Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Knowledge Production and Economic Development: Empirical Evidences

  • Published:
Journal of the Knowledge Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper throws some light on the relationship between domestic knowledge production and economic development for a group of countries in different periods of time. In particular, this article presents a statistical analysis using the Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) method and corroborates that there is a strong relationship between economic development and the domestic capacity to produce new knowledge. We use as a proxy for domestic knowledge production the patent application by residents and the metric of income level used was the GDP per capita. We show that an increase in the stock of knowledge produced by residents is an important policy to generate income in an economic system once residents are able to appropriate the gains for the use of this new knowledge. Accordingly, there is a dual effect: Knowledge stock growth has a positive impact on GDP, and GDP growth leads to increases in resources to be used for new knowledge generation. In times of global value chains and capital mobility, incentivizing creative imitation, absorption, and production of new knowledge seems to be a valid strategy for less industrialized countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Residents’ Patent applications can then be used as a proxy of the level of technological competence of a country but also the level of domestic knowledge that is appropriated by residents.

  2. According to Borrás and Edquist (2015, p. 4), individual competences—“acquisition of information, knowledge, understanding, and skills by individual people, trough participation in some form of education and training, whether formal (for example in educational institutes) or informal (for example competence building (‘learning-by-doing’) in the workplace)”—are also important for innovation.

  3. “How technology evolves” is the central question in technology (…). Without evolution—without a sense of common relatedness—technologies seem to be born independently and improve independently. Each must come from some unexplained mental process, some form of “creativity” or “thinking outside the box” that brings it into existence and separately develops it. With evolution (…), new technologies would be birthed in some precise way from previous ones, albeit with considerable mental midwifing, and develop through some understood process of adaptation. In other words, if we could understand evolution, we could understand that most mysterious of processes: innovation” (Arthur 2011, p. 15).

  4. For an assessment on Science and Technology metrics, see Geisler (2000). For a critique on the use of patents as an economic indicator, see Desrochers (1998).

  5. It is worth mentioning that a patent entitles an eligible right used to defend (by legal protection) competitive advantages of successful innovative companies, it does not constitute, necessary or sufficient condition to ensure the success of innovation or favorable appropriability. The establishment of a legal monopoly does not automatically translate into an effective economic monopoly position (Possas and Mello 2009). Therefore, a patent per se does not guarantee ex ante that there will be an economic monopoly position for the owner of the patent. It will depend obviously of its relevance to the productive sector and if it can be applied in production affecting the costs and/or differentiating products. What is important to mention is that having a patent does not mean the company has innovated or will ever innovate. According to Dressler (2012), due to the lack of a sufficient economic theory of patents, an assessment of the economic effects of patents cannot be conclusive, thus, any economic justification of a patent system is biased.

  6. For a further analysis about the Brazilian case compared to the South Korean, please see Romero et al. (2015).

  7. Patent application (or deposit) is a request pending at national intellectual property office for the grant of a patent for the invention described and claimed by that deposit. Prior to publication (generally patents are published at about 18 months after the earliest priority date of the application), the application is confidential to the national intellectual property office. After publication, depending on each office rules, certain parts of the application file may remain confidential. The publication of a patent application marks the date at which it becomes publicly available. Once the patent application complies with the requirements of each national intellectual property office, the patent will be granted/issued/registered.

  8. Information available at <www.managingip.com/Article/3501851/Brazils-battle-against-the-patent-backlog.html>

  9. Despite the usual understanding about patent (proxy for knowledge production) defining economic development, some studies show that the increase on trade liberalization and FDI tends to establish a realignment between good production in developing countries and knowledge production in developed ones (LAI 2007; Branstetter et al. 2007). On these results rest out the additional hypothesis of a new causality direction from economic development to the capability of generating domestic knowledge. The findings in this paper are not conclusive to answer these questions.

  10. Innovations systems are classified as Albuquerque (1999) in a mature and immature tipology.

  11. They were not observed here the distinct combinations for infrastructure, open trade and financial system.

  12. The USA, Germany, Canada, France, Italy, Japan and the UK.

  13. Many studies corroborate this point such as Kim (1997) and Laplane and Ferreira (2013).

References

  • Albuquerque, E. M. (1999). National systems of innovation and non-OECD. Countries: notes about a rudimentary and tentative “tipology”. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 19(76), 35–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allred, B., & Park, W. (2007). Patent rights and innovative activity: evidence from national and firm-level data. J Int Bus Stud, 38(6), 878–900.

