Skip to main content
Log in

Generic and Brand Advertising Strategies Under Inter-Industry Competition

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Customer Needs and Solutions Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Industries invest in over billion dollars annually to drive up the primary demand and to fence off competing new industries’ threat to their customer bases. Companies in addition to contributing to industry generic campaign also heavily rely on brand advertising in order to capture a greater market share. Using a game-theoretic approach, we study generic and brand advertising competition under such an inter-industry competitive framework. We built an analytical model to study two competing industries each simultaneously making generic advertising decisions followed by firms within each industry simultaneously conducting brand advertising. We found that the mere presence of a rival industry can act as an impetus for an industry to invest in generic advertising. Model analyses and numerical studies suggest that there is a clear interactive nature between the two types of advertising decisions under inter-industry competitive framework. The generic advertising spending of an industry increases as the firms within that industry are more asymmetric. While a firm’s brand advertising spending increases as the generic advertising of its associated industry becomes more effective and that of the rival industry becomes less effective. Extensions of the main model suggest that there is a first-mover advantage in generic advertising under inter-industry competition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One of the most famous examples is perhaps the “Got Milk?” campaign by the California Milk Advisory Board.

  2. There are agricultural economic studies where the focus is on how policy changes such as the introduction of a specific tax affects industries of substitutable products (e.g., [14]) and how generic advertising changes when production is rationed in a competing industry (e.g., [9]).

  3. We investigate in Section 4.4 the asymmetric case where there is an unequal number of firms within each industry.

  4. A recent example could be iOS versus Android for smartphone operation system.

  5. For example, the CRH ticket price for the Beijing-Shanghai route is reported to be fairly close to the average discount airfare.

  6. Following the roof top example, this specification could imply that more and more residences are adopting the solar panel rooftop as opposed to the traditional roofing material.

  7. An industry can inform its members that no generic campaign will be conducted at all if the total amount decided at Stage 1 is not met. The provision point literature shows that if an industry sets the provision point at the optimal level, it constitutes a credible threat leading to contribution.

  8. Derivations using the general margin parameter (s ij ) yields qualitatively consistent results, yet the mathematical expression is more complex which makes it challenging for readers to following the intuitions.

  9. We do not include all result tables from our extensive numerical studies in this manuscript due to the space limit. They are available upon request from the authors. The patterns are qualitative persistent from the numerical results of all scenarios.

  10. Detailed analyses of these two extensions are available from the authors upon request.

  11. The experimental setup used by Krishnamurthy [16] could potentially be expanded into an industry-by-firm between subject design for a laboratory study testing the predictions from the analytical models of this paper.

References

  1. Armbruster WJ, Nichols JP (2001) Commodity promotion policy. Working paper, Texas A&M University, University College Station

  2. Bass FM, Krishnamurthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2005) Generic and brand advertising strategies in a dynamic duopoly. Mark Sci 24(4):556–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Bates R (2015) De Beers Invests in Generic Advertising (with an Asterisk). http://www.jckonline.com. September 3, 2015

  4. Bell DP, Keeney RL, Little JDC (1975) A marketing share theorem. J Mark Res 12(5):136–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Brandenburger AM, Nalebuff BJ (1996) Co-opetition. Doubleday, New York

    Google Scholar 

  6. Carey C, Bolton DL (1996) Brand versus generic advertising and the decision to advertise collectively. Rev Ind Organ 11:93–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Chakravarti A, Janiszewski C (2004) The influence of generic advertising on brand preference. J Consum Res 30(March):487–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Cooper LG, Nakanishi M (1988) Market share analysis. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  9. Cranfield JAL (2007) Optimal generic advertising with rationed related good: the case of Canadian beef and chicken markets. Can J Agric Econ 50(2):117–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Crespi JM (2007) Generic advertising and product differentiation revisited. Journal of Agricultural and Food Industrial Organization 5(1):445–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Erickson G (1985) A model of advertising competition. J Mark Res:297–304

