Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Industry Variations in Health Plans and Dynamic Employment Substitution

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This article has been updated

Abstract

Using data on the U.S., we study the effects of employer-sponsored health insurance on dynamic employment substitution between 1990 and 2007 by exploiting the interindustry variation in health care coverage. We find that industries with a high health benefit structure in 1990 have experienced faster employment growth of full-time workers relative to part-time workers, while the relative wage of full-time to part-time workers has declined more in such industries. We argue that considering the dynamic responses of both firms and workers to the benefit structure is crucial to understanding our empirical findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

  • 18 November 2021

    The original version of this article was updated. Starting second paragraph under Proposition 1 and Proposition 2 has been changed to upright position.

Notes

  1. Total fringe benefits as a proportion of total compensation were around 30% between 1991 and 2003 (BLS). Health insurance comprises the largest portion of fringe benefits, followed by paid leave and retirement benefits.

  2. One might argue that employers bearing high health benefits can adjust by paying lower wages, and thus, the overall rising cost of ESHI is not a burden for firms. For instance, Gruber (1994) shows that when maternity benefits are mandated towards women of childbearing age, the wage of the targeted group is reduced, indicating substantial shifting of the costs of the mandate in the form of lower wages. However, when we consider wage adjustments inter- or between- firms or industries, rather than within- firms or industries (as in Gruber (1994)), the studies that attempt to investigate the trade-off between wage and ESHI find a positive correlation, as high-paying jobs often provide generous health benefits (Currie and Madrian 1999). Our empirical strategy relies on interindustry variation in health benefits and thus does not necessarily contradict Gruber (1994) who considers within-firm wage adjustment upon providing mandated benefits.

  3. There might exist other channels through which employers can respond to rising health benefit costs; for instance, switching to high-deductible health plans (HDHP) might be one alternative. Koh (2018) finds that during the Great Recession, firms in industries that experienced severe recession shocks exhibit a higher growth of the enrollment rate of HDHP among workers covered by ESHI. While switching to HPDP can be an option for employers, the HDHP enrollment rate was relatively low (lower than 5% in 2006) before the Great Recession (Fig. 1 of Koh (2018)) so that the switching channel is likely to be weak in our sample period.

  4. 66% of those aged 16–64 have private health insurance that comes through employment (March Current Population Survey, 2001–2010).

  5. We restrict the sample period up to 2007 to remove the effect of the Great Recession that occurred at the end of 2007.

  6. Importantly, this view is consistent with recent empirical evidence by Borjas and Ramey (2000) and Shim and Yang (2018): They show that a competitive view of the labor market to explain interindustry wage differentials cannot generate the pattern observed in the data. For instance, Shim and Yang (2018) show that an initially high-wage industry has adopted new technology to replace labor more aggressively than a low-wage industry does, which cannot be explained by the standard assumption that workers are heterogenous but can be explained by the non-competitive view of the labor market. However, this does not mean that we undervalue the importance of unobserved heterogeneity across workers; rather, what we would like to emphasize is that non-competitive factors can play important roles in explaining the dynamics of the labor market.

  7. Firms’ response to wage structure is similar to Shim and Yang (2018).

  8. A similar labor supply equation can be found in Borjas and Ramey (2000).

  9. The share of workers with health insurance is higher among full-time employees than part-time employees (66% vs. 7% based on the 1991 March Current Population Survey) and is persistent over time (Fig. 3).

  10. The information on the share of full-time workers with health benefits is available from 1980, while the information on employer contribution is available from 1991.

  11. The Census system up to the 1990 Census was based on the structure of the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC). This classification was replaced in 1997 by the NAICS and the 2000 Census industrial classification system was therefore based on the structure of the NAICS.

  12. This specification does not allow our estimate to be interpreted as a causal effect; rather, the estimate is a partial correlation.

  13. We do not use industry fixed effects in our specification as there is not much variation in the ESHI coverage within-industry over time.

  14. To calculate the share of full-time workers with ESHI, using the sample of full-time workers, we create a dummy variable indicating whether an individual was a policyholder in a group health insurance plan to a job that the person had during 1990. We then take the average of this variable at the industry level.

  15. That is, \(\Delta {y}_{i1990,2007}=\left[\frac{Full- time\ worker{s}_{i,2007}}{Part- time\ worker{s}_{i,2007}}-\frac{Full- time\ worker{s}_{i,1990}}{Part- time\ worker{s}_{i,1990}}\right]/17\), where Full – time workersit is the number of full-time workers in industry i at time t.

  16. For the union membership database, see Hirsch and Macpherson (2003) for details.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Autor DH (2011) Skills, tasks and technologies: implications for employment and earnings. Handbook Labor Econ 4:1043–1171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2021) Demographics and automation. Rev Econ Stud

  • Alder S, Lagakos D, Ohanian L (2014) Competitive pressure and the decline of the Rust Belt: a macroeconomic analysis. NBER Working Paper No. 20538

  • Autor DH, Dorn D (2013) The growth of low skill service jobs and the polarization of the U.S. labor market. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1553–1597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor DH, Levy F, Murnane RJ (2003) The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Quarterly J Econ 118(4):1279–1333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baicker K, Chandra A (2006) The labor market effects of rising health insurance premiums. J Labor Econ 24(3):609–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Convergence. J Political Econ 100(2):223–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn M, Neumark D (1992) Unobserved ability, efficiency wages, and Interindustry wage differentials. Quarterly J Econ 107(4):1421–1436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ, Ramey VA (2000) Market responses to interindustry wage differentials. NBER Working Paper No. 7799

  • Bradley DJ, Kim I, Tian X (2017) Do unions affect innovation? Manag Sci 63(7):2251–2271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchmueller TC, DiNardo J, Valletta RG (2011) The effect of an employer-provided health insurance mandate on health insurance coverage and the demand for labor: evidence from Hawaii. Am Econ J: Econ Policy 3:25–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchmueller TC (1999) Fringe benefits and the demand for part-time workers. Appl Econ 31:551–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchmueller TC, Valletta RG (1999) The effect of health insurance on married female labor supply. J Human Resour 34(1):42–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Hammour  ML (1998) Jobless growth: Appropriability, factor substitution and unemployment. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48:51–94

  • Currie J, Madrian BC (1999) Health, health insurance and the labor market. Handbook Labor Econ 3:3309–3416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler D, Madrian BC (1998) Labor market responses to rising health insurance costs. RAND J Econ 29(3):509–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrett B, Kaestner R (2015) Recent evidence on the ACA and employment: has the ACA been a job killer? ACA Implementation–Monitoring and Tracking, Urban Institute

  • Gibbons R, Katz L (1992) Does unmeasured ability explain inter-industry wage differentials. Rev Econ Stud 59(3):515–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J (1994) The incidence of mandated maternity benefits. Am Econ Rev 84(3):622–641

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutowski M, Rivera-Lowitt C, Dicken J, Bonin P (1997) Private health insurance: continued Erosion of coverage linked to cost pressures. U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO/HEHS-97-122), Washington, D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch BT, Macpherson DA (2003) Union membership and coverage database from the current population survey: note. Industrial Labor Relations Rev 56(2):349–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones C, Klenow P (2016) Beyond GDP? Welfare across countries and time. Am Econ Rev 106(9):2426–2457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koh K (2018) The great recession and workers’ health benefits. Journal of Health Economics 58:18–28

  • Krueger AB, Summers LH (1988) Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica 56(2):259–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau MK (1997) Compensation in part-time jobs versus fulltime jobs: what if the job is the same? Econ Lett 56(1):101–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly J Econ 107(2):407–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathur A, Slavov SN, Strain MR (2015) Has the affordable care act increased part-time employment? Appl Econ Lett 23(3):222–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery M (1988) On the determinants of employer demand for part-time workers. The Review of Economics and Statistics 70(1):112–117

  • Nickell S, Wadhwani S (1990) Insider forces and wage determination. Econ J 100(401):496–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shim M, Yang H-S (2018) Interindustry wage differentials, technology adoption, and job polarization. J Econ Behav Organization 146:141–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sommers BD (2005) Who really pays for health insurance? The incidence of employer-provided health insurance with sticky nominal wages. Int J Health Care Finance Econ 5:89–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Summers LH (1989) Some simple economics of mandated benefits. Am Econ Rev 79(2):177–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh F (1999) A multisector model of efficiency wages. J Labor Econ 17(2):351–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was supported by the Yonsei Signature Research Cluster Program of 2021 (2021-22-0011). We thank Jaesung Choi, Do Won Kwak, and Haishan Yuen for helpful comments. Lisa Chan and Seoyoon Jeong provided excellent research assistance.

Availability of Data and Code

Data and codes are available on request.

Funding

This research was supported by the Yonsei Signature Research Cluster Program of 2021 (2021-22-0011).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hee-Seung Yang.

Ethics declarations

Ethics Approval and Informed Consent

We do not need ethics approval from the IRB as we use publicly available data sets only, such as (1) the U.S. Census, (2) March Current Population Survey and (3) EU KLEMS data, and thus the research does not involve identifiable private information.

Conflict of Interest

None of us has significant competing financial, professional,

or personal interests that might have influenced the work described in this manuscript.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This research was supported by the Yonsei Signature Research Cluster Program of 2021 (2021-22-0011). We thank Jaesung Choi, Do Won Kwak, and Haishan Yuen for helpful comments. Lisa Chan and Seoyoon Jeong provided excellent research assistance.

Appendices

Appendix

Appendix A (Data Appendix for Fig. 1) The data are spliced from a variety of sources to form one continuous time series. Real health premiums are constructed by dividing nominal health insurance premiums by the Consumer Price Index (CPI).

19801985: U.S. Department of Commerce, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1994 and 1999 editions, Washington D.C., available from.

https://www.census.gov/prod/www/statistical_abstract.html.

Average health insurance premium per capita is calculated by dividing health insurance income by population (also from the Statistical Abstract). Missing years (1981 and 1985) are interpolated by first deflating the data by the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ CPI to account for inflation. The CPI data are from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2015) Washington D.C., CPI Detailed Report, Table 24, accessed in August 2015, http://www.bls.gov/cpi/#tables.

19861988: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Office of Compensation and Working Conditions (2002), Employer Costs for Employee Compensation Historical Listing (Annual), 1986–2001, Table 3, p. 12, Washington D.C., available from: http://www.bls.gov/ncs/ect/sp/ecechist.pdf.

19891995: U.S. General Accounting Office (February 1997), Employment-Based Health Insurance, Costs Increase and Family Coverage Decreases, Report to the Ranking Minority Member, Subcommittee on Children and Families, Committee on Labor and Human Resources, GAO/HES-97-35, U.S. Senate, Washington D.C., Appendix II, p. 33, available from: http://www.gao.gov/assets/230/223812.pdf.

1996: The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation (2012) California, U.S., Employer Health Benefits Annual Survey Archives, various issues, accessed in January 2015, http://kff.org/health-costs/report/employer-health-benefits-annual-survey-archives.

1997: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (2013) Rockville, Maryland, Medical Expenditure Panel Survey, accessed in January 2015, http://meps.ahrq.gov/mepsweb/survey_comp/Insurance.jsp.

19982010: Kaiser (2012). Kaiser (2015) California, U.S., Premiums and Worker Contributions Among Workers Covered by Employer-Sponsored Coverage, 1999–2014, accessed in January 2015, http://kff.org/interactive/premiums-and-worker-contributions.

Appendix B (Collection of Proofs)

Given the firm’s problem introduced in Eqs. (1) and (2), one can derive the following first-order conditions:

$$\frac{w_{it}}{p_{it}}=\frac{h_{it}^{-1/\sigma }{\lambda}_{it}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }}{{\left(\tilde{h}_{i}t\right)}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }+{\left({\lambda}_{it}{h}_{it}\right)}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }}$$
(A.1)
$$\frac{w_{it}}{p_{it}}=\frac{h_{it}^{-1/\sigma }{\lambda}_{it}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }}{{\left(\tilde{h}_{i}t\right)}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }+{\left({\lambda}_{it}{h}_{it}\right)}^{\left(\sigma -1\right)/\sigma }}$$
(A.2)

By dividing Eq. (A.1) by (A.2) and rearranging the terms, one would get the Eq. (3) in the main text. Differentiating Eq. (3) with respect to wage would yield the following equation, which proves Proposition 1.

$$\frac{\partial\log(\frac{h_{it}}{{\widetilde h}_it})}{\partial\log w_{it}}=-\sigma<0$$
(A.3)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hahn, Y., Shim, M. & Yang, HS. Industry Variations in Health Plans and Dynamic Employment Substitution. J Labor Res 42, 449–467 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-021-09325-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-021-09325-8

Keywords

Navigation