    Google Scholar 

  • Archibugi, D., & Filippetti, A. (2010). The globalisation of intellectual property rights: four learned lessons and four theses. Global Policy, 1(2), 137–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (2011). The nature of technology. What it is and how it evolves (Vol. 246). New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J., & Maskin, E. (2009). Sequential innovation, patents and imitation. RAND J Econ, 40(4), 611–635.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borrás, S., & Edquist, C. (2015). Education, training and skills in innovation policy. Science & Public Policy, 42(2), 215–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter, L, Fisman, R., Foley, C. F., Saggi, K. (2007). Intellectual property rights, imitation, and foreign direct investment: theory and evidence. NBER Working Paper Series. Working Paper 13033. Able in: http://www.nber.org/papers/w13033.

  • Chang, H.-J. (2003). Trade and industrial policy issues. In H.-J. Chang (Ed.), Rethinking development economics (pp. 257–276). London: Anthem Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (2004). Chutando a escada: a estratégia do desenvolvimento em perspectiva histórica (p. 268). São Paulo: Editora da UNESP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (2009). Maus samaritanos: o mito do livre-comércio e a história secreta do capitalismo (p. 258). Rio de Janeiro: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Puttitanun, T. (2005). Intellectual property rights and innovation in developing countries. J Dev Econ, 78(2), 474–493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesnais, F. (1996). A mundialização do capital (p. 335). Editora Xamã: São Paulo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesnais, F. (2010). National systems of innovation, foreign direct investment and operations of multinational enterprises. In B. Å. Lundvall (Ed.), National Systems of innovation: toward a theory of innovation and interactive learning (pp. 259–292). New York: Anthem Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiarini, T., & Silva, A. L. G. (2016). Intellectual property rights and innovation system: some lessons from Brazil. International Journal of Innovation and Learning, 20, 265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiarini, T., Rapini, M. S., Silva, L. A. (2016). Access to knowledge and catch-up: Exploring some intellectual property rights data from Brazil and South Korea. Science and Public Policy (pp. 1–16) doi:10.1093/scipol/scw034.

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q, 35(1), 128–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coriat, B. (2002).O novo regime de propriedade intelectual e a sua dimensão imperialista: implicações para as relações Norte/Sul. In: CASTRO, A. C. (Orgs.). Desenvolvimento em Debate: Novos Rumos para o Desenvolvimento no Mundo. Desafios do Crescimento: instituições, investimento, competitividade e tecnologia. Rio de Janeiro, p.375–396.

  • Correa, C. M. (1997). New intellectual standards for intellectual property: impact on technology flows and innovation in developing countries. Science & Public Policy, 24(2), 79–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desrochers, P. (1998). On the abuse of patents as economic indicators. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 1(4), 51–74.

  • Dosi, G. (1988). Source, procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation. J Econ Lit, 26, 1120–1171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dressler, M. (2012). Assessing the economic effects of patents. J Knowl Econ, 3(3), 294–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C. (2000). Systems of innovation approaches – their emergence and characteristics. In C. Edquist & M. Mckelvey (Eds.), Systems of innovation: growth, competitiveness and employment (p. 38). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., & Srholec, M. (2008). National innovation systems, capabilities and economic development. Research Policy 37, 1417–1435.

  • Geisler, E. (2000). The metrics of science and technology. Wesrport (Connecticut): Quorum Books.

  • Gereffi, G. (1999). International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain. Journal of International Economics v, 48(1), 37–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hudson, J., & Minea, A. (2013). Innovation, intellectual property rights, and economic development: a unified empirical investigation. World Dev, 46, 66–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., Johnson, B., Lorenz, E., & Lundvall, B. Å. (2007). Forms of knowledge and modes of innovation. Res Policy, 36(5), 680–693.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kascheva, M. (2013). The role of foreign direct investment in the relation between intellectual property rights and growth. Oxf Econ Pap, 1–22.

  • Klevorick, A. K., Levin, R. C., Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1995). On the sources and significance of interindustry differences in technological opportunities. Res Policy, 24(2), 185–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, L. (1997). Imitation to Innovation: the dynamics of Korea's technological learning. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, L., & Nelson, R. R. (2005). Tecnologia, Aprendizado e Inovação: as experiências de economias de industrialização recente (p. 503). Campinas: Editora Unicamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • LAI, E. L.-C. (2007). The theory of international policy coordination in the protection of ideas. In K. E. Maskus (Ed.), Intellectual Property, Growth and Trade (Frontiers of economics and globalization, volume 2) (pp. 357–389). Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

  • Lall, S. (1980). Developing countries as exporters of industrial technology. Res Policy, 9, 24–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laplane, M., Ferreira, A. N (2013). Padrões de crescimento, investimento e processos inovadores: o caso da Coreia do Sul. In: BIELSCHOWSKY, R. (Orgs.). Padrões de desenvolvimento econômico (1950–2008): América Latina, Ásia e Rússia. Brasília: Centro de Gestão e Estudos Estratégicos (CGEE), 2, cap. 10, p.491–556.