  12. Galbraith J K (1967) The new industrial state. Boston

  13. Hauser JR, Shugan SM (1983) Defensive marketing strategies. Mark Sci 2(4):319–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Kinnucan HW, Paudel L (2001) Upstream effects of generic advertising: the case of catfish. Mar Resour Econ 16(2):83–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Krishnamurthy S (2000) Enlarging the pie vs. increasing one’s slice: an analysis of the relationship between product class and brand advertising. Mark Lett 11(1):37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Krishnamurthy S (2001) The effect of provision points on generic advertising funding. Mark Lett 12(4):315–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Krishnamurthy S, Bottom WP, Rao AG (2003) Adaptive aspirations and contributions to a public good: generic advertising as a response to decline. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 92(1.2):22–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. McGuire TW, Staelin R (1983) An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Mark Sci 2(2):161–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Messer KD, Schmit T, Kaiser HM (2005) Optimal institutional mechanisms for funding generic advertising: an experimental analysis. Am J Agric Econ 87(4):1046–1060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Messer KD, Schmit T, Kaiser HM (2008) The problem of free riding in voluntary generic advertising: parallelism and possible solutions from the lab. Am J Agric Econ 90(2):540–552

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Moorthy KS (1988) Product and price competition in a duopoly. Mark Sci 7(2):141–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Ngo DD, Okura M (2008) Coopetition in a mixed duopoly market. Econ Bull 12(20):1–9

    Google Scholar 

  23. Organization Consumer Association (2011) Organic Trade Association Modified GMO Interests

  24. Qi J, Wang D, Ding Y, Wang Z (2007) Dynamical analysis of a nonlinear competitive model with generic and brand advertising efforts. Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 8(2):664–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Qi J, Ding Y, Chen L (2008) Complex dynamics of the generic and brand advertising strategies in duopoly. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 36(2):354–358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Rao R, Syam N (2001) Equilibrium price communication and unadvertised specials by competing supermarkets. Mark Sci 20(1):61–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Roma P, Perrone G (2010) Generic advertising, brand advertising and price competition: an analysis of free-riding effects and coordination mechanisms. Rev Mark Sci 8(4)

  28. The Produce News (2014) COTA Launches Think Canada Organic’ Campaign

  29. Thomadsen R, Rhee K (2007) Costly collusion in differentiated industries. Mark Sci 26(5):660–665

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Trabish HK (2013) Arizona utility funds solar smear campaign, saying it is ‘Obligated to flight’. http://www.greentechmedia.com/. October 22, 2013

  31. Wilder RP (1974) Advertising and inter-industry competition: testing a galbraithian hypothesis. J Ind Econ 22(3):215–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Wiskerchen S (2016) New Ad Campaign Urges Consumers to “Get RealtorR”. http://www.realtor.org/. February 8, 2016

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuanfang Lin.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Based on the model setup in Section 3, profit function for firm i of industry j can be written as:

$$ {\pi}_{ij}=\left(\frac{M_{oj}+{\alpha}_j{G}_j}{M_{0 j}+{\alpha}_j{G}_j+{M}_{0,3- j}+{\alpha}_{3- j}{G}_{3- j}}\right)\left(\frac{\theta_{ij}{B}_{ij}^{1/2}}{\theta_{ij}{B}_{ij}^{1/2}+{\theta}_{3- i, j}{B}_{3- i, j}^{1/2}}\right){S}_j-{G}_{ij}-{B}_{ij},\mathrm{with}\; i, j=1,2. $$
(6)

Equilibrium brand advertising levels at the second stage of the game are obtained from simultaneously solving the first-order conditions \( \frac{\partial {\pi}_{ij}}{\partial {B}_{ij}}=0 \) and check the negative semi-definiteness of the second-order Hessian matrix, which results in

$$ {B}_{ij}=\frac{\theta_{ij}{\theta}_{3- i, j}{M}_j{s}_j}{2{\left({\theta}_{ij}+{\theta}_{3- i, j}\right)}^2} $$
(7)

Substitute M 01 = ϕ, M 02 =  and (7) back to (6), sum over the profit functions of the two firms within each industry yields the industry total profit function:

$$ {\pi}_1=\left(\frac{\phi +{\alpha}_1{G}_1}{\phi +{\alpha}_1{G}_1+ k\phi +{\alpha}_2{G}_2}\right){Y}_1{s}_1-{G}_1;{\pi}_2=\left(\frac{k\phi +{\alpha}_2{G}_2}{\phi +{\alpha}_1{G}_1+ k\phi +{\alpha}_2{G}_2}\right){Y}_2{s}_2-{G}_2 $$
(8)

where \( {Y}_j=1-\frac{\theta_{ij}{\theta}_{3- i, j}}{{\left({\theta}_{ij}+{\theta}_{3- i, j}\right)}^2} \), ∀i , j = 1 , 2.

