate systemic risks posed by a shadow banking entity associated with its specific economic function (see Table 2).Footnote 119

Table 2 Most commonly reported policy tools to address shadow banking risks (by EF).

After being tasked by the G20 with addressing Too-Big-To-Fail problems, the FSB also produced a number of policy recommendations designed to reduce the chance of failure of financial institutions and minimise the impact of any such failure. Of primary importance are its Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions (KA), which set out the core elements that the FSB considers necessary for an effective resolution regime.

The FSB recommends that any financial institution that could be systemically significant or critical if it fails should be subject to a resolution regime. Resolution should be initiated when a financial institution is no longer viable or likely to be no longer viable, and when it has no reasonable prospect of becoming viable again.

Effective resolution regimes should, according to the FSB:

  1. (i)

    ensure continuity of systemically important financial services, and payment, clearing and settlement functions;

  2. (ii)

    protect, where applicable and in coordination with the relevant insurance schemes and arrangements, such depositors, insurance policy holders and investors as are covered by such schemes and arrangements, and ensure the rapid return of segregated client assets;

  3. (iii)

    allocate losses to firm owners (shareholders) and unsecured and uninsured creditors in a manner that respects the hierarchy of claims;

  4. (iv)

    not rely on public solvency support and not create an expectation that such support will be available;

  5. (v)

    avoid unnecessary destruction of value, and therefore seek to minimise the overall costs of resolution in home and host jurisdictions and, where consistent with the other objectives, losses for creditors;

  6. (vi)

    provide for speed and transparency and as much predictability as possible through legal and procedural clarity and advanced planning for orderly resolution;

  7. (vii)

    provide a mandate in law for cooperation, information exchange and coordination domestically and with relevant foreign resolution authorities before and during a resolution;

  8. (viii)

    ensure that non-viable firms can exit the market in an orderly way; and

  9. (ix)

    be credible, and thereby enhance market discipline and provide incentives for market-based solutions.Footnote 120

4 Policy Response in the United States—Systemic Risk Regulation

This section discusses some notable regulatory reforms in the US in relation to the identification and subsequent regulation and supervision of non-bank systemically important financial institutions. The US practice can provide valuable insights for possible European reform along the same or similar lines.

As illustrated in Sect. 2, systemic risk in the US manifested itself not only in the traditional banking sector but also to a significant degree in the shadow banking sector. Activities in the lightly regulated shadow banking sector—e.g. investment banks and money market funds—proved the most damaging. The combination of high leverage and the dependence on short-term (overnight) funding to finance long-term investments rendered non-bank financial institutions susceptible to modern bank runs. The withdrawal of funds, or refusal to roll over existing debt, forced fire sales, which led to a further decline in asset prices. As asset prices deteriorated, the solvency of other financial institutions holding similar assets became uncertain, freezing short-term funding and leading to additional fire sales.Footnote 121

The main regulatory response of the crisis was the Dodd–Frank Act, which was signed into law by President Obama on 21 July 2010. Its chief goal was to address the issues of financial stability and systemic risk and to prevent further bailouts of the financial system at the taxpayers’ expense.Footnote 122 The Dodd–Frank Act applies a more risk-based approach to the identification and regulation of non-bank SIFIs in two notable ways. First, by introducing a Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC), a new federal regulator, charged with monitoring systemic risk and determining what non-bank financial institutions could pose a threat to the financial stability of the US. Second, it creates a resolution regime for non-bank financial institutions whose failure poses a significant risk to the financial stability of the US. Both reforms are discussed in the following sections.

4.1 Designation by the Financial Stability Oversight Council

In general, the FSOC has two main tasks. First, to identify risks to the financial stability of the US emanating from non-bank financial institutions. Second, to respond to emerging threats to the stability of the United States financial system.Footnote 123

The FSOC is charged with determining whether a non-bank financial companyFootnote 124 is systemically important.Footnote 125 The designation may be made by an affirmative vote of at least two-third of the FSOC’s voting members, including the Chairperson. In consequence, a designated company is supervised by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (FRB) and is subject to the prudential standards set in Title I of the Dodd–Frank Act.

More specifically, a designation may be made under either of two determination standards: (i) when material financial distress at the company could pose a threat to the financial stability of the US; or (ii) when the very ‘nature, scope, size, scale, concentration, interconnectedness, or mix’ of the company’s activities could pose the same threat.Footnote 126

Industry practitioners, commenting on the scope of the FSOC’s non-bank SIFI determination, found that the particular segment of the financial industry they represented does not pose a threat to US financial stability and should not generally be subject to a determination.Footnote 127 The FSOC, however, contended that it does not intend to provide industry-based exemptions from potential non-bank SIFI determinations. Instead it will apply the statutory standards to determine whether a non-bank financial company qualifies as systemically important.Footnote 128 The Dodd–Frank Act identified ten factors that the FSOC must consider when determining whether material financial distress at a non-bank financial company could pose a threat to the US economy.

  1. (A)

    the extent of the leverage of the company;

  2. (B)

    the extent and nature of the off-balance-sheet exposures of the company;

  3. (C)

    the extent and nature of the transactions and relationships of the company with other significant non-bank financial companies and significant bank holding companies;

  4. (D)

    the importance of the company as a source of credit for households, businesses, and State and local governments and as a source of liquidity for the United States financial system;

  5. (E)

    the importance of the company as a source of credit for low-income, minority, or underserved communities, and the impact that the failure of such company would have on the availability of credit in such communities;

  6. (F)

    the extent to which assets are managed rather than owned by the company, and the extent to which ownership of assets under management is diffuse;

  7. (G)

    the nature, scope, size, scale, concentration, interconnectedness, and mix of the activities of the company;

  8. (H)

    the degree to which the company is already regulated by 1 or more primary financial regulatory agencies;

  9. (I)

    the amount and nature of the financial assets of the company;

  10. (J)

    the amount and types of the liabilities of the company, including the degree of reliance on short-term funding; and

  11. (K)

    any other risk-related factors that the Council deems appropriate.

The FSOC adopted a final rule and interpretive guidance for non-bank financial company determinations, in which it grouped all factors relevant to the risk determination in six categories.Footnote 129 These six categories, referred to as the ‘analytic framework for determinations’, are: (i) size, (ii) interconnectedness, (iii) substitutability, (iv) leverage, (v) liquidity risk and maturity mismatch, and (vi) existing regulatory scrutiny. Three of these six categories—size, substitutability and interconnectedness—aim to assess the potential impact of the non-bank financial company’s financial distress on the broader economy. The purpose of the other three—leverage, liquidity risk and maturity mismatch, and existing regulatory scrutiny of the non-bank financial company—is to assess the vulnerability of a company to financial distress.

In its Rule and Guidance, the FSOC developed a three-stage process for identifying non-bank financial companies for determination under non-emergency situations.Footnote 130 In stage 1, the FSOC applies six quantitative thresholds to a broad group of non-bank financial companies to identify companies that will be subject to further evaluation by the Council.

4.1.1 Stage 1

First, a financial company has to have at least $50 billion in total consolidated assets. Additionally it has to meet at least one of the following thresholds:

  • $30 billion in credit default swaps for which the company is the reference entity;

  • $3.5 billion in derivative liabilities;

  • $20 billion in total debt outstanding;

  • 15 to 1 leverage ratio;

  • 10% short-term debt-to-asset ratio.

Companies that have passed the first stage are subject to active review by the FSOC in stage 2. Additionally, a non-bank financial company which does not meet the thresholds of the first stage may still be subjected to a stage 2 analysis by the FSOC based on other firm-specific qualitative or quantitative factors. After all, the uniform quantitative thresholds may not capture all types of non-bank financial companies and all of the potential ways in which a non-bank financial company could pose a threat to financial stability.Footnote 131

4.1.2 Stage 2

In stage 2, the FSOC, conducts a robust analysis of the potential threat that a company could pose to US financial stability. In contrast to the application of uniform criteria under stage 1, stage 2 evaluates the risk profile and characteristics of each individual non-bank financial company. This in line with the belief that systemically important designation cannot be reduced to a formula.Footnote 132 This review is performed on the basis of a company’s: (i) size, (ii) interconnectedness, (iii) substitutability, (iv) leverage, (v) liquidity risk and maturity mismatch, and (vi) existing regulatory scrutiny. It is interesting to note that a key factor of the determination is the extent to which the non-bank financial company is subject to regulation. This shows that the designation process actively aims to remedy gaps in regulation and counteracts regulatory arbitrage and thus draws systemically important shadow banks within the regulatory perimeter.

4.1.3 Stage 3

Companies that are subsequently advanced to stage 3 are informed through a ‘Notice of Consideration’ that they are being considered for a ‘Proposed Determination’. Review under stage 3 focuses on the non-bank financial company’s potential to pose a threat to US financial stability because of the company’s material financial distress or the nature, scope, size, scale, concentration, interconnectedness or mix of its activities. The Notice of Consideration will likely include a request for information deemed relevant to the FSOC’s evaluation. The information necessary may vary significantly based on the non-bank financial company’s business and activities and the information already available. However, the information requests will likely involve both qualitative and quantitative data.

The FSOC indicates that an information request may include confidential business information.Footnote 133 The additional information helps the FSOC to gain a complete image of the systemic risk posed by a company. Factors such the opacity of the non-bank financial company’s operations, its complexity, and the extent to which it is subject to existing regulatory scrutiny and the nature of such scrutiny, may not directly cause systemic risks but could mitigate or aggravate them.

Additionally, the FSOC makes an in-depth analysis of the resolvability of the company. This entails assessing the complexity of the non-bank company’s legal, funding, and operational structure, and any obstacles to the rapid and orderly resolution of the company.

Based on the analyses conducted in stages 2 and 3, a non-bank financial company may be considered for a Proposed Determination. The FSOC may, by a vote of two-thirds of its members (including an affirmative vote of the Council Chairperson), make a Proposed Determination with respect to a non-bank financial company. After the company has been notified of its proposed determination and given the chance to contest it through a non-public hearing, the FSOC will determine by a vote of two-thirds of its voting members whether or not to subject such a company to supervision by the FRB and the prudential standards from Title 1 of the Dodd-Frank Act.

The FSOC designated American International Group (AIG), General Electric Capital Corporation, Prudential Financial and MetLife to be non-bank financial companies whose material financial distress could pose a threat to US financial stability. Metlife successfully appealed its designation in first instance, with an appeal still pending.Footnote 134 The designation of GE Capital Global Holdings was rescinded by the FSOC on 28 June 2016 after it fundamentally changed its business.Footnote 135 Additionally, the FSOC designated eight financial market utilities as systemically important. Recently, the FSOC started considering asset managers for systemic designation.Footnote 136

4.1.4 Judicial Protection against Designation

Following a Proposed Determination, the FSOC provides a written notice of the Proposed Determination to the non-bank financial company. This includes an explanation of the basis of the Proposed Determination. A non-bank financial company that is subject to a Proposed Determination may, within 30 days of receiving any notice of a proposed determination, request a non-public hearing to contest the Proposed Determination.Footnote 137 The FSOC must notify the company of its final determination within 60 days after the hearing.

The company subjected to a final determination may, within 30 days after receiving the notice of final determination, bring an action in the United States district court for the judicial district in which the company’s home office is located, or in the United States District Court for the District of Columbia, for an order requiring that the final determination be rescinded. The court’s review is limited to determining whether the final determination was arbitrary and capricious.

American insurance company Metlife brought such proceedings before the US District Court of Columbia, complaining inter alia that the FSOC had not followed its own regulations in designating Metlife as a non-bank SIFI and had failed to examine the costs of its designation.

The judicial review by reference to the arbitrary and capricious criterion is narrow as the court is not able to substitute its judgment for that of the agency.Footnote 138 It may only therefore consider ‘whether the decision was based on a consideration of the relevant factors and whether there has been a clear error of judgment’.Footnote 139 This does mean, however, that the court must consider whether an agency has engaged in reasoned decision-making and has not departed from a prior policy or disregarded its own rules.

Applying this test led the District Court of Colombia to conclude that

FSOC made critical departures from two of the standards it adopted in its Guidance, never explaining such departures or even recognizing them as such. That alone renders FSOC’s determination process fatally flawed. Additionally, FSOC purposefully omitted any consideration of the cost of designation to MetLife. Thus, FSOC assumed the upside benefits of designation (even without specific standards from the Federal Reserve) but not the downside costs of its decision. That is arbitrary and capricious under the latest Supreme Court precedent.Footnote 140

Subsequently, on 30 March 2016, the Supreme Court quashed the FSOC’s designation of Metlife as a non-bank SIFI.

4.2 Supervision of Non-Bank SIFIs

The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (FRB) is tasked with the primary supervision of systemically important financial institutions.Footnote 141 This includes all bank holding companies with a minimum of $50 billion in assets and all non-bank financial companies which have been designated as systemically important by the FSOC.Footnote 142 The FRB is tasked with establishing enhanced prudential standards for non-bank financial companies which are deemed systemically important.Footnote 143

The FRB may establish such enhanced prudential standards on its own initiative or after a recommendation of the FSOC.Footnote 144 The prudential standards developed by the FRB may differentiate between institutions on an individual or categorical basis, thus allowing for the creation of tailored prudential requirements.Footnote 145 The FRB may, therefore, take into consideration the capital structure, riskiness, complexity, financial activities (including the financial activities of their subsidiaries), size, and any other risk-related factors of the financial institution that the FRB deems appropriate. Such a flexible approach to regulation is warranted given the differences in business model and risks between, for instance, insurers and banks. The prudential standards developed by the FRB includes (i) risk-based capital requirements and leverage limits; (ii) liquidity requirements; (iii) overall risk management requirements; (iv) resolution plan and credit exposure report requirements; and (v) concentration limits.Footnote 146

The FRB may establish additional prudential standards for non-bank financial companies that include (i) a contingent capital requirement; (ii) enhanced public disclosures; (iii) short-term debt limits; and (iv) such other prudential standards as the FRB, on its own or pursuant to a recommendation made by the FSOC, determines are appropriate.Footnote 147

In the summer of 2016 the FRB issued an advance notice of proposed rulemaking regarding approaches to regulatory capital requirements for depository institution holding companies significantly engaged in insurance activities, and non-bank financial companies determined by the FSOC that have significant insurance activities.Footnote 148 In regard to FSOC designated nonbank financial companies with significant insurance activities—as discussed these are currently AIG and Prudential Financial—the advanced notice proposes a categorization of the insurance firm’s assets and insurance liabilities into risk segments and determine the consolidated required capital by applying risk factors to the amounts in each segment.Footnote 149

4.2.1 Living Wills

The Dodd–Frank Act provides that (i) each non-bank financial company designated by the FSOC as systemically important and supervised by the FRB and (ii) bank holding companies with consolidated assets amounting to a minimum of $50bn, periodically have to provide the FRB, FSOC and the FDIC with a plan for their rapid and orderly resolution in the event of material financial distress or failure.Footnote 150 These resolution plans, commonly known as ‘living wills’, include:

  1. (A)

    information regarding the manner and extent to which any insured depository institution affiliated with the company is adequately protected from risks arising from the activities of any non-bank subsidiaries of the company.

  2. (B)

    full descriptions of the ownership structure, assets, liabilities, and contractual obligations of the company;

  3. (C)

    identification of the cross-guarantees tied to different securities, identification of major counterparties, and a process for determining to whom the collateral of the company is pledged; and

  4. (D)

    any other information that the Board of Governors and the Corporation jointly require by rule or order.Footnote 151

On 17 October 2011 the FRB approved a joint rule with the FDIC, implementing the resolution plan requirements of the Dodd-Frank Act.Footnote 152 The rule requires covered firms to perform a strategic analysis of how they can be resolved under the Bankruptcy Code in a way that would not pose systemic risk to the financial system.Footnote 153

A key goal of the actions required in order to prepare a living will is the reduction of the interconnectedness between legal entities within a firm as ‘the inability to resolve one legal entity without causing knock-on effects that may propel the failure of other legal entities within the firm makes the orderly resolution of one of these firms extremely problematic’.Footnote 154 This does not necessarily imply that firms, under the living will obligation, have to break up, but, as Thomas Hoenig, vice chairman of the FDIC put it, ‘we want you to structure yourself so that your failure doesn’t bring the economy down next time’ and ‘If you can’t get to that point with your current organization structure, then you should sell assets to get to that state’.Footnote 155

Resolution plans will support the FDIC by providing an understanding of the covered companies’ structure and complexity as well as their resolution strategies and processes. Additionally, they will assist the FRB in its supervisory task to ensure that covered companies operate in a manner that is both safe and sound and that does not pose risks to financial stability. Finally, the resolution plans enhance the understanding of the US operations of foreign banks resulting in a more comprehensive and coordinated resolution strategy for a cross-border firm.Footnote 156

The living wills are reviewed by the FRB and the FDIC. They may jointly determine that a living will is not credible or would not facilitate an orderly resolution of the company concerned under the Bankruptcy Code. In such a case, the financial institution, after being notified by the FRB and the FDIC, has to resubmit a plan that remedies the deficiencies. If the firm fails to resubmit a credible plan, the FRB and the FDIC may jointly impose restrictions and requirements on the firm or its subsidiaries until it resubmits a plan that remedies the deficiencies. They may require more stringent capital, leverage, or liquidity ratios or restrict growth, activities, or operations.Footnote 157 If the firm fails to resubmit a revised resolution plan within 2 years after being required to fulfil additional requirements, the FRB and the FDIC, in consultation with the FSOC, may jointly order the firm to divest assets or operations to facilitate an orderly resolution under the Bankruptcy Code.

4.3 Resolution of Non-Bank SIFIs under OLA

While living wills are intended to identify and remove obstacles to orderly resolution under the Bankruptcy Code, in practice systemically important financial institutions, including bank holding companies, qualify for resolution under the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA).Footnote 158

Since the passing of the Dodd-Frank Act, the US has had three main regimes for resolving financial institutions. A general insolvency regime is provided for by the Bankruptcy Code. However, insured depository institutions (i.e. banks) are excluded from the Bankruptcy Code. Instead they are subjected to a specialised regime under federal law.Footnote 159 The Federal Deposit Insurance Company (FDIC) is charged with the application of this regime.

The Dodd–Frank Act also established the Orderly Liquidation Authority, which presents an alternative resolution regime for non-bank financial institutions, including bank holding companies. The OLA provide a liquidation regime for covered financial institutions in a manner that mitigates risks to financial stability and minimises moral hazard.Footnote 160 While, in principle, the Bankruptcy Code remains the default option, resolution under the OLA regime is preferred when normal bankruptcy proceedings would potentially harm financial stability.

The OLA applies to financial institutions that are (i) domestic bank holding companies, (ii) non-bank financial companies supervised by the FRB, (iii) any domestic company predominantly engaged in activities that the FRB has determined are financial in nature or incidental thereto, and (iv) any subsidiary of such companies that is predominantly engaged in activities that are financial in nature or incidental thereto (other than a subsidiary that is an insured depository institution or an insurance company).Footnote 161 Consequently, financial institutions that have been designated as systemically important by the FSOC fall within the meaning of ‘financial company’ under the OLA as they are supervised by the FRB.

Furthermore, in order for a financial company to become ‘covered’ by the OLA the following conditions must be met:Footnote 162

  1. 1.

    in default or in danger of default;

  2. 2.

    the failure of the financial company and its resolution under otherwise applicable Federal or State law would have serious adverse effects on financial stability in the United States;

  3. 3.

    no viable private sector alternative is available;

  4. 4.

    any effect on the claims or interests of creditors, counterparties, and shareholders of the financial company and other market participants as a result of actions to be taken under this subchapter is appropriate, given the impact that any action taken under this subchapter would have on financial stability in the United States;

  5. 5.

    any action under OLA would avoid or mitigate such adverse effects;Footnote 163

  6. 6.

    a Federal regulatory agency has ordered the financial company to convert all of its convertible debt instruments that are subject to the regulatory order.

These determinations are made by the Secretary of Treasury, acting in consultation with the President and after receiving recommendations from the FRB and the FDIC or (in the case of a broker or dealer) the FRB and the SEC. Pursuant to a determination, a financial company may be placed under OLA in order to liquidate it in a manner that mitigates significant risk to the financial stability of the US and minimises moral hazard.

Under an OLA resolution, the FDIC must act as the receiver for the company. It therefore succeeds to all rights and powers of the covered financial company. The FDIC will operate, and conduct all business of, the financial company during its orderly liquidation. It may also appoint itself as receiver of any failing domestic covered subsidiary of the financial company if this would avoid or mitigate adverse effects on the financial stability and such action would facilitate the orderly liquidation of the covered financial company.

4.3.1 Resolution Under OLA

With the introduction of OLA, the treatment of qualified financial contracts has been subject to a different treatment than under normal bankruptcy. Qualified financial contracts (QFCs) are any securities contract, commodity contract, forward contract, repurchase agreement and swap agreement, and any agreement deemed similar by the FDIC.Footnote 164 Normally a financial companies’ default triggers ‘safe harbour’ provisions enabling counterparties to terminate derivative contracts and take the collateral. This can accelerate its decline and lead to value destruction, as counterparties race to terminate derivative contracts with the failing institution.Footnote 165

However, under OLA safe harbour provisions, specifically the right to terminate, liquidate or net a QFC may not be exercised during one business day after the FDIC has been appointed receiver.Footnote 166 Furthermore, walkaway clauses—which suspend, condition, or extinguish a payment obligation—are rendered unenforceable.Footnote 167 This gives the FDIC some time to find a third-party buyer for these contracts. According to the FDIC, this provides market certainty and stability and preserves the value represented by the contracts.Footnote 168

A ‘top-down’ approach to resolution is applied, whereby the top of the financial group (i.e. the parent company level) is placed into receivership and resolution powers are applied by a single resolution authority at this level. The OLA provides the FDIC with the power to merge a company with another company or transfer any asset or liability to another company or a new FSOC-created bridge financial company.Footnote 169 The FDIC does not need to obtain approval for its resolution actions, except approval under antitrust law when it concerns a merger.

Transfer of specific assets and liabilities to a bridge financial company may be used to separate ‘good’ from ‘bad’ assets. Assets such as investments in subsidiaries would be transferred to the bridge company. Through capitalisation of the bridge financial company, by issuing new debt and equity or temporary operating funding from the FDIC,Footnote 170 it will be able to provide support to its subsidiaries, thereby ensuring that they can continue operations. The status as bridge company terminates, barring earlier termination, at the latest after 2 years, with the possibility of an extension for no more than three additional one-year periods.Footnote 171

Left behind in the failed parent company are the bad assets together with equity, subordinated debt and senior unsecured debt. Claims against the receivership are paid according to a statutory priority.Footnote 172 At the minimum all creditors must receive at least the amount that they would have received if the FDIC had the company been liquidated under Chapter 7 of the Bankruptcy Code. Creditor’s claims in the receivership are satisfied by the issuance of securities representing debt and equity in the new holding company.Footnote 173 Such a securities-for-claims exchange, has the effect of what is commonly referred to as a bail-in and ensures that the new operations are well capitalized.Footnote 174

4.4 First Experiences with Non-bank SIFI Designation in the US

As previously mentioned, on 8 July 2013 the FSOC designated American International Group (AIG), General Electric Capital Corporation, Prudential Financial and MetLife as non-bank financial companies which could pose a threat to US financial stability.

After the FSOC’s designation of GE Capital, the latter fundamentally changed its business. From being one of the largest financial services companies in the United States and a significant source of credit to the US economy, it decreased its total assets by over 50%, moved away from short-term funding and reduced its interconnectedness with large financial institutions.Footnote 175 Moreover, it repelled its US depository institutions and no longer provides financing to consumers or small business customers in the United States. As a consequence the FSOC voted on June 28, 2016 to rescind GE Capital’s non-bank SIFI designation.

It seems that the FSOC’s designation of GE Capital had the positive effect of pulling a shadow banking entity within a suitable regulatory perimeter. Where it had earlier gained an advantage through regulatory arbitrage, this was offset by its designation. In consequence, it had the choice to either compete on a level-playing-field and be subjected to stricter oversight, capital/liquidity requirements, or restructure in such a manner that it no longer posed a systemic risk. GE Capital chose to do the latter. It should therefore be regarded as an early success of the Dodd-Franks designation regime as it pulled this shadow banking entity within the regulatory perimeter and effectively alleviated systemic risks.

Metlife’s successful appeal of its designation illustrates the importance of an effective judicial appeal possibility. While the authority in charge of designating non-bank SIFIs needs broad discretionary powers to identify and regulate systemic risk, its decisions must adhere to general principles of law in order to avoid the appearance of arbitrary decision-making.

In regard to future developments, it is interesting to note that the FSOC has adopted an open approach in order to address systemic risk wherever it might arise. Treasury Secretary Jacob J. Lew emphasised in a Wall Street Journal op-ed that ‘It is particularly important that FSOC look over the horizon to where future risks may develop’.Footnote 176 Interestingly, the FSOC is now in the process of examining whether asset managers might present risks that could threaten financial stability.Footnote 177 However, as stated previously, the Trump administration seems to prefer light-touch regulation.Footnote 178

5 Policy Response in the EU

As discussed in the previous section, the FSOC’s powers to designate a non-bank institution as systemically important and the possibility to liquidate financial institutions under the OLA mark the adoption of a more holistic approach to the identification and mitigation of the systemic risks posed by non-bank SIFIs. In the EU, the policy response to the global financial crisis and the European sovereign debt crisis has remained organised largely along sectoral lines. The most notable reform has been the creation of a European Banking Union (EBU) which entailed an extensive overhaul and transfer of bank supervision and resolution to the EU level.Footnote 179 Because the creation of the Banking Union is the single most important response to the manifestation of systemic risk in the eurozone, a short account of its institutional make-up and scope, especially in relation to shadow banking entities, is in order. This will also allow us to assess the feasibility of expanding its scope to capture systemically important shadow banking entities.

5.1 The European Banking Union

The European focus on the banks can be understood against the backdrop of the euro specific sovereign debt crisis. European governments were confronted with banks that held more debt on their balance-sheets than their gross domestic product (GDP). Large-scale government bailouts created a colossal financial burden, consequently propelling debt-to-GDP ratios.Footnote 180 As European banks are prone to hold large amounts of debt from their national governments, any deterioration of the state’s financial position consequently erodes banks’ solvency and vice versa. Lacking a supranational resolution framework and a common fiscal backstop, states remained individually responsible for bailing-out banks headquartered in their territory.Footnote 181 This burdened their finances, leading to stress on the sovereign-bond markets which, in turn, led to a deterioration in the value of the bank’s assets.Footnote 182 At the same time, indebted governments came to rely even more on financing from domestic banks.Footnote 183 This has created an interdependence between the two, with any deterioration of the one impairing the position of the other, a situation ominously referred to as the bank-sovereign ‘doom loop’.Footnote 184

Consequently, a credible resolution framework for banks is crucial in order to provide a viable alternative to bailouts and a cross-border distribution of related costs. Indeed, shifting the burden of failing banks away from national budgets to the European level is often cited as the true raison d’etre of the European Banking Union (EBU).Footnote 185 Such a regime would, together with European supervision of the largest banks, help to break the feedback loop between sovereigns and banks. Ideally, it should also do so by providing a credible alternative to the dreaded, public-funded, bailouts. It is therefore no surprise that the Euro Area Summit Statement of 29 June 2012 proclaimed ‘that it is imperative to break the vicious circle between banks and sovereigns’. In the same statement, the Commission was tasked with presenting ‘proposals on the basis of Article 127(6) for a single supervisory mechanism’.Footnote 186

5.1.1 Scope of the Single Supervisory Mechanism

The first pillar of the European Banking Union is the Single Supervisory Mechanism.Footnote 187 It should be noted that the SSM is a mechanism not a supervisory entity.Footnote 188 It is not an agency, nor does it have legal personality. At its heart lies the ECB, which is directly responsible for the prudential supervision of significant credit institutions and for the effective and consistent functioning of the SSM.Footnote 189 National authorities remain primarily responsible for the supervision of less significant credit institutions.

The scope of the SSM is limited to the prudential supervision of credit institutions, financial holding companies and, subject to certain conditions, mixed financial holding companies.Footnote 190 Additionally, branches established in participating Member States of credit institutions established in non-participating Member States are included in the SSM supervision.Footnote 191

For a definition of ‘credit institution’ the SSM Regulation refers to the Capital Requirement Regulation (CRR). According to the CRR definition a credit institution is ‘an undertaking the business of which is to take deposits or other repayable funds from the public and to grant credits for its own account’.Footnote 192 The key terms ‘deposits’, ‘other repayable funds’, ‘from the public’ and ‘grant credits’ are not defined in the CRR. Nor is there any uniform approach to ‘credit institution’ in the Member States. Consequently, the interpretation of credit institution may differ from one Member State to another.Footnote 193 As long ago as 2009, the de Larosière Report pointed out that differences in the definition of credit institutions are a source of problematic divergences between members that can lead to laxer supervision and regulatory arbitrage. This problem has also been noted by the Commission, which has tasked the European Banking Authority (EBA) with giving an opinion on the perimeter of ‘credit institution’. It is hoped that this opinion will lead to a delegated act of the Commission defining the exact perimeter of credit institutions.Footnote 194

Other financial institutions are, explicitly or implicitly, beyond the scope of application of the SSM. As made clear by Article 127(6) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), insurance undertakings are in any event excluded from the SSM. Central Clearing Counterparties (CCPs) are likewise excluded from the SSM if they do not also qualify as credit institution.Footnote 195 Other market infrastructure facilities such as multilateral trading facilities only fall under the SSM regime when they also participate in banking activities.

The exclusion of market infrastructure, insurers, investment firms and other shadow banking entities is puzzling from the perspective of financial stability. The global financial crisis clearly demonstrated their potential to pose a threat to the stability of the financial system.Footnote 196 The limited scope of the Banking Union appears to be primarily motivated by legal limitations and policy makers’ priority of breaking the vicious circle between banks and sovereigns.Footnote 197 Legal limitations arise from Article 127(6) TFEU, which allows for the conferral of specific tasks upon the European Central Bank concerning policies relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and other financial institutions, with the explicit exception of insurance undertakings.

However, non-bank financial institutions are not completely unaffected by supervision under the SSM. The ECB is charged with supervision on a consolidated basis of credit institutions, financial holding companies and mixed financial holding companies that are significant on a consolidated basis, where the parent undertaking is an EU parent institution established in a participating Member State.Footnote 198 As consolidated supervisor and in cooperation with the supervisor of subsidiaries, it has to reach a joint decision on the adequacy of the consolidated level of own funds and liquidity requirements.Footnote 199

A financial holding company is a financial institutionFootnote 200 the subsidiaries of which are exclusively or mainly institutions (i.e. credit institutions or investment firms)Footnote 201 or financial institutions, at least one of such subsidiaries being an institution, and which is not a mixed financial holding company. A mixed financial holding company means a parent undertaking, other than a regulated entity,Footnote 202 which, together with its subsidiaries—at least one of which is a regulated entity which has its registered office in the Union—and other entities, constitutes a financial conglomerate.Footnote 203

5.1.2 Scope of the Single Resolution Mechanism

The second pillar of the European Banking Union constitutes the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM).Footnote 204 The SRM became fully operational on 1 January 2016 and provides for a resolution regime for banks. It places the Single Resolution Board, a newly created European agency, in charge of the decision-making on bank resolution.

Within the SRM the tasks are divided between the SRB and the national resolution authorities (NRAs). The latter are directly responsible for the resolution of non-significant entitiesFootnote 205 and non-cross-border entities and groups. The NRAs are, however, bound to apply the resolution tools referred to in the SRM Regulation.Footnote 206 To this end, the NRAs must apply resolution powers conferred on them under national law transposing the BRRD, in accordance with the conditions laid down in national law.Footnote 207 It should be pointed out that, in so far as this may lead to differences in the application of the resolution tools, for example due to divergent national implementations of the BRRD, the SRB remains responsible for the uniform and consistent application and may intervene accordingly.Footnote 208 Consequently, they do not have additional resolution powers granted under national legislation.Footnote 209

The SRM covers all credit institutions established in participating Member States, regardless of their size.Footnote 210 Also within the scope of resolution under the SRM are (i) parent undertakings subjected to consolidated supervision by the ECB, and (ii) investment firmsFootnote 211 and financial institutions, established in a participating Member State, that are covered by the ECB’s consolidated supervision of the parent.Footnote 212 These entities are brought within the scope of the SRM because—to the extent that parent undertakings, investment firms and financial institutions are included in the consolidated supervision by the ECB—the ECB will be the only supervisor that has a global perception of the risk to which a group (and indirectly its individual members) is exposed—even if it does not supervise these entities on a solo basis.Footnote 213

Resolution of a parent undertaking can take place when:

  1. (i)

    the resolution conditionsFootnote 214 are met with regard to both the financial institution and with regard to the parent undertaking subject to consolidating supervision;

  2. (ii)

    the resolution conditions are met with regard to both the parent undertaking and with regard to one or more subsidiaries which are institutions (i.e. credit institutions or investment firms);Footnote 215

  3. (iii)

    a subsidiary which is an institution meets the resolution conditions and its assets and liabilities are such that its failure threatens an institution or the group as a whole and resolution action with regard to that parent undertaking is necessary for the resolution of such subsidiaries which are institutions or for the resolution of the group as a whole;

  4. (iv)

    the insolvency law of the Member State provides that groups be treated as a whole and resolution action with regard to the parent undertaking is necessary for the resolution of such subsidiaries which are institutions or for the resolution of the group as a whole.Footnote 216

Consequently, resolution primarily focuses on and applies to credit institutions or 730k investment firms covered by consolidated supervision of the ECB. However, when the parent undertaking also meets the conditions for resolution or when economic interdependencies are such that failure of a subsidiary threatens the group as a whole, the parent can be pulled into resolution along with its subsidiary institution. At the same time, group resolution extends only to credit undertakings, parent undertakings subject to consolidated supervision of the ECB, and investment firms and financial institutions covered by the consolidated supervision of the parent undertaking (SRM entities). Other institutions within the same group are left outside the scope of resolution. Similarly, a failing subsidiary, for example an insurance undertaking, cannot trigger resolution of the group.

5.1.3 Conclusions on the Scope of the Banking Union

The Banking Union is first and foremost a mechanism which provides for the supervision and resolution of banks within the eurozone. However, its scope does extend to certain non-bank entities and groups. The SSM also captures parent undertakings which are a financial holding or mixed financial holding. The resolution mechanism also extends to 730k investment firms and financial institutions that are covered by the consolidated supervision of the parent undertaking by the ECB.

This creates a complicated legal patchwork where certain non-bank financial entities are also affected by the regime created by the Banking Union. Whether and, if so, to what extent an entity falls within the scope of the Banking Union depends on its legal classification (e.g. the perimeter or definition of credit institution) and the nature of the group to which it belongs.

The partial supervision of financial groups, which excludes solo supervision of non-bank entities within a group, but includes supervision of their parent holding, risks gaps in supervision. Similarly, resolution at group level can be triggered only if strict conditions are met, with the health of the group’s bank subsidiary being decisive. This could encourage regulatory arbitrage activities as groups might escape supervision and resolution under the Banking Union by changing the make-up of their group.

Although the Banking Union is an ambitious and vigorous overhaul of banking supervision in the eurozone, it risks being inflexible and setting a non-future proof regulatory perimeter due to the rigid scope of its application.Footnote 217

5.2 Other Sectoral Reform in the EU

Besides the European Banking Union, the European legislators have adopted numerous reform measures for the financial sector.Footnote 218 These can largely be divided into regulation, either of markets or financial institutions, and supervisory infrastructure. Both are organised mainly along sectoral lines.

5.2.1 Regulatory Reforms

Many of the regulatory reforms have, at least partially, a financial stability objective. This reduces the potential for regulatory arbitrage, at least in regard to the applicable entities. For instance, investment funds are subject to increased regulation under the ‘undertakings for collective investment in transferable securities’ (UCITS) DirectiveFootnote 219 or the Alternative Investment Fund Managers Directive (AIFMD).Footnote 220 Both directives have the effect of reducing liquidity risks in investment funds. The UCITS Directive requires investment funds to hold liquid assets only. Alternative investment funds (AIFs), other than unleveraged closed-ended AIFs, must employ appropriate liquidity management and monitoring procedures for liquidity risks.Footnote 221 The liquidity profile of the investments must comply with the AIF’s underlying obligations.

The UCITS Directive places direct restrictions on the use of leverage. A UCITS may only borrow up to 10% of its assets.Footnote 222 Additionally, synthetic leverage, which is acquired through derivatives and securities lending and measured in ‘global exposure’, must not exceed the fund’s total net asset value.Footnote 223 The AIFMD, in contrast, does not provide regulatory limits on the amount of leverage. Instead, the AIFM has to demonstrate the leverage limits set by it, for each AIF it manages, are reasonable and that it complies with them at all times. National authorities are competent to impose leverage limits on an AIF in its jurisdiction where they deem this necessary in order to ensure the stability and integrity of the financial system.Footnote 224 Furthermore, additional regulation is applicable to money-market funds to preserve the integrity and stability of the internal market.Footnote 225

In regard to the insurance sector, the EU legislator adopted the Solvency II Directive, harmonising EU insurance regulation.Footnote 226 The Solvency II Directive requires Member States to ensure that their supervisory authorities can protect policyholders and, second, to contribute to the stability of the financial system as a whole.Footnote 227 Solvency II therefore requires insurers and regulators to take account of the asset-side risks, as capital needs to be held against market risks.

However, notwithstanding the increase in sector regulation, the potential for regulatory arbitrage remains. The ESRB, for instance, notes in its 2017 shadow banking report that hedge funds should be closely monitored as they are not subject to leverage limits if regulated under the AIFMD.Footnote 228 More importantly, such an approach to financial regulation remains calibrated on ‘form over function’; in other words, the legal label of a financial institution is decisive for the applicable regulation and supervisor. In consequence, new financial market participants (e.g. FinTech entities) or formally different institutions performing similar activities may fall into regulatory gaps.Footnote 229

5.2.2 The European Supervisory Agencies

The institutional supervisory structure provided at EU level mimics the sectoral approach in regulation. The previous structure of informal cooperation and peer review arrangement at EU level, provided for in the form of the Lamfalussy Level 3 committees, have been replaced by more robust European Supervisory Agencies (ESAs). The tasks of the ESAs are delineated along sectoral, institutional lines. The ESAs consist of the European Banking Authority (EBA), the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) and the European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Authority (EIOPA). They have a dual function of harmonisation and identification of (macro) prudential risks. To this end, they draft technical standards and guidelines which are endorsed and adopted by the European Commission.Footnote 230 Of the three ESAs, currently only ESMA has direct supervisory powers over Credit Rating Agencies and Trade Repositories.Footnote 231

The governance set-up of the ESAs is, however, such that national interests are still predominant, hindering the exercise of powers in the common interests of the EU. The Board of Supervisors is the main decision-making body of each of the ESAs. The Board of Supervisors of each ESA is composed of (i) the chairperson, who has no voting rights, (ii) the heads of the national competent authorities (NCAs), all of whom have voting rights. There is also one representative each from (a) the Commission, (b) the ESRB, (c) the two other ESAs and (d) in the case of EBA, the ECB is represented. None of them has voting rights.Footnote 232 As the Commission observes in its ‘Public consultation on the operations of the European Supervisory Authorities’ of 21 March 2017:Footnote 233 ‘Experience has shown that, depending on the circumstances, this configuration may lead to conflicts of interests and may fail to deliver solutions and decisions in the best interest of the EU as a whole.’Footnote 234

It is interesting to note that the Commission, in its ESA consultation document, stated that a careful reflection about supervisory arrangements is in order, especially against the backdrop of a developing Capital Markets Union and the UK’s vote to leave the EU. Amongst other things, the Commission asked for views to help identifying specific areas where stronger European supervision would provide clear added value to overcome market fragmentation and to develop integrated capital markets, so as to ensure that risks are being appropriately regulated and supervised.Footnote 235 The Commission is therefore considering a possible extension of ESMA’s powers in the following areas: (1) in market segments in which there is a strong need to support more integrated, efficient and well-functioning financial instruments markets, (2) in areas where common solutions in the application of the EU capital market rules are more efficientFootnote 236 or (3) in areas where high integration or intense cross-border activity entails higher cross-border contagion risks to financial stability or market integrity.Footnote 237 The Commission provides three examples for a possible extension of ESMA’s current mandate: (i) direct supervision of data providers, (ii) direct supervision of the asset management industry and (iii) direct supervision of central counterparties (CCPs).

In regard to the latter, the Commission published, on 13 June 2017, proposed amendments to the European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR) and the ESMA Regulation, with a view to regulating and supervising the systemic risk posed by CCPs and strengthening the role of ESMA.Footnote 238 In order to avoid risks of regulatory and supervisory arbitrage the ‘CCP executive session’—established within the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA)—will be responsible for a more coherent and consistent supervision of CCPs. To this effect, ESMA may determine a third-country CCP to be systemically important, thereby subjecting it to stricter requirements. Acting on a recommendation from ESMA, the Commission may also determine a third-country CCP to be substantially systemically important. Subsequent to such a determination, the Commission may declare that the CCP may provide services in the Union only if it is authorised in the EU.Footnote 239 The determination of systemic importance of CCPs by ESMA shows clear parallels with our proposed non-bank SIFI determination.

In conclusion, two elements in the make-up of the European Supervisory Agencies stand out. First, despite some coordination efforts, it is based on a sectoral approach to supervision.Footnote 240 As sectoral lines increasingly blur and new institutions outside the traditional institutional regulatory perimeter perform equivalent activities, an institutionally based layout of the supervisory organisation may risk regulatory gaps. As illustrated by the crisis and described in Sect. 2, an institutional approach to financial regulation and supervision encourages regulatory arbitrage. It is therefore of eminent importance that an institutional approach to financial regulation is supplemented by the existence of an authority with robust, financial sector-wide, monitoring powers and, if deemed necessary, the power to pull systemically important financial institutions inside a suitable regulatory and supervisory perimeter. As discussed in the following section, the European Systemic Risk Board is responsible for monitoring the financial system within the EU and identifying systemic risk. Its powers, however, are rather limited.

A second important element in the functioning of the ESAs is their limited powers of direct prudential supervision of financial institutions.Footnote 241 Instead, national authorities are responsible for day-to-day prudential supervision. Systemically important institutions expand, however, across many jurisdictions. Much the same arguments that underpin the creation of direct ECB supervision over significant credit institutions therefore apply also to non-bank SIFIs. This line of reasoning is now familiar, for example because a European authority is better placed to ensure a smooth and sound overview of the entire non-bank SIFI and its overall health and would reduce the risk of different interpretations and contradictory decisions at the level of the individual entity, thereby enhancing market integration. In our proposal, designated non-bank SIFIs, like significant credit institutions, should therefore be placed under direct prudential supervision by an EU authority. The intended reforms of the ESAs may therefore provide a connection with our proposal. They illustrate a developing inclination to endow the ESAs with more direct supervisory powers. Supervision of designated non-bank SIFIs by the most relevant ESA, as determined by the nature and activities of the non-bank SIFI, is in line with these developments.

5.3 Systemic Risk Monitoring by the European Systemic Risk Board

The de Larosière Group envisaged a Union body charged with overseeing risk in the financial system as a whole.Footnote 242 This led to the creation, in November 2010, of the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB).Footnote 243 It is tasked with exercising ‘macroprudential oversight of the financial system within the Union, in order to contribute to the prevention or mitigation of systemic risks to financial stability in the Union’.Footnote 244 Its oversight has a broad scope as the ESRB Regulation recognises that all types of financial intermediaries, markets and infrastructure may potentially be systemically important to some degree.Footnote 245

As a consequence of the global financial crisis, microprudential supervision of financial institutions has become increasingly complemented by a macroprudential dimension. The latter’s objective is to limit the distress of the financial system as a whole in order to protect the overall economy from significant losses in real output.Footnote 246 Macroprudential supervision focuses on systemic risks arising from the common exposure of many financial institutions to the same risk factors. In other words, whereas microprudential supervision focuses on the tree, macroprudential supervision is all about the forest.Footnote 247 In accordance with its macroprudential tasks, the ESRB monitors and assesses risks and, if necessary, adopts warnings and recommendations.

Pursuant to its monitoring tasks the ESRB may request information from the European System of Central Banks (ESCB), the ESAs, the national supervisory authorities or the national statistics authorities. If information remains unavailable the ESRB may request it from the Member States.Footnote 248 The request may be of either a general or a specific nature and must be addressed in particular to the Union as a whole or to one or more Member States, or to one or more of the ESAs, or to one or more of the national supervisory authorities.

When the ESRB identifies significant risks to financial stability it must provide warnings and, where appropriate, issue recommendations for remedial action.Footnote 249 Warnings and recommendation may be of a general or a specific nature and must be addressed in particular to the Union as a whole or to one or more Member States, or to one or more of the ESAs, or to one or more of the national supervisory authorities.Footnote 250 As the ESRB has no formal legal powers its warnings and recommendations are non-binding, but they are subject to a ‘comply-or explain’ procedure. In consequence, addressees of recommendations have to inform the ESRB and the Council of the actions undertaken in response and must provide adequate justification for any inaction.Footnote 251 A warning or recommendation may be made public when two-thirds of the General Board agree to this.Footnote 252

The ESRB does not have legal personality or its own budget. It has a complicated organisational structure consisting of a General Board, a Steering Committee, an Advisory Technical Committee (ATC) and an Advisory Scientific Committee (ASC). The General Board is the principal decision-making body of the ESRB. Of its 67 (!) members, 38 have a voting right. These are the President and Vice-President of the ECB, the Governors of the 28 national central banks, a Member of the Commission, the Chairperson of each of the European Supervisory Authorities, the ATC Chair, the ASC Chair and the two ASC Vice-Chairs. The non-voting members consist of one representative per Member State of the competent national supervisory authorities and the President of the Economic and Financial Committee.

Since the ESRB is charged with monitoring systemic risk in the EU’s financial system, it would, logically, be best placed to perform our proposed task of designating financial institutions as ‘systemically important’, in imitation of the FSOC. To this end the ESRB’s mandate would need to be expanded, providing the ESRB with the power to adopt legally binding non-bank SIFI designation decisions. The related legal aspects are discussed in Sect. 6.3.1. The ESRB’s governance structure would also have to be streamlined as the current number of 38 voting members potentially obstructs and politicises a non-bank SIFI designation decision-making process.

6 Towards Single Supervision of Systemically Important Institutions in the EU

6.1 Addressing Systemic Risk: The Institutional Structure

As discussed in Sect. 2, the global financial crisis revealed the shortcomings of an institutionally organised supervisory model.Footnote 253 Financial institutions falling outside the regulatory perimeter of traditional financial entities may engage in equivalent activities without being subjected to adequate regulation. In the same vein, sectoral supervisors can only monitor the build-up of systemic risk within their competence and thus, by definition, lack a comprehensive overview of the financial sector. The institutional financial supervisory structure in the EU should, therefore, be supplemented by an institution charged with monitoring systemic risk build-up in any financial institution and, when necessary, bring them within an adequate regulatory and supervisory perimeter.

As demonstrated in Sect. 5, an institutional approach is still prevalent in the EU’s financial regulatory structure. Because such an approach is especially susceptive to regulatory gaps, it needs to be complemented by a robust monitoring mechanism which has an activity-based approach of detecting systemic risk across the entire financial sector. In the EU, the ESRB provides for monitoring of systemic risks, but lacks substantial formal legal power. The US, in contrast, has equipped the FSOC with substantial systemic risk monitoring powers and the competence to bring systemically important financial institutions within an adequate regulatory and supervisory perimeter, as discussed in Sect. 4. We advocate an expansion of the ESRB’s powers, providing it, in imitation of the FSOC, with the competence to designate financial institutions as systemically important and, in consequence, bring them within prudential supervision or enhanced supervision.

Given the dual legal orders of the EU and its Member States, we would also argue that prudential supervision should be performed at the EU level by an EU institution. As systemically important financial institutions operate across national borders, regulation and supervision should not be confined within such borders. This brings to mind what Dirk Schoenmaker has called the ‘financial trilemma’: increased financial integration due to globalisation and, more specifically, to the creation of an European internal market is not compatible with both financial stability and national financial policies.Footnote 254 National supervision of non-bank SIFIs has proved inadequate.Footnote 255 This is in part due to inherent jurisdictional limitations and the corresponding fragmentised view of the supervised institution.Footnote 256 Moreover, national authorities might be tempted to practise forbearance in regard to financial institutions perceived as national champions.Footnote 257

Similarly, the resolution of non-bank SIFIs can best be achieved by a Union institution. Much the same arguments as for European supervision apply. Lacking a comprehensive view of a non-bank SIFI’s business causes suboptimal resolution decisions. Moreover, national authorities have strong incentives to minimise the impact of failing non-bank SIFIs on their economy.Footnote 258 This can result in unilateral measures such as requiring higher capital and liquidity buffers or limiting intra-group transfers. Maintaining financial stability is not the prime aim of such measures. Consequently, they have the potential to cause unnecessary destruction of the non-bank SIFI’s value and distort the functioning of the internal market.

6.2 Monitoring Systemic Risk

The global financial crisis exposed the integrated nature, both cross-sectoral and cross-border, of financial markets and institutions. This warrants an integrated approach to the monitoring of financial risks. In the EU the ESRB is tasked with systemic risk monitoring. The ESRB’s powers, however, are limited to monitoring and assessing systemic risks and, where appropriate, issuing warnings and recommendations. It does not have formal powers and instead has to rely on systemic risk warnings and non-binding recommendations to EU members, which can be punctuated by a ‘comply or explain’ mechanism.

In regard to the collection of information, it is of interest to note that the ESRB may request information of the ESA’s, the ECB, the Commission and national supervisors, statistics authorities and member states.Footnote 259 However, as the information provided has to be in aggregate form, it is impossible to distinguish individual firms. If, as we propose below, the ESRB is to be able to make non-bank SIFI designations comparable to the FSOC designations, this limitation has to be removed.

In the US, the FSOC is charged with identifying risks to the financial stability of the United States, promoting market discipline, and responding to emerging risks to the stability of the US financial system. Its powers include the designation of non-bank financial institutions and financial market utilities to be supervised by the Federal Reserve Board. It may issue recommendations on heightened prudential standards to supervisory authorities. Moreover, it makes recommendations on jurisdictional disputes and reports on regulatory gaps to Congress.

6.3 Non-bank SIFI Designation

We propose that the ESRB be equipped with powers similar to those of the FSOC to designate non-bank financial companies as systemically important and, consequently, deserving of additional prudential regulation and supervision. This would go a long way towards alleviating systemic risks by creating a mechanism to ensure non-bank SIFIs are subjected to a regulatory perimeter consistent with the risks they pose. Such a designation would be an important instrument in preventing regulatory arbitrage. Indeed, echoing the designation process of the FSOC, we would note that the level of regulatory scrutiny to which a non-bank SIFI is subjected is an important factor when deciding on a designation.

6.3.1 Legal Feasibility

The ESRB could be given the power to designate non-bank SIFIs under Article 114 TFEU, as it aims to improve the functioning of the internal market by helping to provide financial stability. Indeed, the very goal of such a designation is to make sure that such non-bank SIFIs are regulated to an extent consistent with the level of systemic risk they pose. Consequently, the power to make such a designation is conditional on whether it addresses a threat to financial stability and whether such a designation would alleviate the threat.

However, such a power of designation for the ESRB might be subject to legal constraints on the delegation of discretionary powers to agencies. The EU Member States have delegated powers to the EU through the Treaties. In turn, the Union legislature may decide to delegate some of these powers to an agency in cases where the Treaties provide for this possibility either in a specific provision or in the form of a general competence such as Article 114 TFEU.

The degree to which such delegation is allowed was addressed by the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) in its Meroni ruling.Footnote 260 The CJEU distinguished between two types of delegation. Whereas purely executive powers may be delegated as their exercise can be reviewed against objective criteria specified by the delegating authority, powers involving a wide margin of discretion in determining economic policy may not be delegated. Such delegation would replace the choices of the delegating authority by those of the delegatee and bring about an actual transfer of responsibility.Footnote 261 As a transfer of responsibility of this kind would alter the balance of power between the EU institutions, it would be incompatible with the Treaties.Footnote 262

In its Short Selling judgmentFootnote 263 the CJEU revisited and revised its Meroni doctrine. First, the CJEU emphasised that the contested delegation in Meroni concerned delegation to an entity governed by private law, whereas the contested delegation in the Short Selling case was to ESMA, which had been established pursuant to an EU regulation. The Court went on to note that ESMA’s power to prohibit or impose conditions on the entry by natural or legal persons into a short sale or require them to notify a competent authority or to disclose to the public details of net short positionsFootnote 264 does not confer any autonomous power that goes beyond the boundaries of the regulatory framework established by the ESMA Regulation.Footnote 265 Furthermore, and unlike the circumstances in Meroni, ESMA’s discretionary powers in regard to short selling are circumscribed by various conditions and criteria.Footnote 266 The CJEU therefore held that the powers available to ESMA in regard to short selling are precisely delineated and amenable to judicial review in the light of the objectives established by the delegating authority. Accordingly, it found that those powers comply with the requirements laid down in Meroni. Consequently, those powers do not imply that ESMA is vested with a ‘very large measure of discretion’ that is incompatible with the Treaties.Footnote 267

In line with the Short Selling ruling it could be argued that granting the ESRB the power to designate non-bank financial institutions as systemically important is not in breach of the Meroni constraints. Much the same conditions and restraints applicable to ESMA’s short selling powers would be applicable to the designation procedure as the ESRB too has to make an assessment of a possible threat to the stability of the whole or part of the financial system. The Commission could provide conditions detailing how such an assessment should be made in a delegated regulation. Judicial review of a designation would also be possible as a designation is of direct and individual concern to the subject institution, opening up proceedings, under Article 263 TFEU, before the CJEU.

At the same time, we concede that in order to have in place a forward-looking system for the monitoring and designation of systemically important institutions, it is vital for the ESRB to have a degree of discretion. As the financial sector is ever evolving, the ESRB should not be subject to extremely detailed conditions limiting its ability to review and determine systemic relevance. As the FSOC too notes in its final rule and interpretive guidance on non-bank SIFI designation, a determination decision cannot be reduced to a formula.

In order to loosen possible Meroni constraints, final determination could be subjected to validation by the Commission (or by non-objection within an appropriate time-frame). As the Commission has a direct basis in the Treaties, it is not subjected to Meroni constraints. Such an arrangement has, for the same reasons, been used in the context of the Single Resolution Mechanism, where resolution decisions by the Single Resolution Board are validated by the Commission. Additionally, in the recent legislative proposal on supervision of CCPs, ESMA may make a request to the Commission that a CCP may be of such systemic importance that it will be able to provide services in the Union only if it establishes itself in the EU. Again, the Commission, officially, makes the final determination.

Alternatively, the ESRB or a newly created institution could be endowed with designation powers in the Treaty. This might be the preferable option as it would provide a strong legal basis, without complicating the governance structure by including the Commission. However, as it would require a Treaty change it seems politically unfeasible. On the other hand, political realities could turn out to fluctuate more than the financial markets.

6.4 Non-bank SIFI Supervision

As described earlier, new prudential regulation in the US rearranged and expanded financial regulation, supervision and resolution. FSOC-designated ‘systemically important’ financial institutions are subject to the prudential regulations set out in Title I of the Act and are supervised by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (FRB). The latter has the discretion to impose additional, tailor-made prudential standards and disclosure requirements.

Following the example set by the FSOC, a designation by the ESRB should have the consequence of pulling a financial institution within an appropriate prudential regulatory perimeter and related supervision. This is not to say that a one-size-fits-all approach should be taken in determining prudential requirements. Instead, regulators should have the discretion to set specific requirements reflecting the specific business of a regulated entity. Following the example set by Dodd-Frank,Footnote 268 this should include requirements in relation to capital, leverage limits, liquidity, risk management, resolution planning and credit exposure reporting. Again, following the US model, the prudential standards should be tailored, on an individual basis or by category, to the designated institution. Such standards should reflect the institutions’ capital structure, riskiness, complexity, financial activities (including the financial activities of their subsidiaries), size and any other risk-related factors. In consequence, the resulting tailored prudential requirements address the systemic risks while providing a fair regulatory burden, taking into account the specific nature and activities of the institution.Footnote 269

European supervision could be realised by having designated non-bank SIFIs fall within the scope of the Banking Union. In addition to supervising significant eurozone banks, the ECB would then also be charged with supervising of non-bank financial institution designated by the ESRB as systemically important.Footnote 270 In this scenario it would be most sensible to have the ECB determine adequate prudential requirements for the designated institution.

Alternatively, another EU entity could be charged with supervision. A possible connection could be made with the intended or successive reforms of the European Supervisory Agencies, as discussed in Sect. 5.2.2. Pursuant to a non-bank SIFI designation by the ESRB, the ESA which has most affinity with the designate institution would operate as direct prudential supervisor. Direct supervision by an ESA is not unprecedented as ESMA already has direct supervisory tasks. Some would prefer this option as it would remove the perception that designated institutions are regulated and supervised as banks by the ECB. Moreover, as the ECB, arguably, already has a conflict of interest between monetary policy and prudential supervisory objectives, this would be even more the case if it were also to supervise non-bank SIFIs.Footnote 271 At the same time, the ECB could profit from the resources and experiences gained in the context of the Banking Union and from a comprehensive overview of the financial sector. We will limit ourselves to the more fundamental contention that the prudential supervision of non-bank SIFIs, subject to a determination by the ESRB, should be performed by an EU authority as opposed to a national authority. It is, however, important to note that the scope of ECB supervision in the context of the Banking Union currently coincides with that of the eurozone as no additional Member States have acceded. This is more limited than the scope of the ESAs which operate throughout the EU. We prefer a broader scope.

This touches upon an important, additional benefit of our proposed designation and supervision scheme for systemically important institutions. As Schwarcz and Zaring point out, the benefits of a non-bank SIFI identification and supervisory scheme extend beyond the systemic risk mitigation of the supervised institution. First, the possibility to take over or provide additional supervision of designated firms deters the initial supervisors (if any, of course) of the non-bank institutions from applying lax supervisory standards or neglecting to take proper account of systemic risk.Footnote 272 This dimension is of extra importance in the context of the EU where non-bank financial regulation largely depends on national administration. As stated, national supervisors are not well equipped to address systemic risks in cross-border financial institutions. They are ill-positioned to have a comprehensive overview of the risks present in a cross-border financial institution and are predominantly mandated to address national (stability) concerns. National supervisors might also feel tempted to practise supervisory forbearance by giving national champions a competitive advantage. In such cases, the looming threat of losing supervisory control to an EU authority would provide a strong incentive for national supervisors to redouble their efforts. Moreover, an instruction from EU authorities such as the ERSB itself or other agencies to national supervisors would have even greater impact if non-compliance could lead to a non-bank SIFI designation by the ERSB.

Another benefit of the designation regime is that it compels financial institutions to exercise self-restraint when confronted with the threat of being designated as a non-bank SIFI. Since, as already noted, the existing level of regulatory scrutiny is an important factor for a non-bank SIFI determination, financial institutions which add value through regulatory arbitrage activities might be deterred from engaging in these activities if they knew that this might bring them within the scope of a non-bank SIFI designation. In other words, the possibility of being designated as systemically important curbs the risk appetite of institutions. As shown in Sect. 4.4, these effects are already apparent in the US where General Electric has greatly reduced its risk profile in a successful effort to have its non-bank SIFI status rescinded.

6.4.1 Legal Feasibility

The scope of the SSM will have to be expanded in order to bring supervision of designated non-bank SIFIs within the scope of the Banking Union. However, the scope of the SSM is subject to Treaty limitations.

Article 127(6) TFEU grants the Council the power to confer specific tasks upon the ECB concerning policies relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and other financial institutions with the exception of insurance undertakings. It follows that although the basic treaty provision allows for a broader scope than merely credit institutions, the SSM does not reflect this. Instead the design of the SSM was determined by the need to break the link between sovereigns and banks, as joined supervision paved the way for the mutualisation of bank bailouts.Footnote 273

The scope of the SSM could therefore be expanded to include other financial institutions, provided they do not qualify as insurance undertakings. It could, perhaps, be argued that the term insurance undertaking should be narrowly defined to exclude institutions that deal in bank-like products, as AIG did when it took large positions in credit default swaps.

However, a more legally satisfying approach, albeit perhaps a politically less feasible one, would be to amend the TFEU. The primary function of such an amendment would be to confer on a European body the power to supervise all non-bank SIFI designated entities. Logically, this would be the same body as is in charge of supervision under the SSM.

Alternatively, a European Supervisory Agency could be tasked with the direct prudential supervision of designated non-bank SIFIs. To this end the EU legislators could adopt a regulation on based on Article 114 TFEU in which they delegate these task to a European agency. Article 114 TFEU provides a suitable legal basis as EU supervision harmonises the supervisory practices and thereby improves the conditions for the establishment and functioning of the internal market. This is also in compliance with the principle of subsidiarity and proportionality since the execution of supervision at the EU level is motivated, precisely because, fragmentised supervision at the national level has proven inadequate. Additionally, proportionality is an important element in the determination whether or not to designate a financial institutions as a non-bank SIFI and placing it under direct supervision.

In view of the Short Selling judgement, direct prudential supervision by an EU agency seems legally possible when the execution of supervision is circumscribed by various conditions and criteria which limit the agencies discretion and the possibility of judicial protection against the agency’s acts. However, while the ECJ’s ‘mellowing’ of Meroni through the Short Selling case provides a legal window to task supervision of non-bank SIFIs with an EU agency, the associated legal uncertainty is troublesome. Furthermore, the fact that no regulatory powers may be conferred to the agency renders it impossible for the agency to adopt tailored prudential requirements for non-bank SIFIs without approval by an EU institution with a Treaty basis.

6.5 Non-Bank SIFI Resolution

A credible resolution regime for non-bank SIFIs is of paramount importance in order to create a credible alternative to publicly funded bailouts and help safeguard financial stability by providing for orderly liquidation and allowing for the continued operation of systemically important business processes. Such a regime subjects non-bank SIFIs to market discipline as it cancels out their Too-Big-To-Fail status and associated implicit guarantees.

The European Banking Union (EBU) provides a resolution regime for banks and, subject to certain conditions, their parent companies if they are a financial holding company or mixed financial holding company. Additionally, 730k investment firms and financial institutions’ subsidiaries may also fall within the resolution scope of the EBU. This creates a complicated and opaque resolution regime with some entities within a group falling within the resolution scope and others not. The scope of resolution is governed not by the systemic risk posed by an institution and whether this may be mitigated by placing it under resolution but instead by inflexible and arbitrary legal norms.

This leads to regulatory gaps, regulatory arbitrage, an unlevel playing field and an incomplete toolbox for addressing systemic risk, which may manifest itself in different and to some extent unknown forms. A resolution regime needs to reflect this. Therefore non-bank SIFIs should also qualify for liquidation under a European resolution mechanism. This creates a more flexible, open-ended and forward-looking approach aimed at preventing the next crisis, not the last one.

Inspiration can, again, be drawn from the resolution regime created by the Dodd-Frank Act in the US. This regime, known as the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA), captures any non-bank financial institution whose failure would seriously impact financial stability in the US.

A possible way of strengthening the European resolution regime and mitigating the systemic risks stemming from non-bank entities would be to widen the scope of the SRM to include all financial institutions that pose systemic risk.

It should be remembered that the legal basis of the SRM is Article 114 TFEU, which provides a basis for the adoption of measures for the approximation of the provisions in Member States which have as their object the establishment and functioning of the internal market. According to the European Court of Justice (CJEU), measures under Article 114 TFEU must genuinely have as its object the improvement of the conditions for the establishment and functioning of the internal market.Footnote 274

A centralised European resolution authority aims to ensure a uniform application of resolution rules. This enhances the proper functioning of the internal market, specifically in the field of financial services as it eliminates, national, fragmentised resolution rules and thus improves the level playing field. Additionally, its main objective is to strengthen financial stability in the EU: an essential prerequisite for the functioning of the internal market.

This leads to the conclusion that a resolution scheme for non-bank SIFIs or an expansion of the SRM to include such entities does not need Treaty change. Instead, it can be established in accordance with the ordinary legislative procedure on the basis of Article 114 TFEU.

7 Conclusions

The global financial crisis revealed that the migration of financial activities outside the traditional banking sector was accompanied by a huge and unchecked build-up of systemic risk. National and/or sectorally organised regulation and supervision proved insufficient owing to the continued integration and interconnectedness of financial markets, institutions, products and services. Gaps in the coverage of regulation and supervision led to an inconsistent regulatory treatment of equivalent products and/or services. This in turn caused an unlevel playing field and encouraged regulatory arbitrage behaviour, which caused a migration of activities and a build-up of systemic risk in the less regulated or unregulated parts of the financial system.

We propose that equivalent financial products and/or services should be subject to an integrated European regulatory and supervisory approach. Above all, institutions that pose systemic risk should be brought within a regulatory perimeter consistent with the risk they pose to financial stability.

A European body should therefore be in charge of monitoring financial institutions active in the EU, and should identify institutions which pose systemic risk. It should, subsequently, have the discretion to designate a non-bank financial firm as a non-bank SIFI. Such designation would ensure a level of regulatory and supervision consistent with the risks to financial stability posed by a financial institution. Given its current tasks, the European Systemic Risk Board seems best suited for this task.

After an institution has been designated as non-bank SIFI, it comes under European supervision. As such a regime has been created for banks in the form of the European Banking Union, designated non-bank SIFIs should be brought within the perimeter of the EBU. While the Treaties exclude insurance companies, other financial institutions can be brought under supervision of the ECB without the need for Treaty change. The ECB would then be able to supervise and impose enhanced prudential standards on designated non-bank SIFIs. Alternatively, another EU entity could be charged with supervision, for example the relevant ESA.

In keeping with the second pillar of the EBU, a regime should also be in place to ensure that non-bank SIFIs can be resolved without causing systemic risk. This would resolve the Too-Big-To-Fail dilemma and subject the institutions concerned to market discipline. A connection could be made with the EBU’s second pillar by expanding the scope of the SRM to include designated non-bank SIFIs. Such an inclusion could be based on Article 114 TFEU, as the alleviation of systemic risk greatly improves the functioning of the internal market.

The development of such a regime could be based on the example of the US, where the Dodd-Frank Act provides for the designation of non-bank SIFIs and their regulation, supervision and possible resolution.

Ensuring that non-bank SIFIs are properly regulated, supervised and, if necessary, resolved would help to eliminate supervisory and regulatory gaps, reduce regulatory arbitrage activities, enhance the level playing field and contribute to the stability of the financial system as a whole.