  • Longest, K. C., & Vaisey, S. (2008). Fuzzy: a program for performing qualitative comparative analyses (QCA) in Stata. Stata J, 8(1), 79–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B.-A., Johnson, B., Andersen, E. S., & Dalum, B. (2002). National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Res Policy, 31, 213–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1993). Technological regimes and firm behavior. Ind Corp Chang, 2(1), 45–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marengo, L., Pasquali, C., Valente, M., & Dosi, G. (2012). Appropriability, patents, and rates of innovation in complex products industries. Econ Innov New Technol, 21(8), 753–773.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, K. E. (2000) Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

  • Michalopoulos, Constantine. (2003) Special and Differential Treatment of Developing Countries in TRIPS. Geneva: QUNO. http://www.geneva.quno.info/pdf/SDT(Euro)final.pdf. Access in 09/05/2016.

  • Mowery, D. C., & Rosenberg, N. (2005). Trajetórias de Inovação: A mudança tecnológica nos Estados Unidos da América no século XX (p. 230). Campinas, SP: Editora Unicamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Pack, H. (1999). The Asian miracle and modern growth theory. Economic Journal, 109, 416–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. (2005). [1982] Uma teoria evolucionária da mudança econômica (p. 632). Editora da UNICAMP: Campinas (SP).

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1992).The role of firm differences in an evolutionary theory of technical advance. In: MAGNUSSON, L.. Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics.

  • Pack, H., & Westphal, L. E. (1996). Industrial Estrategy and technological change: theory versus reality. J Dev Econ, 22(87–128), 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. (1973). International patenting and the less-developed countries. Econ J, 83(331), 768–786.

    Google Scholar 

  • Possas, M., Mello, M.T.L. (2009) .Regulação da Concorrência e Propriedade Intelectual: conflitos e convergências. Seminário Internacional PPED “Promovendo Respostas Estratégicas à Globalização”, Rio de Janeiro, novembro de (mimeo).

  • Ragin, C. C. (1987). The Comparative Method. Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative strategies. Berkeley, Los Angeles and London: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ragin, C. C. (2000). Fuzzy-set social sciences. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Ragin, C. C. (2006). Set relations in social research: evaluating the consistency and coverage. Polit Anal, 14, 291–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ribeiro, L. C., Ruiz, R. M., Bernardes, A. T., & Albuquerque, E. M. (2006). Science in the developing world: running twice as fast? Computing in Science and Engineering, 8, 81–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rihoux, B., & Ragin, C. C. (2009). Configurational Comparative Methods: Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and Related Techniques. Applied social research method series (p. 118). California: SAGE Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romero, J. P., Freitas, E., Britto, G., Coelho, C (2015) . The Great Divide: The Paths of Industrial Competitiveness in Brazil and South Korea. Texto para Discussão n. 519. Belo Horizonte (MG): Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional (CEDEPLAR), Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais (UFMG).

  • Sabato, J. A. (1979). Ensayos de Campera. Buenos Aires: Juarez Editor, 172.

  • Schneider, P. (2005). International trade, economic growth and intellectual property rights: a panel data study of developed and developing countries. J Dev Econ, 78(2), 529–547.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1985). A Teoria do Desenvolvimento Econômico. Uma investigação sobre lucros, capital, crédito, juro e o ciclo econômico. São Paulo: Nova Cultural, [1911]. 168p.

  • SelL, S. (2004). Intellectual property and public policy in historical perspective: contestation and settlement. Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review, 38, 267–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sell, S., & May, C. (2001). Moments in law: contestation and settlement in the history of intellectual property. Rev Int Polit Econ, 8(3), 467–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tigre, P. B., Ripper, M. D., Roselino, J. E. S. (2010). Tecnologias da Informação e Comunicação (TIC). In: Cassiolato, J. E. (Orgs.) Perspectivas do investimento na economia do conhecimento. Rio de Janeiro: Synergia, cap. 4, p.85–144.

  • Vaitsos, C. (1972). Patents revisited: their function in developing countries. The Journal of Development Studies, 9(1), 71–97.

  • Viotti, E. B. (2002). National Learning Systems: a new approach on technical change in late industrializing economies and evidences from the cases of Brazil and South Korea. Technological Forecasting & Social Change, 69, 653–680.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

The opinions expressed herein are those of only the authors. They do not necessarily reflect the views of, or involve any responsibility for, the institutions to which they are affiliated. Any errors are the fault of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tulio Chiarini.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Caliari, T., Chiarini, T. Knowledge Production and Economic Development: Empirical Evidences. J Knowl Econ 12, 1–22 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-016-0435-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-016-0435-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation