1 Introduction

The Internet of Things (IoT) revolution has influenced various industries and has been transforming both companies and competition.Footnote 1 The agricultural sector is one of the industries affected. Today’s agricultural practices are becoming densely data-drivenFootnote 2 with the proliferation of digital technologies and IoT systems in the farm setting.Footnote 3 Thus, farmers are able to make agronomic decisions more accurately.Footnote 4 Data-driven analytics are used, for instance, to track crop developments, to diagnose (or even predict) plant diseases, to estimate harvesting times and to determine the right time for inseminating livestock, as sensors are much more sensitive and precise than human observation.Footnote 5 This technological transformation has led to a paradigm shift from traditional agricultural decision-making to data-driven “smart farming”,Footnote 6 and created the digital agriculture (DA) sector,Footnote 7 in which agricultural technology providers (ATPs)Footnote 8 equip farmers with data-driven agronomic solutions, prescriptions and predictions.Footnote 9

This transformation has brought with it new challenges. One of the most prominent data-related debates in this nascent sector is about “ownership” of agricultural data (ag-data). Although “data ownership” as a legal concept has been discussed and has faded over time in the broader literature on non-personal data,Footnote 10 the discussions in the sectoral literature still revolve around whether data belongs to farmers, ATPs, machine producers or other stakeholders, such as data collectors (if not farmers), landowners or even financial lenders.Footnote 11 The majority of the existing publications advocate the idea of providing a data ownership right for farmersFootnote 12 or at least removing uncertainties regarding ag-data ownership.Footnote 13 This general tendency has resulted in various initiatives, which have created voluntary ag-data rules and rights in various countries.Footnote 14 For Europe, the EU code of conduct on agricultural data sharing by contractual agreement (EU Code) was created by stakeholders in 2018.Footnote 15 The EU Code also used the popular understanding of “data ownership” as the central legal concept when designing its ag-data rules, rights and principles.Footnote 16 Beyond voluntary initiatives and active debates in the literature, stakeholders also predominantly accept the understanding of data ownership, as can be observed from the views of participants in the recent expert workshop run by the European Commission (the Commission)Footnote 17 on how to build a “Common European Agricultural Data Space” (CEADS).Footnote 18

These developments provided the stimulus for this study to identify whether “data ownership” as a central legal concept is really preferable for regulating ag-data, as very little attention has been paid to the potential consequences of such a regulatory attempt in the emerging DA sector,Footnote 19 especially from the perspective of competition and innovation. To provide a sound analysis based on an analytical framework, the paper identifies prominent data-related market failures in the sector to use as a benchmark when discussing to what extent a data ownership right or an alternative regulatory designFootnote 20 can address those failures and serve sectoral development. As new regulatory initiatives are already starting to appear or are on the way,Footnote 21 it is necessary to contribute in good time to the question of how to frame the development of a sectoral data governance regime by investigating the policy options in this regard. This paper will provide a proposal in order to address sectoral issues. The suggestions will also be compared with the legal framework provided under the recent horizontal Data Act.Footnote 22 The contribution made to the literature by this research will be twofold: (1) for the digital agriculture literature, the paper provides a deeper legal discussion of the potential effects of data ownership regulation on sectoral dynamics and contributes to the ag-data governance debate by highlighting alternatives, and (2) for the broader legal literature, it presents a detailed sector-specific analysis on non-personal data governance issues.

The rest of the paper consists of three main sections. Section 2 highlights prominent data-related market failures in the emerging DA sector. Section 3 provides a discussion on the legal concept of “data ownership”, and explores its possible implications in the DA sector. Section 4 presents an alternative approach to regulating the sector, which is also compared with the recent horizontal Data Act proposal. Finally, Section 5 concludes with the main findings of the paper.

2 Prominent Data-Related Market Failures in the Emerging DA Sector

In order to evaluate the consequences of possible data ownership rights for farmers or an alternative design for sectoral regulation, it is critical to understand the sectoral conditions, as well as prominent data-related market failuresFootnote 23 and the reasons for them. Thus, it can be discussed more systematically whether the widely advocated understanding of data ownership (or an alternative design) is capable of addressing the sectoral issues.

2.1 Data Lock-In and Farmers’ Weak Bargaining Power

Farmers struggle to transfer historical data setsFootnote 24 when they want to switch to a new company or machine, and this locks them in even if their existing setting becomes insufficient or expensive compared with an innovative or cheaper alternative.Footnote 25

There are various reasons for this. First of all, there is no undisputed legal framework applicable to ag-data sets.Footnote 26 Most of the data in the sector is considered non-personal.Footnote 27 Therefore, the General Data Protection RegulationFootnote 28 (GDPR) with its right to data portability is unlikely to be applicable hereFootnote 29 or, at best, might not be sufficient to address lock-in in a connected devices setting.Footnote 30 Moreover, farms, especially those operating on a smaller scale, might not be able to properly understand and negotiate the standard contractual terms and conditions.Footnote 31 Even if they have a high level of awareness, they have a weak bargaining position vis-à-vis ATPs or machine producers.Footnote 32 There are also technical barriers to transferring ag-data, owing to the lack of interoperabilityFootnote 33 and to data standardsFootnote 34 that are sometimes intentionally designed to be incompatible in order to nudge farmers to buy all digital agriculture operations from the same group.Footnote 35On top of these factors, there are also indirect network effects from positive feedback loops (having more users (farmers) gives an ag-data advantage that can be used to develop better services, in order to attract more customers in turn).Footnote 36

These legal, contractual, technical, and economic conditions are likely to create insurmountable switching costs for farmers, erecting barriers to entry into the emerging DA sector, and thus potentially resulting in a first-mover advantage for a few vertically integrated agricultural giants.Footnote 37 So, the first analysis in the sections below will be of whether granting farmers data ownership rights (or an alternative design) may help mitigate their data-related lock-in problems, increase their bargaining power or address any of the reasons behind these problems.

2.2 Fragmentation of Data Sets and Exclusive Data Sharing Clusters

Connected with the reasons for lock-in, data fragmentation is another issue in the emerging DA sector. There are unconnected data silos controlled exclusively by certain players.Footnote 38 This isolated data control environment works in favour of integrated big players, which cooperate with each other to increase their data capabilities and create synergies, while erecting higher data access barriers for smaller rivals or new entrants.

