Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Democracy and the Supply of Labor

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The average number of hours we spend at work varies dramatically by country. Previous research focuses on tax policy, social security, and labor market regulation to explain the differences. This paper builds on previous work by focusing on politics. Specifically, it examines the relationship between democracy and the average number of hours worked per person employed. Using data on the supply of labor from the Penn World Tables 9.1, I find there is an important difference between democracies and dictatorships: as GDP/capita increases, individuals in democracies spend fewer hours at work than their counterparts in dictatorships. The results are robust to various specifications of the model that account for selection bias and data that are missing not at random (MNAR). These findings imply that the elections, civil rights, and the political liberties associated with democracy influence the amount of time people spend at work.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A comprehensive review of the literature on institutions and culture or the new cultural economics can be found in a piece by Alesina and Giuliano (2015).

  2. It is important to remind that in terms of democracy and the average number of hours worked, the important differences in this study are between the USA and Venezuela or Russia, not between the USA and France or Switzerland.

  3. This assumes, of course, that the dictator is not the median voter or does not arbitrarily choose the same raft of policies.

  4. I use the variable “polity2” from the polity data which combines the “democ” and “autoc” scores that ranges from − 10 representing the most authoritarian regimes and + 10 representing the most democratic regimes. Throughout this paper, I classify the polity2 score of seven and above as democratic. This is slightly different in comparison to the cutoff adopted by Epstein et al. (2006) to distinguish between full democracies and all other regime types. I check the stability of the main results with respect to the cutoff point by varying it between four and eight (Table 2). I find the statistical and substantive significance of the estimates hold regardless of where the cutoff is made.

  5. The countries that remained at 10 throughout the sample are as follows: Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Italy, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Slovenia, Sweden, and Switzerland.

  6. There is an important restriction in this particular formulation of the more general ARDL (1,1) model (De Boef and Keele 2008). In the Koyck model, the estimate for the lagged form of the independent variable is restricted to be zero. Invalid restrictions pose serious problems for the coefficients on the independent variable of interest. De Boef and Keele recommend testing whether the lagged form of the independent variable of interest is statistically significant coefficient. A lagged version of the democracy dummy variable was included in the basic model and the null hypothesis could not be rejected: the estimate could be zero.

  7. For a nice treatment of how to calculate and present substantive results from distributed lag models, see Williams and Whitten (2012).

  8. I want to thank one of the anonymous reviewers for suggesting this as a possibility.

  9. The measure of capacity used throughout this paper is a function of mining, exports, and social security contributions as a percentage of GDP. Added to that is GDP/capita, the economically active population, education, and a dummy indicator for OECD members.

  10. Including country and year dummies together resulted in computational problems that stem from matrices that were singular and could not be inverted.

  11. So that I can produce estimates across all models using the sample selection methods, I use the “simulated annealing” stochastic global optimization algorithm proposed by Bélisle (1992).

  12. To preserve the dichotomous nature of the democracy measure, when calculating the means across years to construct different cross-sections, I count countries with a majority (over .50) of years as democratic as democracies. I varied the cutoff between .40 and .60 and found it had no significant impact on the findings or the conclusions drawn from them.

  13. For the imputation, in the selection equation I, use the democracy dummy variable, GDP/capita (logged), the interaction between democracy and GDP/capita and state capacity (the “ape1” variable).

  14. To measure TFP I use the variable “ctfp” from the Penn World Tables data (9.1).

  15. Another possible avenue for future research: what role does democracy play in the labor share of income? If democracy does, in fact, influence the power dynamics between labor and capital, it stands to reason regime type could influence the share of GDP output going to labor and capital. I want to thank one of the anonymous reviewers for pointing to this possibility for future investigation.

References

  • Acemoglu, D, Johnson S, Robinson JA. Chapter 6 institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of economic growth, 385–472. Elsevier; 2005.

  • Acemoglu, D, Robinson JA. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York, USA: Cambridge University Press; 2005.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, M, Hurst E. Measuring trends in leisue: the allocation of time over five decades. Q J Econ 2007;122(3):969–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A, Algan Y, Cahuc P, Giuliano P. Family values and the regulation of labor. J Eur Econ Assoc 2015;13(4):599–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A, Giuliano P. Culture and institutions. J Econ Lit 2015;53(4):898–944.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto, Glaeser Edward, Sacerdote Bruce. Work and leisure in the United States and Europe: Why so Different?. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005;20:1–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arbetman, M, Kugler J, Organski AFK. Political capacity and economic behavior. Westview Press. In: Arbetman M and Kugler J, editors; 1997.

  • Bell, LA, Freeman RB. The incentive for working hard: explaining hours worked differences in the us and germany. Labour Econ 2001;8:181–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T, Persson T. The origins of state capacity: property rights, taxation, and politics. Am Econ Rev 2009; 99 (4): 1218–44. http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/aea/aer/2009/00000099/00000004/art00007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bélisle, CJP. Convergence theorems for a class of simulated annealing algorithms on R \(\hat {}\) d. J Appl Probab 1992;29:885–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bick, A, Fuchs-Schüdeln N, Lagakos D. How do hours worked vary with income? Cross-Country evidence and implications. Am Econ Rev 2018; 108(1):170–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botero, JC, Djankov S, Porta RL, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A. The regulation of labor. Q J Econ 2004;119(4):1339–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracha, A, Gneezy U, Loewenstein G. Relative pay and labor supply. J Labor Econ 2015;33(2):297–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, DS. Reading, writing, and regime type: Democracy’ impact on primary school enrollment. Political Res Q 1999;52(4):681–707. https://doi.org/10.1177/106591299905200401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantore, C, Ferroni F, León-Ledesma MA. The dynamics of hours worked and technology. J Econ Dyn Control 2017;82:67–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y, Hong JH. Do technological improvements in the manufacturing sector raise or lower employment. Am Eco Rev 2006;96(1):352–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, DM, Madrian BC. 1996. Labor market responses to rising health insurance costs: evidence on hours worked. Working paper 5525. 1050 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02138: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • De Boef, S, Keele L. Taking time seriously. Am J Political Sci 2008;52(1):184–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dincecco, M, Katz G. State capacity and long-run economic performance. Eco J 2016;126(590):189–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. Harper & Row.

  • Epstein, D, Bates R, Goldstone J, Kristensen I. Democratic transitions. Am J Political Sci 2006;54(1):190–208. http://www.jstor.org/stable/3694234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erosa, A, Fuster L, Kambourov G. Labor supply and government programs: a cross-country analysis. J Monetary Eco 2012;59:84–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP. The next generation of the penn world table. Am Eco Rev 2015;105(10):3150–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisunoglu, A, Kang K, Arbetman-Rabinowitz M, Kugler J. 2011. Relative political capacity dataset (Version 2.4) August 2020. Harvard Dataverse. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/NRR7MB.

  • Galimard, J-E, Chevret S, Curis E, Resche-Rigon M. Heckman imputation models for binary or continuous Mnar outcomes and Mar predictors. BMC Med Res Methodol 2018;18(90):1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galimard, J-E, Chevret S, Protopopescu C, Resche-Rigon M. A multiple imputation approach for MNAR mechanisms compatible with Heckman’s model. Stat Med 2016;35(17):2907–20. https://doi.org/10.1002/sim.6902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geist, C. The welfare state and the home: regime differences in the domestic division of labor. Eur Socio Revi 2005;21(1):23–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gershuny, J, Sullivan O. Time use, gender, and public policy regimes. Social Politics 2003;10(2):205–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, JJ. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 1979;47(1):153–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendrix, CS. Measuring state capacity: Theoretical and empirical implications for the study of civil conflict. J Peace Research 2010;47(3):273–85. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343310361838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A. n.d. What Is New in Pwt 6.3?

  • Hotelling, Harold. Stability in competition. Eco J 1929;39:41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, EH, Maug E, Schneider C. Labor representation in governance as an insurance mechanism. Rev Finance 2018;22(4):1261–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koyck, LM. 1954. Distributed lags and investment analysis. North-Holland.

  • Lake, DA, Baum M. The invisible hand of democracy. Comparative Political Studies 2001;34(6):587–621. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414001034006001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDaniel, C. Forces shaping hours worked in the oecd, 1960-2004. Am Eco J: Macroeconomics 2011;3:27–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, AH, Richard SF. A rational theory of the size of government. J Political Eco 1981;89(5):914–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesquita, BB-d, Smith A, Siverson RM, Morrow JD. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. The MIT Press.

  • Ohanian, L, Raffo A, Rogerson R. Long-term changes in labor supply and taxes: evidence from oecd countries, 1956-2004. J Monet Econ 2008; 55:1353–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. Dictatorship, democracy, and development. Am Political Sci Rev 1993;87(3):567–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pontusson, J. Unionization, inequality and redistribution. British J Industrialization 2013;51(4):797–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, EC. 2004. Why do Americans work so much more than Europeans? NBER Working paper series 10316. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Przeworski, A. 1990. The state and economy under capitalism. Harwood Academic Publishers.

  • Przeworski, A, Alvarez ME, Cheibub JA, Limongi F. 2000. Democracy and development. Cambridge University Press.

  • Quintero-Rojas, C. Hours worked: explaining cross-country differences through the effects of Tax/Benefit systems on the employment rate. Ann Eco Stat 2009;95/96:79–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. Democracies pay higher wages. Quart J Eco 1999;114 (3):707–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, R. Understanding differences in hours worked. Rev Eco Dynamics 2006;9:365–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. Is democracy good for the poor? Am J Political Sci 2006; 50(4):860–74. http://www.blackwell-synergy.com/doi/abs/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2006.00220.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savoia, A, Sen K. Measurement, evolution, determinants, and consequences of state capacity: a review of recent research. J Eco Surveys 2015;29(3): 441–58. https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12065.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, LK, Whitten GD. But wait, there’s more! maximizing substantive inferences from tscs models. J Politics 2012;74(3):685–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David S. Brown.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brown, D.S. Democracy and the Supply of Labor. St Comp Int Dev 57, 149–170 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-021-09331-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-021-09331-y

Keywords

Navigation