Solving for \( \frac{\partial {\pi}_j}{\partial {G}_j}=0 \) and check the negative semi-definiteness of the second-order Hessian matrix yields the expressions of \( {G}_j^{\ast } \) as in part 1 of Proposition 1. \( {G}_j^{\ast }>0 \) as long as \( 0<\phi <\frac{\lambda_1^2{\lambda}_2}{{\left({\lambda}_1+{\lambda}_2\right)}^2} \) (condition i) with λ j  = α j Y j s j  , j = 1 , 2.

We next check if an industry would still have incentive to invest positive amount for generic campaign when its rival industry does not conduct any generic advertising. Suppose G 2 = 0, straight profit maximization yields the optimal generic advertising level for industry 1 as:

$$ {G}_1^{\prime }=\frac{\sqrt{k{\phi \alpha}_1{Y}_1{s}_1}-\left(1+ k\right)\phi}{\alpha_1} $$
(9)

and the above (9) is positive as long as \( 0<\phi <\frac{k{\alpha}_1{Y}_1{s}_1}{{\left(1+ k\right)}^2} \) (condition ii). Similarly, we can derive the condition for \( {G}_2^{\prime }>0 \) if G 1 = 0.

Combing conditions (i) and (ii) results in the parameter condition for part 1 of Proposition 1. Substituting \( {G}_j^{\ast } \) back to (7) yields the equilibrium brand advertising levels reported in part 1 of Proposition 1. Finally, the feasibility conditions are satisfied by substituting the equilibrium generic-brand advertising levels back to the industry profit functions and found that \( {\pi}_j^{\ast}\left({G}_j^{\ast },{B}_{ij}^{\ast}\right)>0 \). Derivation of brand advertising levels for part 2 of Proposition 1 follows by substituting \( {G}_j^{\ast }=0 \) into (7) for profit maximization with respect to B ij . This completes the proof. ■

1.2 Proof of Corollary 2

Taking partial derivatives of the equilibrium brand advertising level (\( {B}_{ij}^{\ast } \)) in part 1 of Proposition 1 with respect to α j and α 3 − j , Corollary 2 follows after straight algebraic arrangement. ■

1.3 Proof of Corollary 3

Taking partial derivatives of the equilibrium generic advertising level (\( {G}_j^{\ast } \)) in Proposition 1 with respect to θ ij and θ 3 − i , j , Corollary 3 follows as the product of these two partial derivatives is negative. ■

1.4 Proof of Proposition 2

The brand advertising decision at the last stage can be derived similarly as in proposition 1. Back to the second stage of the sequential game in Extension (Section 4.4) where industry 2 determines G 2 given G 1 and knowing how the firms across industries decide their brand advertising at the last stage. Profit maximization of π 2 in (8) with respect to G 2 yields

$$ {G}_2=\frac{\sqrt{\alpha_2{Y}_2{s}_2\left(\phi +{\alpha}_1{G}_1\right)}-{\alpha}_1{G}_1-\left(1+ k\right)\phi}{\alpha_2} $$
(10)

Finally, move back to the first stage where industry 1 decides G 1 knowing how industry 2 would choose G 2 and the consequent brand advertising decision at the firm level. Substitute G 2 from (10) into π 1 in (8), profit maximization with respect to yields

$$ {G}_1^{\ast \ast }=\frac{\lambda_1^2}{4{\alpha}_1{\lambda}_2}-\frac{\phi}{\alpha_1} $$
(11)

Substitute (11) back to (10) yields

$$ {G}_2^{\ast \ast }=\frac{\lambda_1\left(2{\lambda}_2-{\lambda}_1\right)}{4{\alpha}_2{\lambda}_2}-\frac{k\phi}{\alpha_2} $$
(12)

It can be shown by comparing (11), (12) with \( \left({G}_1^{\ast },{G}_2^{\ast}\right) \) from Proposition 1 that \( {G}_2^{\ast \ast }-{G}_2^{\ast }<0 \), while \( {G}_1^{\ast \ast }-{G}_1^{\ast }>0 \) as long as \( {\alpha}_1>\frac{\alpha_2{Y}_2{s}_2}{Y_1{S}_1} \). This completes the proof. ■

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lin, Y., Krishnamurthy, S. Generic and Brand Advertising Strategies Under Inter-Industry Competition. Cust. Need. and Solut. 4, 18–27 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40547-017-0070-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40547-017-0070-2

Keywords

Navigation