The Commission stated in the Bayer v. Monsanto decision that “[l]arger companies with more proprietary data, economic and digital resources are more likely to attract key partners interested in sharing their areas of expertise and own data”.Footnote 39 Indeed, there are some alliances for exclusive data sharing amongst vertically integrated agricultural giants and machine producers,Footnote 40 which result in both larger exclusively controlled data sets and communication channels between already powerful ATPs and machinery producers. For example, Monsanto (now Bayer) has agreements with machine manufacturers John Deere, Agco and CNHI through its subsidiary, the Climate Corporation, which specialises in data-driven agronomic services.Footnote 41 Monsanto also has data-sharing partners, including Growmark, AgIntegrated Inc., Agrian, Deere & Company, AgStudio, Software Solutions Integrated Inc., MZB Technologies, and EFC Systems.Footnote 42 Similarly, technology providers Maglis and Proagrica agreed to create an interface to share data.Footnote 43 John Deereas a machine producer and BASF as a vertically integrated service provider aim to develop a joint project regarding “precision farming and farm management solutions”.Footnote 44 Deere also has data integration arrangements with DuPont – another integrated input giant.Footnote 45 Additionally, there are other collaborations that might also indirectly result in de facto cross-access to related exclusive data sets. For instance, there has been research and development collaboration worth $2.5 billion between BASF and Monsanto since 2007, specifically on breeding, biotech, pesticides, agricultural microbials, agricultural biologicals, and precision agriculture.Footnote 46 Similar practices are common amongst the so-called “Big Six” (Monsanto, Syngenta, DuPont, BASF, Bayer, Dow), which have complicated and interconnected cross-licensing agreements to improve their technologies.Footnote 47

This cooperative tendency might make sense to participants as it has significant potential to improve the quality and accuracy of their data-driven agronomic services.Footnote 48 Indeed, data exchange is presented as a positive activity against business model disruptions in the wider agricultural value chain, as players can access and combine related data sets in order to do their business.Footnote 49 However, participation in these agreements is not open to every interested party and/or new entrants. Instead, major players exchange their isolated data sets only amongst themselves. Big data sets attract other complementary big data sets. This closed system of data collaboration between already powerful players, while creating insurmountable advantages for them, could also have exclusionary effects for smaller rivals and new innovative start-ups that face data access problems.Footnote 50 A data advantage as a result of these exclusive practices can also be used as leverage to dominate connected markets throughout the whole agricultural value chain if not addressed in time by traditional competition law enforcement. This process may result in the emergence of a few powerful data clusters by excluding weaker players, and may give the emerging DA sector an oligopolistic structure. So, the second criterion of the analysis in the sections that follow will be whether a data ownership (or alternative) legal design may help prevent these risks.

2.3 The Data Access Puzzle

Another connected issue can be presented as a puzzle rather than a problem. Beyond farmers, there are a variety of access seekers.Footnote 51 Different elements of the comprehensive notion of ag-dataFootnote 52 can be critical for them. The fragmentation and isolation of data result in bigger problems in this regard (beyond the exclusionary consequences in the DA markets), especially when considering numerous potential data-driven innovations. For instance, access to soil data might be needed by various ATPs, from agronomic irrigation services to fertilising or pesticide/insecticide solutions. Harvesting data is important not only for farmers, but also for other players in the farm-to-fork value chain. Even financial institutions need data access in order to estimate the credibility of farm businesses. Input performance data can be a critical element in generating agronomic solutions for farmers despite the exclusive control of the input producers. Beyond existing markets, innovative players may create completely new services or products both inside and outside of the agricultural value chain. The accessing of ag-data sets by public institutions can also be useful for monitoring, for instance, environmental obligations or CAP enforcement. There may be many more examples, as different components of ag-data sets are related to different services, products or policies that are not even limited to the agricultural sector. However, there is no clear mechanism to respond to or reconcile these various access interests, despite the fact that wider access to ag-data sets would, in terms of the economies of scale and scope enabled by ag-data,Footnote 53 open up enormous potential for Europe. In this regard, the third analytical criterion in the sections below will be whether ag-data ownership regulation (or an alternative design) can help ensure broader ag-data access for all related access seekers.

2.4 Farmers’ Lack of Trust in Sharing Data

As pointed out in earlier studies, farmers also hesitate to share data with third parties or even to adopt digital technologies, owing inter alia to the unclear and unforeseeable consequences of adopting “smart farming” and data sharing.Footnote 54 Two main reasons behind this stand out in particular. The first relates to the lack of clear legal rules that frame the consequences of adopting the technologies and sharing data.Footnote 55 The second relates to whether “smart farming” is a really cost-effective method of compensating investment in these technologies and services.Footnote 56 The latter seems more of a feasibility issue, but both reasons are interconnected. If there is a higher adoption rate and more data sharing with legal clarity, then cheaper and more efficient services can be expected with the help of the economies of scale and scope in data.Footnote 57 This, in turn, can increase the rate of adoption of digital technologies amongst farmers.Footnote 58 As an important component of building trust is developing good data governance,Footnote 59 the considerations in the sections below will also take into account whether an understanding of data ownership (or an alternative design) can address the trust-related challenges in the emerging DA sector.

3 “Data Ownership” as a Legal Concept and Its Possible Implications in Agriculture

3.1 Envisioning “Ownership” for Data

The idea of designing a right to data ownership is not unique to the DA sector. Data ownership as a legal concept has been mentioned in various documents released by the Commission.Footnote 60 At the time of EU Commissioner Oettinger, it was even indicated that the Commission would consider adopting a horizontal data ownership right for IoT data.Footnote 61 In 2017, the slightly different approach of a “data producer’s right” was put forward by the Commission: “A right to use and authorise the use of non-personal data could be granted to the ‘data producer’, i.e. the owner or long-term user (i.e. the lessee) of the device”.Footnote 62 There are different grounds for proposing or rejecting a property rights understanding for data.Footnote 63 Researchers who advocate data ownership focus on different rationales behind their position, such as expecting more control for individuals or creating incentives for further investment with exclusive control.Footnote 64 Their common position in advocating data ownership with a liberal approach does not mean they all agree on the questions of “who should originally own the data?” and “why?”.Footnote 65 The main argument presented by opponents highlights the problematic consequences of such a legal design from the perspective of competition and the functioning of markets.Footnote 66

Even though data ownership is discussed in the broader non-personal data literature and was once considered by policymakers as a regulatory tool,Footnote 67 there is currently no data ownership regulation or de jure ownership right on data in the EU or at Member State level.Footnote 68 At the time of writing this paper, the heated public debate about data ownership seems to have cooled with the GDPR for personal data and a shift in the broader non-personal data literature towards the question of “who would access data?”.Footnote 69 However, this does not mean that the data ownership debate has definitively ended, especially for agricultural data.Footnote 70 This was clearly recognised in the Commission’s summary report of the high-level conference on “Building a Data Economy”:

The vast majority of participants from different sectors agreed that identifying the “owner” of the data is not the key question; instead, defining rights for data access and reuse would be more important. However, the agricultural sector constitutes an exception here, as several stakeholders advocate for a discussion on data ownership for farmers.Footnote 71

According to Wolfert and others, data ownership problems in the DA sector should be regulated, but the method needs to be designed diligently; otherwise, the intervention might reduce the pace of innovation in the sector.Footnote 72 However, the question is “how?”. Could bringing a de jure “ag-data ownership” design be the ultimate solution for sectoral concerns?

3.2 Possible Consequences of a de jure Ag-Data Ownership Right

“Ownership” is a specific and distinct legal concept that needs to be understood clearly and used consistently. The modern understanding of the ownership concept dates back to property rights in Roman Law, which confers three core rights on the owner of an asset: (1) the right to use the good (usus), (2) the right to encumber or transfer the good (abusus), and the right to the fruits of the good (fructus).Footnote 73 In this regard, the ownership right is not a stand-alone right, but rather intrinsically consists of sub-rights. Thus, it is essential to evaluate the consequences of these particular sub-rights before advocating them as a regulatory tool for any sector.

3.2.1 Why an Ag-Data Ownership Right Design Might not Help Change the Status Quo in the DA Sector

An ownership right covers the right to use the asset (usus); thus, ownership of data can be perceived as a possible legal tool for farmers, to enable them to use their farm data with another technology provider. In this sense, providing de jure data ownership for farmers might seem to be a solution to mitigate data lock-in or to increase farmers’ trust in their data-sharing decisions. However, a data ownership right does not change the dynamics of contractual relations for using, processing and sharing the data. More importantly, a property design does not remove the underlying problem of unequal bargaining power.Footnote 74 So, the existing practice based on contractual freedom may continue as before.Footnote 75 For that reason, ex-ante ownership of ag-data might not fundamentally ease existing concerns. Having an ownership right by default could only be useful for farmers when they are deciding the fate of data anew if a contract is found null and void, but this would bring very limited benefits for farmers, especially compared with the risks, which are discussed in detail below. The same dynamics may be valid for the control of complementary and proprietary agricultural data sets beyond farm data.Footnote 76 In this sense, it is difficult to argue that ownership as a legal concept would help change the status quo in general.Footnote 77

3.2.2 How Can Such a Policy Choice Exacerbate Existing Failures?

Consequences for the lock-in problem It is also critical to take into account the “right to transfer” element of the ownership right. This element can be imagined as a two-edged sword because transferability provides the owner of an asset with flexibility and discretion regarding the fate of the asset, but also means that the owner could lose control.Footnote 78 Property rights for data can easily be alienated from right holders.Footnote 79 It was demonstrated a long time ago that, regardless of original allocation, property rights end up in the hands of those who attach most value to them.Footnote 80 Thus, a data ownership design might even result in stronger data holders (owing to their superior bargaining power and interest in controlling data) rather than removing the chains from weaker entitlement holders.Footnote 81

In line with these insights, it should be taken into account that farmers can transfer/sell their data ownership rights to ATPs or agricultural machine producers via standard terms and conditions.Footnote 82 This might reinforce those companies’ already powerful de facto data control with de jure ownership rights.Footnote 83 Bearing in mind, in particular, that the historical data sets can be crucial when changing service providers,Footnote 84 farmers would face harsher lock-in and more dependency if they lose de jure rights to related data sets. So, transferable ag-data ownership might be more problematic than beneficial. With legally recognised ownership rights, few integrated agri-tech giants can actively prevent the transfer of historical data and make existing customers more dependent on them. This might make first-mover players more powerful, and further raise already high entry barriers in this emerging sector.Footnote 85 In brief, a data ownership understanding should be avoided as it is likely to exacerbate power imbalances and the lock-in problem in the sector.

Consequences for the data fragmentation problem and data access puzzle Another element of the “ownership” concept is the “right to encumber”. Entitlement holders can legally prevent use by others. The application of this right to a data setting is strictly related to the longstanding discussion on the dilemma of wider access to data sets versus exclusive control.Footnote 86 It has been argued that there should be an optimal balance between the two.Footnote 87 However, providing an exclusive data ownership right is one of the two extremes, as it contradicts wider access and further innovation possibilities.Footnote 88

There is no clear incentive for first-movers to let others access data. More importantly, data holder companies can be extra hesitant to share data, on the assumption that renouncing exclusive control might be detrimental to their competitive position, particularly with regard to possible future operations or other benefits of exclusive data access.Footnote 89 This means that each data silo can enforce its ownership rights to legally block the re-use of data not only by rivals but also by other parties that are not in direct competition. In such an environment, it is difficult to expect positive consequences from an ownership design. For instance, soil data is needed by many different services in the DA sector, such as seeding, irrigation, or fertilising solutions. A first-mover irrigation service provider might prefer to keep historical soil data to itself by using de jure ownership rightsFootnote 90 with a view to possible future expansion to connected markets or other types of exclusive exploitation. Thus, companies in these connected markets may even become unable to provide competitive solutions to individual farms without legal access to main soil data input even if data access is technically possible, for instance, via farmers’ parallel data storage. And there are many more examples. With the right of ownership including the right to encumber, it would become much more difficult to access the required data sets, which would mean a scarcity of data for rivals and third parties, thus hampering data-driven innovation in the DA sector. Also, if the exclusive ownership right becomes the sector reality, then exclusive data exchange clusters amongst a few integrated giantsFootnote 91 would be legally protected by property rights, which would increase the risk of an oligopolistic sector structure. In this regard, an intervention with a de jure ag-data ownership right would only exacerbate existing failures.

Consequences for farmers’ trust in digital technologies and data sharing An ag-data ownership regulation would potentially increase farmers’ trust and reduce their reluctance to share data in the short run by giving them the perception that they can control any unintended re-use of data via their ownership rights. However, in the long term, the potential accumulation of data rights in the hands of a few vertically integrated agricultural giants, which have more incentives and opportunities to acquire data entitlements, might frustrate farmers far more, and irreversibly. This process might cancel out or even erode any previously increased trust in digital technologies and data sharing in the DA sector, which would not be compatible with the EU policy aim of increasing the rate of adoption of digital technologiesFootnote 92 in the sector. Therefore, the data ownership approach should be avoided in any ag-data regulation from the perspective of trust-related problems as well.

4 Seeking Fit-for-Purpose Agricultural Data Governance in the EU

The section above was about “what not to do”: use the popular concept of data ownership when regulating the DA sector. This section seeks answers to the questions of “what to do” and “how to do it” in order to address the failures identified above more effectively via a functional ag-data governance regime in the EU. In particular, the following analysis aims to (1) explore alternative legal concepts, (2) discuss possibilities for a fit-for-purpose sectoral regulation compared with the recent horizontal Data Act proposal, and (3) highlight the synergistic potential of creating a data access infrastructure to complement sectoral regulation by providing some suggestions for the forthcoming CEADS.

4.1 Understanding Alternative Legal Concepts

Before diving into the question of how a functional legal design can be configured in accordance with the needs of the emerging DA sector, it is critical to be aware of alternatives (the legal concepts of “access rights” and “co-generated data rights”)Footnote 93 to the “data ownership” understanding in the broader connected-devices setting. Thus, the following sectoral analysis will benefit from those insights when focussing on the deeper questions of how to design and allocate ag-data rights.

4.1.1 Concept of Access Rights

Many researchers, such as Hilty and others,Footnote 94 KerberFootnote 95 or Drexl,Footnote 96 propose data access rights instead of data ownership rights for the IoT setting in the broader literature not specifically focussed on agriculture. In particular, Drexl argues that data access rights might be a more appropriate focus when addressing lock-in problems.Footnote 97 The main advantages of access rights over an ownership understanding are as follows: (1) they can provide a more targeted mechanism to solve data lock-in problems; (2) they can be designed to be non-waivable to protect the entitlement holder; (3) they can be flexibly allocated to relevant rightholders with an interest-based approach; (4) they can be regulated as a stand-alone legal concept – not an exception to ownership; and (5) they are a more suitable tool for a competition-oriented regulation with the objective of enhancing new data-driven markets.Footnote 98

DrexlFootnote 99 and KerberFootnote 100 rightly suggest that designing data access rights should be sector-specific, as the needs and distinctive features of sectors and stakeholders vary considerably. Still, Drexl proposed a list of general principles for designing data access rights, which emphasises inter alia the need for a non-waivable/non-transferable statutory design,Footnote 101 broader coverage for all kinds of data for functionality of access, allocation of rights based on legitimate interest in making the best use of the data (instead of on machine ownership or usage),Footnote 102 the right to transfer data direct to third parties, precedence over trade secrets and database rights to ensure free data flow without harming device manufacturers’ confidentiality,Footnote 103 and ensuring a flexible FRAND regime in the case of a paid access design.Footnote 104 Drexl also claims that, regardless of the data rights design, regulatory intervention should be based on economic justification instead of purely considerations of justice, which can be done via an analysis of market failures.Footnote 105 In his approach, a sector-specific focus can generate optimal outcomes on the basis of targeted solutions for sectoral market failures when it comes to data access by multiple stakeholders.Footnote 106

In this regard, Drexl provided highly valuable insights and even principles for data regulation in the digital economy. Section 4.2 below aims to apply inter alia these insights and principles to the ag-data setting by filtering them according to sectoral conditions where necessary.

4.1.2 Concept of Co-Generated Data Rights

This concept was originally developed by the ELI-ALI project,Footnote 107 while the Commission mentioned “usage rights for co-generated data” in its communication on “A European strategy for data”.Footnote 108 Although the ELI-ALI project has not published its ultimate proposal, it is obvious that this idea has already been seriously considered by the Commission.Footnote 109

Some publications give valuable hints on what this concept brings for addressing data access issues in the digital economy. For instance, Thomas and Wendehorst, who are contributors to the ELI-ALI project, submitted a response to the Commission’s public consultation.Footnote 110 Their response states that many parties contribute to the generation of non-rivalrous data in many different ways, and these contributors need to be taken into account when considering data rights. This entails going beyond contractual relations and a classic understanding of exclusive ownership to maximise overall welfare, with data being economically exploited in multiple ways.Footnote 111 Beyond the types of data rights envisaged,Footnote 112 they revealed five main criteria for allocating rights for co-generated data;

  1. 1.

    the scope and nature of the contribution to data generation by the party asserting a data right;

  2. 2.

    the weight of that party’s legitimate interest in being granted said right;

  3. 3.

    the weight of any possibly conflicting interests on the part of the other party or of third parties, taking into account any potential compensation arrangements;

  4. 4.

    the interests of the general public; and

  5. 5.

    the balance of power between the party asserting the data right and the other party.Footnote 113

Although contribution to data generation is the main justification for granting rights to stakeholders vis-à-vis de facto controllers (as can be understood from the name of the proposal), there are valuable complementary elements for the allocation of data rights that increase the flexibility of the concept to cover potential specificities in different sectors.

The project also provides certain case studies from different industries, one of which relates to farm data re-use, which is important to note here. The case discusses a situation where a machine producer/ATP uses collected farm data for a purpose other than providing tailored services to the farmer.Footnote 114 If a farmer’s contribution was for an entirely different purpose, this kind of data re-use could harm the farmer. Moreover, such data generation would not have been possible if the farmer had known the purpose beforehand; the authors of the case study implied that the farmer should have the right to prevent producers/ATPs from data re-use for purposes other than generating agronomic solutions for the customer farm.Footnote 115 Although this evaluation seems reasonable at first sight, it has significant limitations and ambiguities. Limiting data (re-use) solely to providing services to the customer farm would be a highly restrictive outcome, which would not be compatible with the broader data access needs of the sector. Indeed, in this case, the application does not directly consider the five principles proposed above. Instead, the analysis focusses overly on the purpose of data sharing. There is no discussion of the balance of power or the legitimate interests of the conflicting parties or the general public.Footnote 116 Also, even if these factors are included in an analysis, weighting the conflicting interests correctly to ensure a fair conclusion is a delicate matter. Nonetheless, the five principles proposed have significant potential as a general framework (maybe with some particular reconfigurations) for sectoral data rights.

The discussions regarding the concept of data access rights explored above were more about “how to design” the rights, while the criteria explained in the ELI-ALI project complement the aspect of “how to allocate” them. In this regard, the following discussion about sectoral data regulation in agriculture will take into account both of these valuable insights.

4.2 Designing Specific Provisions to Address Specific Failures

In their seminal contribution to the fields of law and economics, Celabresi and Melamed explained why a society allocates entitlements as property,Footnote 117 liabilityFootnote 118 or inalienability rulesFootnote 119 by emphasising that, without any entitlement, “might makes right”, as the strongest or shrewdest in a conflict ultimately prevails.Footnote 120 The law’s role in deciding the prevailing party with entitlement is critical, but the mere allocation of entitlements might not be able to eradicate the “might makes right” environment.Footnote 121 Thus, different degrees of state intervention are needed, depending on the situation.Footnote 122 This section will take into account this valuable framework in addition to the recently developed concepts of “data access rights” and “co-generated data rights”Footnote 123 in order to generate preliminary insights into a fit-for-purpose ag-data governance that eliminates/prevents sectoral failures and promotes sectoral development in a tailored way, in the hope of moving discussions in the sector beyond the popular “ownership” debate.

The discussion in this section might also be relevant for the ongoing process of EU law-making. In February 2022, the Commission issued the Data Act proposal containing a horizontal framework for data sharing to unlock competition and innovation.Footnote 124 Although the regulation provides binding rules, obligations and even data rights for users of connected devices at horizontal level, it seems the details are left to follow-up sectoral data regimes, which are repeatedly mentioned as a possible means of providing “more detailed rules for the achievement of sector-specific regulatory objectives”.Footnote 125 In this regard, the suggestions for a sectoral regulation in this section will also be compared with the horizontal provisions of the recent Data Act proposal, as any sectoral intervention will follow or at least should not contradict this horizontal framework when laying down more detailed rules for the achievement of sector-specific regulatory objectives. This can also help identify to what extent the Data Act is applicable to sectoral problems, highlight the remaining issues that need to be addressed by a future sectoral regulation, and better explain how the proposed model in this paper can be used to mitigate the (remaining) sectoral problems.

4.2.1 Addressing the Lock-in Problem

To address farmers’ data lock-in problem,Footnote 126 this paper has a rather more direct proposal: there is a need for an inalienable data portability right for “farm units” in addition to complementary measures relating to data standards and interoperability in the DA sector. So, the solution needs to have more than one element, with each one filling different gaps.

The first element of this proposal is inalienability. The farm data portability right should be designed in such a way that it cannot be transferred or waived via contracts.Footnote 127 Thus, bargaining power imbalances vis-à-vis companies would not defuse the expected outcomes, unlike the risks in ownership design.Footnote 128 To compare with the design in the recent Data Act, it has to be noted that there is no clear statement of inalienability or non-waivability for the rights of data access (Art. 4) and data sharing with third parties (Art. 5) in the Data Act.Footnote 129 This creates ambiguity as to whether users’ rights can be changed via free contractual relationships. Therefore, the proposed model with two elements (inalienability and non-waivability) should be taken into account when designing follow-up sectoral intervention, in order to ensure more effective protection for original entitlements.

The scope of the portability right should be aligned with the particular needs of the DA sector. It is important to identify whether portability would be limited to raw data or include the required derived data.Footnote 130 For seamless continuity of digital agriculture services with a new supplier, the scope should be defined as broadly as possible without harming the investment incentives for companies that generate derived data. Achieving this balance is a necessary, if not easy, task for the EU rule-makers. The right to share data with third parties under Art. 5(1) of the recent Data Act is normally valid for “data generated by the use of a product or related service”, but Art. 5(8) states that “[t]rade secrets shall only be disclosed to third parties to the extent that they are strictly necessary to fulfil the purpose agreed between the user and the third party […]”. This creates some ambiguity regarding the scope of the portability design in the Data Act. One must also wonder whether other derived data (that are strictly necessary for the purpose of data transfer but are not trade secrets) can be ported to the third party or not, but Recital 14 makes clear that “[t]he data represent the digitalisation of user actions and events and should accordingly be accessible to the user, while information derived or inferred from this data, where lawfully held, should not be considered within scope of this Regulation”. However, in this case, one must wonder how raw data can be a trade secret of data holders. More importantly, the formulation in Art. 5(8) opens the way for disputes between parties to determine what is really “necessary”.Footnote 131 Sectoral regulation should be clear about such issues based on sector-specific regulatory objectives. If the aim is to fully unlock farms, all necessary data should be portable, with clear specifications of what forms of derived data are included. If the aim is to respect technology providers’ efforts to process raw data, then the exclusion should be specified to remove any ambiguities in the aforementioned provisions of the Data Act. If the aim is some kind of balance, then what is included and what is excluded should be clearly stated.

Also, a functional portability design should cover ongoing (real-time) data flowsFootnote 132 beyond the transfer of historical data sets. This would allow there to be more than one service provider or machine from different brands on the same farm. For instance, soil data is a common input for various players that provide, for example, irrigation services, fertilising services, or plant growth proposals. So, regardless of the party that collects the soil data, the real-time flow of this data to all these service providers is critical for farm interoperability with various companies/machines. Indeed, the real-time emphasis is rightly stated in the right to access (Art. 4) and the right to share data with third parties (Art. 5) of the Data Act. If a follow-up sectoral intervention were to follow this approach, it would definitely be an improvement and a step towards functional ag-data governance in the EU. Clear rights to real-time data portability should be complemented by technical measures for interoperabilityFootnote 133 amongst different machines and ATPs. This is necessary for farmers to work feasibly with multiple brands for each service or machine. More importantly, this would reduce switching costs and let farmers change ATPs or machines with less difficulty depending on their quality, price or performance, instead of being nudged to buy entire services and machines from the same group because of a lack of data standards and interoperability barriers.

It is also particularly important to dwell for a moment on the notion of the “farm unit”Footnote 134 as an entitlement holder. The distinction between farmers and farm units is not a trivial nuance. If data entitlements were given to individuals (farmers) or legal persons (such as SMEs or companies), this could hamper the development of the sector for several reasons. As these rights are proposed to be designed as inalienable in order to prevent the accumulation of data rights in the hands of a few, rights would be limited to the lifetime of entitlement holders. Even if the inalienability design were to provide an exception for inheritance instead of forfeiture of rights, non-farmer heirs could not transfer related rights to actual farmers active in the business. Furthermore, rightholders might not have heirs. Similarly, if data rights were linked with companies that run the farm business, new operators in the fields or barns could not acquire rights with the farm business for the same reason (inalienability). There is also the risk of insolvency, which would result in forfeiture of rights. Therefore, for the sake of uninterrupted agricultural production with all the necessary farm data rights, inalienable rights need to be linked to farm units, not individuals or legal persons that may be disconnected from the farm at any time. If the rights are linked to farm units, rights can always be used by the active operator regardless of the reason for the change.Footnote 135 New operators would only need to demonstrate that they are in charge of the unit. The definition of the farm unit could be based on the scope of farm data collection and the geographical location of the farm. Alternatively, there might be a registration system with a unique identification number,Footnote 136 especially for movable farming operations. An active individual or company in charge of a unit (related fields, greenhouses or barns) in which data sets are collected would, thus, be able to enforce farm data (portability) rights without interruption.Footnote 137

In the recent Data Act, the entitlement holder for the right to access data (Art. 4) and the right to share data with third parties (Art. 5) is referred to as the “user”, which is defined, in Art. 2(5), as “a natural or legal person that owns, rents or leases a product or receives a services”. As the entitlement holder is the one who originally enters into a contract with the data holder (ATP or machine producer), the same problems identified above are also valid here whenever the farm changes hands (except where the company that holds data rights as a legal person is sold as a whole). It has to be noted that the scope of Arts. 4 and 5 also has other limitations from the perspective of the sector. Only “the data generated by its use of a product or related service” can be accessed or shared with third parties.Footnote 138 The “product” refers to “a tangible, movable item, including where incorporated in an immovable item, that obtains, generates or collects data concerning its use or environment, and that is able to communicate data via a publicly available electronic communications service and whose primary function is not the storing and processing of data”,Footnote 139 while the “related service” refers to “a digital service, including software, which is incorporated in or inter-connected with a product in such a way that its absence would prevent the product from performing one of its functions”.Footnote 140 This entails that related data rights are valid only for the data generated as a consequence of, for instance, the use of agricultural machines or connected services that make the machines functional.Footnote 141 This excludes services provided by ATPs that are mostly independent of farm machine functionality, and thus data under their control. Also, the part of the “user” definition “that owns, rents or leases a product”Footnote 142 may exclude some of the farm machinery data access in the practice of the sector. Sometimes, farm machinery is not rented or leased itself but a company that owns farm machinery is hired to carry out, for instance, the harvesting operation, in which case there is no control over the machine in terms of rent or lease. This entails that farmers would not be able to force the machine producer to access or port the related data. Nor could the service rendered be considered a “related service”, because it is not related to the functioning of a “product” (farm machinery) but is about harvesting the crops. In any case, it is unlikely that the related framework of the Data Act can be applied without any difficulty here.Footnote 143 Therefore, a sectoral intervention should move beyond all these limitations by taking into account the proposed (ag-data portability) entitlement model above.

4.2.2 Addressing Data Fragmentation and the Broader Data Access Puzzle

To address the fragmentation of data sets and the broader data access puzzle in the sector,Footnote 144 the allocation of access rights is the main challenge. The ELI-ALI principlesFootnote 145 provide a valuable set of criteria that can be applied in the ag-data setting with any necessary reconfigurations based on sectoral needs. As the Data Act does not allocate any rights for third parties to let them access relevant data sets directly,Footnote 146 the model proposed in this section might be useful for lawmakers if they are considering a broader sectoral data access regime beyond farms’ data portability.

Various entities (besides farmers) have interests in accessing farm data. For farmland owners, details about the fields, such as fertility rates, soil data or harvesting information, are important when, for instance, they cultivate the soil themselves after a rental period or advertise the land for new tenants. Machine producers or leasing firms may demand access to the technical performance of agricultural machines,Footnote 147 which might cross the line into farm data sets. Banks or financial institutions may want to access farm data sets when farmers apply for financial support.Footnote 148 This causes much ambiguityFootnote 149 regarding who can access what data, under what conditions and for what period, as well as whether they can re-use the data without the farm’s consent. Moreover, the attribution or allocation of rights to re-use farm data can be more complicated than it seems. For instance, if a contagious (plant or animal) disease comes from a neighbouring area, preventive measures can be taken only by accessing data sets for the entire region. When various farmers work with various ATPs, none of them individually would be able to foresee a threat. These data sets, for instance, might be open to all, but the open data model might affect data collection and investment incentives detrimentally through free-riding. Therefore, instead of having to open up entire data sets in the same market, service providers might be obliged to disclose when they detect any contagious disease. While only one example of a particular situation, this demonstrates how there might be a need for a dynamic mechanism to address different needs or newly emerging situations beyond the ex-ante allocation of rights and obligations, especially for those other than farmers.Footnote 150

Proprietary data (producers’ exclusive information on their products such as agricultural inputs) and complementary data sets (on environmental conditions)Footnote 151 are also important to consider. For complementary data, access is possible via non-rivalrous environmental data providers, and the EU policy seems to be as open as possible for these data sets.Footnote 152 However, accessing exclusively controlled farm data and proprietary data sets is an issue,Footnote 153 especially for non-integrated (weaker) rivals. As smart farming solutions reduce farmers’ consumption of agricultural input (seeds, fertilisers, herbicides, etc.), integrated agricultural input producers are strategically entering the DA sector to compensate for their losses from their traditional business, and they have a significant competitive advantage, especially in input usage prescription markets.Footnote 154 As rightly argued in the broader IoT data literature, although data holders have a legitimate interest in developing their own business model with their data, third-party data access should also be possible when identifiable interests justify this access.Footnote 155 On the one hand, providing broader data access is beneficial for competitiveness and innovation in the sector. On the other hand, mandatory access to proprietary data sets may cause free-riding and reduce further investment incentives for the upstream input producers.Footnote 156 Policymakers should keep these delicate dynamics in mind when designing regulation in the sector.

As the allocation of rights is a big challenge in this confusing puzzle of data access in the sector with its variety of stakeholders, motives and data sets, sectoral regulation could generate a certain set of principles for data re-use instead of relying on a heavy-handed data access rights allocation. These principles could be developed on the basis of the valuable insights of the ELI-ALI project discussed aboveFootnote 157 by taking into account the distinctive conditions of the DA sector.Footnote 158 This kind of system would provide a more flexible model.Footnote 159 Thus, identifying and addressing (and possibly changing) legitimate interests could be more feasible, with follow-up insights based on deeper economic and empirical sectoral data.

4.2.3 Ensuring Farmers’ Trust

To address farmers’ trust-related problems,Footnote 160 defensive rights such as consent for re-use might play a role despite negative appearances. So, to achieve an optimal solution, there is a need for a well-balanced and nuanced mechanism.

What farmers fear most is the unintended re-use of farm data by third parties in order to manipulate (increase) the price of commodities, agricultural inputs or land rents according to the identifiable dependencies of farmers.Footnote 161 Similarly, it is mentioned that intermediaries in the food supply chain might also reduce purchase prices for agricultural products, for instance by looking at harvesting estimations, and this would further diminish smallholders’ bargaining power vis-à-vis big buyers.Footnote 162 Some farmers do not want insurance companies, advertisers or even consumers and the government to access “their” data.Footnote 163 So, policymakers have to decide whether farms should have rights to prevent others from accessing or re-using the data, and if so, the extent and limits thereof.

Defensive data rights could theoretically increase farmers’ weak bargaining power, and result in a feeling of control that could positively affect farmers’ rate of adoption of digital technologies and might decrease their hesitation in sharing data. However, defensive data rights could also create an additional barrier to the free flow of data in the sector.Footnote 164 Drexl addresses the same concern in the connected-devices setting in general with his suggestion to provide effective trade secrets protection instead of an exclusive data ownership understanding,Footnote 165 but the demands of farmers stated above go far beyond the protection of trade secrets. So, policymakers have to balance societal welfare gainsFootnote 166 from non-exclusive access to ag-data against farmers’ welfare gains from defensive rights.Footnote 167 Only when the latter overrides the former, might exclusive/defensive rights on ag-data be justified.Footnote 168 It is also important to note that not all concerns of farmers are legitimate. In particular, demands to prevent government access seem related to fear of certain sanctions, such as those relating to environmental obligations or CAP payments. In this regard, the rule-makers should ensure that they respond proportionately to an overriding legitimate interest without excessively harming other stakeholders’ interests or jeopardising the enforcement of other public policies.Footnote 169

Recalling the broader data access needs, some hybrid models can also be considered, such as prohibiting certain actions for data re-use rather than granting farmers complete preventive rights. Indeed, Art. 4(6) of the recently released Data Act proposal can be categorised under this suggestion despite its limitations. It states that “[t]he data holder shall only use any non-personal data generated by the use of a product or related service on the basis of a contractual agreement with the user. The data holder shall not use such data generated by the use of the product or related service to derive insights about the economic situation, assets and production methods of or the use by the user that could undermine the commercial position of the user in the markets in which the user is active”. Indeed, this seems a direct response to farmers’ concerns.Footnote 170 However, the first sentence restricts all kinds of data re-use possibilities to that with the contractual agreement between the users and data holders. Without it, the sentence that follows it could have been enough to address the concerns. Thus, other data re-use could have been possible if it does not harm the commercial position of users. Also, the scope is again limited to “data generated by products or related services” and, owing to the inapplicability of this definition to data stored and processed by ATPs, would only cover machine producer and farmer relationships. Nonetheless, this can help increase farmers’ trust in data sharing.Footnote 171 A sectoral design should ensure that the scope of a similar provision will cover all farm of data sets unlike the limited model in the existing text of the Data Act. In particular, when designing sectoral intervention, lawmakers should carefully re-evaluate the restriction of other data re-use possibilities that do not harm users by considering the broader ag-data access needs inside and outside of the farm-to-fork chain.

Furthermore, Art. 34 of the Data Act states that the Commission will develop non-binding model contractual terms. Model contracts – if widely applied in the sector – would also increase farmers’ trust in adopting digital technologies and sharing data. However, it has to be kept in mind that the wide adoption of model contracts is possible only when the benefits of such voluntary action exceed the advantages of exclusive control of data and locked-in users for companies. So, it is not rational to expect too much from non-binding tools unless market dynamics force the players to adopt them, for instance as a result of competition on better contractual terms. This kind of market pressure can still be observed in the sector though, considering the fact that the digital transformation of European farmers is still in its early phases.Footnote 172

4.3 Synergistic Potential of a Complementary Ag-Data Infrastructure

Sector-specific rulemaking to address particular concerns is a necessary step, but might not be sufficient in itself. For instance, granting a clear portability right can remove the legal part of the lock-in problem, but not the technical barriers regarding interoperability and data standards per se. Focussing on access rights instead of an exclusive ownership understanding can overcome the risk of the de jure isolation of already fragmented ag-data sets, but cannot in itself create an equal and easy-access data platform for all stakeholders. The ex-ante allocation of rights is theoretically possible, but it is difficult to respond to each particular data re-use request from a variety of changing access seekers. Having a clear set of rights would positively affect farmers’ trust, but possible enforcement problems (especially owing to technical incompatibilities) might create frustrations. For all these reasons, this section argues that designing sectoral rules should be complemented by a central ag-data access infrastructure run by a public authority, which could also be responsible for enforcing the rules.

The Commission’s plan to create a Common European Agricultural Data Space (CEADS)Footnote 173 may be critical in this regard. As the details of the CEADS were not yet clear,Footnote 174 the CommissionFootnote 175 organised an expert workshop entitled “How to build a ‘Common European Agricultural Data Space’” in September 2020 together with IT and data specialists and interested participants working in the agri-food sector.Footnote 176 The main aim of the workshop was to collect stakeholders’ views on the question of how to realise data interoperability in practice to reach a functional common data space in agriculture.Footnote 177 The workshop report concludes that trust is one of the main issues to be addressed for ensuring farmers’ involvement and motivation (to share data), apart from the compatibility and interoperability of existing data sharing mechanisms. It seems several data standards will remain, but a need to increase dialogue is emphasised. A federate arrangement of existing ag-data systems was considered a feasible option as opposed to creating central architecture from scratch, and this would require public-private cooperation.Footnote 178 Many participants such as IDSA,Footnote 179 DFKI,Footnote 180 AIOTIFootnote 181 and ILVOFootnote 182 focussed on data ownership or data sovereigntyFootnote 183 for farmers as the central legal concept, in line with the general trend in the sector discussed above.Footnote 184 With all these preliminary discussions, the workshop was a first step towards reaching the insights required for optimal implementation of a CEADS instead of solving all the issues. Indeed, plans were announced for further events.Footnote 185 In December 2021, the Commission organised an information session on the CEADS.Footnote 186 It was declared that the aim was “facilitating the trustworthy sharing and pooling of data for the sector, by creating a single data space, which in turn will be based on a set of data spaces/platforms”, and that there was a need for a clear governance structure and business models to achieve this objective.Footnote 187 Ensuring “alignment with the design of the European data spaces in other sectors with respect to common elements, such as the data space building blocks and reference architecture, some common standards, and protocols” was also stated as critical.Footnote 188 Stakeholders emphasised various points, such as the need for design principles, sovereign infrastructure, the inclusion of stakeholders, technical security and conformance measures to ensure trust and reliability, and standards and protocols for data exchange for the CEADS, in addition to a need for consent rights and digital identity for farmers, the integration of various ag-data types, the stimulation of dialogue among stakeholders, and addressing all stakeholders’ expectations.Footnote 189 The following analysis aims to contribute to the ongoing discussions to create a bindingFootnote 190 data infrastructure for the sector,especially from the perspective of building functional and holistic ag-data governance in the EU.

4.3.1 Addressing the Lock-in Problem

To address the lock-in problem, the CEADS should prioritise ensuring sectoral data standards and interoperability,Footnote 191 which can be a natural consequence if data access rights are enforced via this central hub, as stakeholders would have to align their data sharing formats with the infrastructure’s requirements in time. So, possible obligations regarding technical standards in the sectoral regulation could be implemented via a central data access hub. If the CEADS were able to provide a functional ecosystem in this regard – a transparent central data hub accessible to all, together with a clear ag-data regulation – it would reduce data-related asymmetries between market players. This could in turn help farmers to choose, split and switch the “smart farming” operations on their farms more easily, as dictated by their needs. In such an environment, the main determinant of competitive power would come from better services or more advanced data analytics technologies, instead of the first-mover advantage and data lock-in.Footnote 192

The recent Data Act provides interoperability obligations for operators of data spaces, cloud service providers and smart contracts.Footnote 193 Therefore, these provisions will have to be taken into account when designing the CEADS as well. However, this does not mean that these obligations will be applicable to ATPs or agricultural machines to force them to generate common standards. In other words, direct interoperability in farm operations amongst different machines and ATP services still has to be solved.Footnote 194 Comparing what has been envisioned in this section with the Data Act interoperability provisions, the statements above refer to the indirect effect of mandatory central data access hub usage when enforcing data portability rights in order to naturally create interoperability standards amongst stakeholders (including ATPs and agricultural machines) over time. However, the Data Act’s right to share data with third parties (Art. 5) refers to direct B2B data transfer independent of the interoperability obligations on operators of data spaces (Art. 28).Footnote 195 Therefore, when designing a sectoral intervention, farm interoperability with different machines and digital services (ATPs) should be ensured by imposing the necessary technical obligations on machine producers and ATPsFootnote 196 as well as operators of data spaces, and also taking into account the portability enforcement via the CEADS suggestion above.

4.3.2 Addressing Data Fragmentation and the Broader Data Access Puzzle

To address the fragmentation of data sets and the broader data access puzzle within the sector, a central data infrastructure might bring some additional opportunities. A “one-stop-shop” central data access optionFootnote 197 with a clear catalogue of data setsFootnote 198 as opposed to the dispersed data sets within the isolated data silos of a variety of companies is the most prominent benefit in this regard. The CEADS could be an important infrastructural base for responding to various stakeholders’ complicated data access needs. It is expected to ease further data access and increase sectoral momentum and innovation. However, digital services often evolve rapidly, and regulatory intervention might not match this pace in every setting.Footnote 199 So, instead of trying to achieve a nearly impossible quality standard of tech neutralityFootnote 200 or future-proofness for ag-data regulation, some criteria can be determined for third-party data access and data re-use, with a non-exhaustive list of access seekers and access modalities.Footnote 201 A sectoral authorityFootnote 202 could be constituted to manage these requests on the basis of certain principles. The ELI-ALI principles explored in Sect. 4.1.2 above could be a valuable starting point by also taking into account sectoral conditions in order to amend some nuances. The sectoral authority might declare and reconfigure third-party access or re-use modalities (such as access feesFootnote 203 or the scope, time and conditions of re-use) according to need (which might change over time). This authority could also run the CEADS, investigate breaches, impose sanctions, and thus be responsible for the enforcement of rights via the technical infrastructure of the CEADS by ensuring neutrality,Footnote 204 data security,Footnote 205 and the fair enforcement of ag-data rights.Footnote 206

Indeed, the recent Data Act regulates “competent authorities” that process complaints and impose penalties for breaches.Footnote 207 What it envisions is multiple “competent authorities” designated by the Member States instead of one central European authority.Footnote 208 Article 31(2)(b) of the Data Act further states that “for specific sectoral data exchange issues related to the implementation of this Regulation, the competence of sectoral authorities shall be respected”. This is a positive development towards comprehensive ag-data governance in the EU, as it explicitly provides a green light for this paper’s above proposal. However, while the sectoral authority’s powers should not be limited to the enforcement of the Data Act, it should be responsible for enforcing future sectoral regulation and the management of the CEADS, because frictionless interaction between the rules and the technical infrastructure is critical for overcoming complicated problems in the sector that arise for legal, technical, contractual or economic reasons. Also, fragmented authorities in each Member State may generate problems in terms of coherence in European ag-data governance. Therefore, a central European ag-data authority that is responsible for coherent enforcement might be useful,Footnote 209 and is also critical for the consistency of penalties for breaches across Europe, as Art. 33(1) leaves the regulation of penalties to the Member States, stating that “[t]he penalties provided for shall be effective, proportionate and dissuasive”. Member States are responsible for notifying the Commission of such rules or any amendments thereto.Footnote 210 However, these are generic statements and there is no clear framework about maximum/minimum fines or details for their calculation methods. It might not be desirable to have very different sanctions for the same action across the Member States. Therefore, at least providing a detailed framework to ensure that the Member States act coherently is critical even if the lawmakers prefer not to impose a uniform penalty mechanism across Europe.Footnote 211 A follow-up sectoral intervention might need to take into account these nuances beyond the substantial suggestions made above for effective enforcement.

4.3.3 Ensuring Farmers’ Trust

To address the farmers’ trust issue, a neutral public authority to run the CEADS and be responsible for enforcing the sectoral rules might be helpful. It might increase trust inter alia amongst farmers as it would not have separate commercial interests in data sets. However, there might still be some hesitation towards public bodies or governments.Footnote 212 So, to increase trust, wider stakeholder participationFootnote 213 (by, for instance, including the stakeholders, especially farmers’ representatives, in the management or at least the auditing body of the sectoral authority) should be ensured when setting up the sectoral authority.

Despite said limitations/ambiguities of the provisions on “competent authorities” in the recent Data Act, it is definitely a positive step, which might generate trust amongst farmers. In particular, Art. 31(3) of the Data Act provides horizontal tasks and powers when designing the competent authorities, such as promoting awareness among users and entities, handling complaints arising from alleged violations, imposing dissuasive financial penalties, and cooperating with other competent authorities to ensure consistent application. Each of these actions can help build trust amongst farmers, especially when enforcement is aligned with sectoral needs in future sectoral interventions.

5 Conclusion

Digital transformation in agriculture has opened up various opportunities thanks to data-driven agronomic solutions, but it has also brought about new ambiguities and concerns. The lack of clarity regarding who has what rights to non-personal agricultural data causes a “might makes right”Footnote 214 situtaion, with various market failures including farmer lock-in, exclusionary data clustering within a fragmented data environment, a variety of unsatisfied access seekers, and lack of trust on the part of farmers in sharing data or even adopting digital technologies. The sectoral literature and voluntary initiatives predominantly envisage “data ownership” rights for farmers and link all third-party data re-use to decisions by data-owning farmers.Footnote 215 This paper discussed the possible consequences of a data ownership regime for agricultural data and demonstrated that an ag-data ownership regime is unlikely to change the status quo and solve sectoral problems in the DA sector, as it does not solve underlying bargaining power imbalances.Footnote 216 More importantly, such a legal design could even exacerbate existing failures, mainly due to the alienability and exclusivity features of a property rights understanding. Transferable ownership rights for ag-data could be accumulated in the hands of a few integrated agricultural conglomerates regardless of the original allocation of entitlements. These few data owners could acquire exclusive rights, which could be used to prevent any kind of data portability, access or re-use, which means more dependent farmers, legally protected data isolation/clustering and, thus, unsatisfied access seekers, not to mention a deeper distrust amongst stakeholders. As this design might bring more harm than benefit, this paper opposes ownership or any form of traditional property rights understanding for regulating the emerging DA sector.Footnote 217

For the “what to do” part of the research, this paper first explored the alternative concepts of data access rightsFootnote 218 and co-generated data rights,Footnote 219 which do not carry the same limitations as data ownership. Although originally developed in the broader connected devices literature, some of the functionalities involved can be useful in an ag-data setting, as well. The paper concluded that, instead of adopting one of these concepts directly, each sectoral failure or particular progressive policy aim should be addressed through specific data rights, which might include different elements from various concepts, including but not limited to data access, portability, re-use and other measures if needed – leading to a flexible and fit-for-purpose design for possible sectoral data regulation.

In particular, an inalienable right to data portability for “farm units” might remove the legal ambiguity of the lock-in problem. This right should be applicable to both historical and real-time data flows as well as to raw and essential processed data sets in order to ensure functional service/machine switching and interoperability. Linking inalienable data rights and individual farmers or companies might result in the forfeiture of rights because people can die and legal persons can be dissolved. Instead, linking inalienable rights to farm units (from which data has been collected) could ensure the continuity of agricultural production even if the person or company that runs the farm business changes for any reason. To address the technical part of the problem, clear obligations should be imposed on machine producers and ATPs in the sector in order to achieve certain interoperability and data standards. However, a sole regulation might not be enough for this. The creation of the CEADS as a central data access hub could be a significant catalyst in this regard. If this infrastructure were to be the common gateway to access-related data sets, then standards and the interoperability of systems/machines would emerge naturally over time. Thus, it would be possible for farmers to change services or work with multiple brands at the same time.

Data access is a critical issue not just for farmers, but for various players inside and outside of the farm-to-fork chain. It is essential to design a flexible mechanism to address broader access needs. It might not be realistic to determine or foresee all the legitimate access seekers ex-ante, though. So, determining a set of criteria for third-party data re-use conditions could be considered instead of the nearly impossible task of future-proofing the ex-ante allocation of rights to numerous entities. The ELI-ALI principlesFootnote 220 could be an invaluable starting point for determining general principles for third-party access by also taking into account distinct sectoral conditions. To respond flexibly to possibly changing needs in this dynamic and still emerging sector, the access modalities could be reconfigured by the sectoral authority over time with possibly deeper economic and empirical insights – of course within the margins of the main set of criteria that needs to be designed carefully within the sectoral regulation. Still, a non-exhaustive list of data access situations might be useful at first. In implementing this model, a well designed CEADS might play a complementary role. A “one-stop-shop” data access gatewayFootnote 221 run by a neutral sectoral authority could be very useful for addressing the data access puzzle in the sector by ensuring that access seekers can reach the data required without difficulty via a central access hub.

To address farmers’ trust issues, a consent mechanism or right to prevent some data re-use could create a feeling of control for farmers and might result in higher rates of adoption of digital technologies and less concern about data sharing. However, this would inherently create a legal barrier to free data flow in the sector. The rule-makers should consider these two conflicting outcomes on the basis of deeper insights acquired through a comprehensive investigation of the sector. If defensive rights for farmers are considered inevitable for building trust amongst them and fostering digital transformation, the boundaries of such rights should be carefully contemplated so as not to undermine broader access needs. Instead of granting farmers preventive rights, an alternative could be to provide strict data re-use conditions.Footnote 222 In addition to rules, rights and obligations, a neutral public authorityFootnote 223 to run the CEADS could also be helpful if it is designed with broader stakeholder participation, including farmers’ representatives. Thus, farmers might have an indirect say in data re-use conditions or could, at least, participate in the processes, which would help establish trust.Footnote 224

The recently adopted Data Act provides horizontal provisions including a data access right for users (Art. 4), the right to share data with third parties (Art. 5), obligations on third parties (Art. 6) and data holders (Art. 8), interoperability obligations on operators of data spaces (Art. 28), provisions about competent authorities (Arts. 31–33) and model contractual terms (Art. 34). The general framework, with its holistic approach to covering all relevant issues, is valuable. However, as explained above, the definitions of the core notions and the scope of the provisions do not fully cover ag-data issues.Footnote 225 It seems that keeping the scope of horizontal intervention limited is intentional, as many signs point to future sectoral interventions with more detailed rules for achieving sector-specific regulatory objectives. In this regard, although providing binding rules, obligations and rights, at the horizontal level is a significant step towards the fit-for-purpose European agricultural data governance,Footnote 226 it is difficult to say this on its own will be the ultimate cure for the sector in its existing form. Therefore, the remaining issuesFootnote 227 need to be addressed in a follow-up sectoral regulation with targeted provisions, using the prominent problems of the sector as a benchmark for the evaluation as proposed above.

Further studies might also be useful to deepen insights into achieving a holistic ag-data regime. The optimal allocation of entitlements (especially for parties other than farmers), data re-use conditions, and the existence or level of farmers’ preventive powers are still important questions to be addressed separately by law/economics studies. Despite the synergistic potential explained, the idea of a sectoral regulation and the creation of the CEADS are discussed separately. They should be taken into account jointly to realise the synergistic benefits of a complementary design. Beyond that, governing agricultural data might have potential effects on various policies, such as the CAP,Footnote 228 food safety and traceability regulations,Footnote 229 public, animal and plant health/welfare,Footnote 230 and environmental policies.Footnote 231 Therefore, it is critical to take into account all relevant aspects when shaping the ag-data governance regime in the EU in order to ensure frictionless interaction amongst policies and maximise societal welfare with the help of digital transformation in agriculture.