Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

When Are Federations More Unequal? The Political Economy of Interregional Redistribution in Developing Federations

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Why do some countries redistribute more to poorer regions than others? This paper explores which factors explain variation in the degree of interregional redistribution among countries between 1983 and 2010. The main argument is that interregional redistribution increases with the need and capacity of strong presidents to build territorial coalitions with governors from poorer regions and, by implication, decreases with the ability of strong governors in rich districts to resist pressures to extract resources from their units. Using a multilevel structural equation model (the Generalized Linear Latent Multilevel Model, GLLAMM), the study analyzes these and competing claims on the determinants of interregional redistribution using original data from the subnational units of four types of cases, ranging from decentralized and federal to centralized, unitary countries. Empirical results indicate that the type of redistributive coalition between presidents and governors complement purely structural and institutional models to explain fiscal redistributive outcomes in the context of sharp regional inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Most of these studies analyze the redistributive power of the central government, which expresses the central government’s capacity to reduce regional disparities in terms of income. The redistributive power in a given country is estimated out of the elasticity coefficients of regional revenue and expenditure in relation to their initial revenue, which is the revenue existing prior to public sector action.

  2. This is a key reason for studying interregional redistribution in the five selected cases. The lack of comparative data and time series for analyzing interpersonal redistribution in these countries is another important motive.

  3. Some of the most relevant works in this literature explore whether democratic institutions (since the classic work of Meltzer and Richard 1981), electoral rules (Austen-Smith 2000; Persson and Tabellini 2000; Iversen and Soskice 2006), constitutional veto points (Bradley et al. 2003), the strength of the working class and leftist political parties (Hicks and Swank 1984; Boix 1998; Huber and Stephens 2001; Pontusson et al. 2002; Bradley et al. 2003; Kwon and Pontusson 2003, unpublished; Iversen and Soskice 2006), unionization and wage-bargaining centralization (Wallerstein 1999; Pontusson et al. 2002; Bradley et al. 2003), welfare spending (Bradley et al. 2003), and previous levels of inequality (Meltzer and Richard 1981; Kenworthy and Pontusson 2005; Iversen and Soskice 2006) have a systematic effect on interpersonal redistribution. Other works find that capital mobility and immigration (Alderson and Nielsen 2002); development (gross domestic product (GDP) per capita); education (Nielsen and Alderson 1995); or demographic variables, such as female participation in the labor force and the proportion of female-headed households (Bradley et al. 2003), have an impact on interpersonal redistribution.

  4. Other studies report large variation in how grants are distributed depending on the type of grant under analysis. Instead of focusing in a particular type of grant, this paper includes all transfers (legally mandated and discretionary) from the central government to subnational units in the operationalization of interregional redistribution (see below).

  5. On the effect of overrepresentation on the distribution of federal grants, see also, among others, Atlas et al. (1995), Lee (2000) as well as Rodden (2002), Arretche and Rodden (2004) unpublished, for Brazil, Gibson and Calvo (2000), Gibson, Calvo, and Falleti (2004), (Lodola 2005, 2010, unpublished), and Gordin (2006) for Argentina.

  6. I include tax autonomy (or authority) into this discussion to stress why less developed provinces do not have it as a first-order preference as the more developed do. This discussion has implications for provincial preferences over redistribution.

  7. A large literature measures the redistributive capacity of the central government, since the early MacDougall Report 1977 to more recent works (e.g., Sala-i-Martin and Sachs 1992; Bayoumi and Masson 1995; Mélitz and Zumer 1998; Barberán et al. 2000). There are also works measuring interpersonal redistribution that use a similar estimation strategy but using a different unit of analysis (individuals’ final income instead of governments’ transfers) (e.g., Bradley et al. 2003: 196; Iversen and Soskice 2006: 172).

  8. Federal transfers account for 75 % average of the total revenue, or more (reaching in some cases over 90 %), for the entire series (1983–2011) in almost half of the Argentine provinces (10 out of 24: Catamarca, Chaco, Corrientes, Formosa, Jujuy, La Rioja, Misiones, San Juan, San Luis, Santiago del Estero, and Tucumán), three Brazilian states (Acre, Amapá, and Roraima), all regions in Chile, four Colombian departments (Amazonas, Guainía, Vaupés, and Vichada), and six Mexican states (Campeche, Chiapas, Hidalgo, Tabasco, Tlaxcala, and Yucatán).

  9. Regulated by the revenue-sharing laws in the different countries (see Table 2, online Appendix).

  10. Bagchi 2003; Bosch et al. 2010; Cappelen et al. 2003; Castells and Solé Ollé 2005; Coulombe and Lee 1995; de Oliveira 2008; Garrido and Sotelsek 2002; Maciel et al. 2008; Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev 2010; Porto 1994; Ramakrishnan and Cerisola 2004; Rangarajan and Srivastava 2004.

  11. These variables do not take into account the fact that party control in subnational legislatures can change over time and during the governor’s term in office, especially in contexts with high levels of party factionalization.

  12. The index of gubernatorial power is a composite measure of all the aforementioned shares and dummies. Dummies contribute 0.5 points to the index in case they are coded as 1, to balance the effect of each measure. I am assuming that a 50 % share of votes received by the governor, a 50 % share of the seats in the state legislative controlled by the governor’s party, whether the main party in the legislature is the party of the governor and whether the president and the governor are in the same governing coalition all weight equally in the index. The maximum possible theoretical value is 4, but since the dummies are coded 0.5 instead of 1, the maximum possible value is 3 and the minimum is 0. I calculated the average value for each year and for all governors and classified the average partisan power of governors (a single measure for each year and each country). The gubernatorial partisan power index is “very high” when values range between 3 and 2, “high” for values between 2 and 1.6, “medium” for values between 1.6 and 1.4, “low” for values between 1.4 and 1, and “very low” for values less than 1.

  13. In Argentina, this region includes the provinces of Buenos Aires, Córdoba, Santa Fe, and the Federal Capital. In Brazil, it encompasses all the Southern region states and the Federal District. In Colombia, the departments of Antioquia, Atlántico, Bogota, Santander, and Valle del Cauca. In Mexico, the DF, Campeche, Chihuahua, Nuevo León, and Quintana Roo.

  14. This region includes all the other provinces, states, or departments.

  15. For Colombia, I use data from Battle and Puyana (2011), who calculated the index based on Mainwaring and Jones’s (2003) formula.

  16. For Argentina, I include years before and after the 1988 fiscal decentralization reforms and the 1992–1993 legal changes that decentralized health and education policies. In Brazil, I include years before and after the 1988 fiscal decentralization reforms and the changes in the Unified Health System (SUS) and in the education fund system (FUNDEF) after 1994. For Colombia, I include observations for the period before and after political decentralization reforms that led to the election of mayors and local authorities (1988), as well as the fiscal and administrative decentralization policies implemented after the 1991 constitutional reform. The same is done with Mexico (after the presidencies of Miguel de la Madrid, 1982–1988, and Carlos Salinas de Gortari, 1989–1994) and Chile (after the 1992 mayoral election).

  17. Only to test the consistency of results correcting for heteroskedasticity, I run a generalized least squares regression (GLS). These results are almost identical to those in PCSE. They are available upon request.

  18. There is debate on how many level 2 units should be included in a multilevel model. Gelman (2006: 524) models a multilevel regression with as little as 3 level 2 units. Besides taking care of the normality assumption, another important requirement for him is getting a non-zero variance. Gelman recommends running a multilevel model because alternative non-multilevel models are similar to it with a group-level variance set to 0 or infinity.

  19. Argentina stands out as the country that redistributes the most (it has the largest average IIR) and where interregional inequality has experienced the sharpest decline (according to a Gini index that measures income differences between the average income of each province and the national average) but still remains as the most interregionally unequal of the selected nations. Brazil closely follows Argentina in terms of interregional inequality.

  20. I do not include party system fragmentation and nationalization in the same model due to the high correlation between the two variables (−0.8 and p = 0.00001).

  21. This relationship is statistically significant in PCSE, but it does not reach the usual standards in GLS.

  22. These are the results of the summing up the coefficients for (the log of) gubernatorial power and the interaction term between this variable and the dummies for developed and less developed districts.

  23. These are the results of the summing up the coefficients for (the log of) presidential electoral power and the interaction term between this variable and the dummies for developed and less developed districts.

  24. The coefficients for the control variables are omitted in Table 5b, online Appendix, to save space.

  25. These are the results of the summing up the coefficients for number of presidential allies and the interaction term between this variable and the dummies for developed and less developed districts. The share of allies (instead of the number of allies) is not a statistically significant variable explaining changes in the outcome. This may mean that specific allies are more important than the total share of them, but more research is needed to code different types of allies.

  26. This is the case for most models in the different tables. The coefficients for industrial GDP do not allow us to reach any clear conclusion.

References

  • Aiken LS, West SG. Multiple regression: testing and interpreting interactions. Thousand Oaks: Sage; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alderson AS, Nielsen F. Globalization and the great U-turn: income inequality trends in sixteen OECD countries. Am J Sociol 2002;107:1244--99.

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E. The size of nations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atlas C, Gilligan T, Hendershott R, Zupan M. Slicing the federal net spending pie: who wins, who loses, and why? Am Econ Rev. 1995;85:624–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith D. Redistributing income under proportional representation. J Polit Econ. 2000;108(6):1235–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagchi A. Fifty years of fiscal federalism in India: an appraisal. Working Papers, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy. 2003; 03/2.

  • Barberán R, Bosch N, Castells A, Espasa M. The redistributive power of the central government budget. Institut d’Economía de Barcelona, Working Paper 2000; 2000/6.

  • Batlle M, Puyana J. El nivel de nacionalización del sistema de partidos colombiano: una mirada a partir de las elecciones legislativas de 2010. Colombia Internacional. 2011;74:27–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Masson PR. Fiscal flows in the United States and Canada: lessons for monetary union in Europe. Eur Econ Rev. 1995;39:253–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck N, Katz JN. What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. Am Polit Sci Rev. 1995;89(3):634–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beramendi P. Inequality and the territorial fragmentation of solidarity. Int Org. 2007;61:783–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beramendi P. The political geography of inequality: regions and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2012.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beramendi P. Inequality, representation, and endogenous fiscal institutions. Paper prepared for presentation at the Comparative Politics Workshop, Department of Political Science, Stanford University, June 2, 2008.

  • Beramendi P, Díaz-Cayeros A. Distributive tensions in developing federations. Paper delivered at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association; 2008.

  • Boadway R, Flatters F. Efficiency and equalization payments in a federal system of government: a synthesis and extension of recent results. Can J Econ. 1982;15(4):613–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix C. Political parties, growth and equality: conservative and social democratic economic strategies in the world economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1998.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Roland G. The breakup of nations: a political economy analysis. Q J Econ. 1997;112:1057–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosch N, Espasa M, Solé OA. The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows: measurement, determinants and effects on country stability. Cheltenham: Elgar; 2010.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley D, Huber E, Moller S, Nielson F, Stephens J. Distribution and redistribution in postindustrial democracies. World Polit. 2003;55:193–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo E, Murillo MV. Who delivers? Partisan clients in the argentine electoral market. Am J Polit Sci. 2004;48(4):742–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen A, Castellacci F, Fagerberg J, Verspagen B. The impact of EU regional support on growth and convergence in the European Union. J Common Market Stud. 2003;41:621–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castells A, Solé OA. The regional allocation of infrastructure investment: the role of equity, efficiency, and political factors. Eur Econ Rev. 2005;49(5):1165–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castells A, Costas JC, Parellada M. Efectos Redistributivos Regionales de las Finanzas del Gobierno Central y Flujos de Mercancías y Servicios en España. Investigaciones Económicas 1981;16, Septiembre-Diciembre.

  • Coppedge M. Continuity and change in Latin American party systems. Taiwan J Dem. 2007;3(2):119–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coppedge M, Mejía A. Political determinants of fiscal discipline in Latin America, 1979-1998. Paper prepared for the 2001 LASA Congress; 2001.

  • Coulombe S, Lee FC. Convergence across Canadian Provinces, 1961 to 1991. Canadian J Econ. 1995;28(4a):886–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croon M, Van Veldhoven M. Predicting group-level outcome variables from variables measured at the individual level: a latent variable multilevel model. Psychol Methods. 2007;12(1):45–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Oliveira JC. Análise do Crescimiento Económico e das Desigualdades Regionais no Brasil. Estudos do CEPE 2008;28.

  • Díaz-Cayeros A. El federalismo y los límites políticos de la redistribución. Gestión y Política Pública. 2004;3(13):663–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Díaz-Cayeros A. Federalism, fiscal authority, and centralization in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2006.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Londregan J. The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. J Polit. 1996;58(4):1132–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Londregan J. Fiscal federalism and redistributive politics. J Public Econ. 1998;68(2):153–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domenech R, Maudes A, Varela J. Fiscal flows in Europe: the redistributive effects of the EU budget. Paper presented at the Second Applied Economics Meeting, Zaragoza; 1999.

  • Duboz ML, Nicot B. Fédéralisme Budgétaire et union Monetaire Européenne: les Enseignements de L’expérience Allemande, Revue d’Economie Politique 1998;1(108):37--51.

  • Garrido N, Marina A, Sotelsek D. Convergencia Económica en las Provincias Argentinas (1970-1995). Estudios de Economía Aplicada 2002;20(II):403-421.

  • Gelman A. Prior distributions for variance parameters in hierarchical models. Bayesian Anal. 2006;1(3):515–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelman A, Hill J. Data analysis using regression and multilevel/hierarchical models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson EL. The populist road to market reform: policy and electoral coalitions in Mexico and Argentina. World Polit. 1997;49(3):339–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson EL, Calvo E. Federalism and low-maintenance constituencies: territorial dimensions of economic reform in Argentina. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2000;35(3):32–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson EL, Calvo E, Falleti TG. Reallocative federalism: legislative overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In: Gibson EL, editor. Federalism and democracy in Latin America. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press; 2004. p. 173–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • González L. The redistributive effects of centralization and decentralization across subnational units. Lat Am Res Rev. 2012;47(3):109–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordin, JP. The politics of intergovernmental fiscal relations in Argentina. IBEI Working Paper 2006; No. 2006/2: 1-15.

  • Grossman PJ. A political theory of intergovernmental grants. Public Choice. 1994;78(3/4):295–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks A, Swank D. Governmental redistribution in rich capitalist democracies. Policy Stud J 1984;13(2).

  • Holcombe R, Zardkoohi A. The determinants of federal grants. South Econ J. 1981;48:393–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber E, Stephens JD. Development and crisis of the welfare state: parties and policies in global markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2001.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen T, Soskice D. Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2006;100(2):165–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones MP, Mainwaring S. The nationalization of parties and party systems. An empirical measure and an application to the Americas. Party Polit. 2003;9(2):139–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemmerling A, Bodenstein T. Partisan politics in regional redistribution do parties affect the distribution of EU structural funds across regions? Eur Union Polit. 2006;7(3):373–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenworthy L, Pontusson J. Rising inequality and the politics of redistribution in affluent countries. Perspect Polit. 2005;3(3):449–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King JD, Cohen JE. What determines a governor’s popularity? State Polit Policy Q. 2005;5(3):225–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kousser T, Phillips JH. The power of American governors. Winning on budgets and losing on policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2012.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laakso M, Taagepera R. The effective number of parties: a measure with application to West Europe. Comp Polit Stud 1979;12(1):3--27.

  • Lee F. Senate representation and coalition building in distributive politics. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2000;94(1):59–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lodola G. Protesta Popular y Redes Clientelares en la Argentina: El Reparto Federal del Plan Trabajar (1996-2001) Desarrollo Económico 2005;44(176):515--536.

  • Lowi TJ. Why is there no socialism in the United States? A federal analysis. Int Polit Sci Rev. 1984;5(4):369–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ludtke O, Herbert WM, Robitzsch A, Trautwein U, Asparouhov T, Muthén B. The multilevel latent covariate model: a new, more reliable approach to group-level effects in contextual studies. Psychol Methods. 2008;13(3):203–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luke D. Multilevel modeling. Thousand Oaks: Sage; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacDougall Rapport du Groupe de Réflexion sur le Role des Finances Publiques dans l’Integration Européenne, Comission des Communautes Europeennes, Serie Economie et Finances 1977;A13,B13, Luxemburg.

  • Maciel PJ, Andrade J, Kuhl Teles V. Transferências Fiscais e Convergência Regional no Brasil. Working Paper 2008.

  • Mainwaring S, Shugart M. Presidentialism and democracy in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1997.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Vazquez J, Timofeev A. Intra-regional equalization and growth in Russia. International Studies Program Working Papers 10–11, Georgia State University, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies.

  • Mélitz J, Zumer F. Redistribution Régionale et Stabilisation par le Gouvernement Central. Économie Internationale 1998;75(3rd Quarter):3-31.

  • Meltzer AH, Richard SF. A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ. 1981;89:914–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negretto G. Political parties and institutional design: explaining constitutional choice in Latin America. Br J Pol Sci. 2009;39:117–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neustadt R. Presidential power: the politics of leadership from FDR to Carter. Hoboken: Wiley; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen F, Alderson AS. Income inequality, development, and dualism: results from an unbalanced cross-national panel. Am Sociol Rev 1995; 60(5):606--31.

  • O’Neill K. Decentralizing the state: elections, parties, and local power in the Andes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2005.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Obinger H, Francis GC, Leibfried S, editors. Federalism and the welfare state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G. Federal fiscal constitutions, risk sharing, and redistribution. J Polit Econ. 1996;104(5):979–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G. Political economics. Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pontusson J, Rueda D, Way C. Comparative political economy of wage distribution: the role of partisanship and labor market institutions. British J Polit Sc 2002;32(2):281--308.

  • Porto G, Convergencia y Política Económica. Algunos Resultados para Provincias Argentinas. Anales de la Asociación Argentina de Economía Política; 1994.

  • Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A, Pickles A. Generalized multilevel structural equation modeling. Psychometrika. 2004;69(2):167–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramakrishnan U, Cerisola, MD. Regional economic disparities in Australia. IMF Working Paper 2004;04/144.

  • Rangarajan C, Srivastava D. Fiscal transfer in Australia: review and relevance to India. Working Papers 2004;04/20, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy.

  • Rao MG, Singh N. The political economy of center-state fiscal transfers in India. Working Paper 2001;107, Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford University, Stanford.

  • Rodden J. Strength in numbers? Representation and redistribution in the European Union. Eur Union Polit. 2002;3(2):151–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden J. Federalism and inter-regional redistribution, in the political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows: measurement determinants and effects on country stability (Studies in Fiscal Federalism and State-local Finance). Cheltenham: Elgar; 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodden J. Federalism and inter-regional redistribution. Documents de Treball de l’IEB 2009;2009/3.

  • Roine J, Vlachos J, Waldenström D. The long-run determinants of inequality: what can we learn from top income data? J Public Econ. 2009;93:974–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-I-Martín X, Sachs J. Fiscal Federalism and Optimum Currency Areas: Evidence for Europe from the United States. In Canzoneri, M, Grilli, V, Masson, P (Eds.). Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the US. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1992:195--219.

  • Samuels D, Richard S. The value of a vote: malapportionment in comparative perspective. Br J Polit Sci. 2001;31(4):651–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart M, Carey J. Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1992.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Skrondal A, Rabe-Hesketh S. Generalized latent variable modeling: multilevel, longitudinal, and structural equation models. CRC; 2004.

  • Snyder R. Scaling down: the subnational comparative method. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2001;36(1):93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein M. Wage setting institutions and pay inequality in advanced industrial societies. Am J Polit Sc 1999;43(3):649--680.

  • Wibbels E. Decentralized governance, constitution formation, and redistribution. Const Polit Econ. 2005;16(2):161–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildavski A. Federalism means inequality. In: Golembiewski RT, Wildavski A, editors. The cost of federalism. Piscataway: Transaction Books; 1984.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Support for this research has been provided by CONICET and the Carolina Foundation-CEALCI Research Grant. An earlier version of the paper was delivered at the Conference on “Federalism and Inequality in the Global South,” Brown University, May 22-23, 2013; the XXXII International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association (LASA), May 21-24, 2014; the Universidad de Salamanca, February 24, 2014; the Jornadas de Investigación at the Universidad de San Martín, March 27-28, 2014; and the University of Limpopo, South Africa, November 13, 2014. I want to thank Pablo Beramendi, German Lodola, David Samuels, Richard Snyder, Hillel Soifer, Jonathan Rodden, and the three anonymous SCID reviewers for their insightful comments and suggestions. The usual caveat applies. Ana Bovino and Julia Rubio provided crucial research assistantship for this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lucas I González.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DOC 86.8 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

I González, L. When Are Federations More Unequal? The Political Economy of Interregional Redistribution in Developing Federations. St Comp Int Dev 51, 209–234 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-015-9205-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-015-9205-3

Keywords

Navigation