Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The race between the snail and the tortoise: skill premium and early industrialization in Italy (1861–1913)

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we estimate series of the skill premium for Italy during the early stages of the industrialization with a refined version of the regression approach originally introduced by Clark (J Polit Econ 113(6):1307–1340, 2005). We compute series for the whole country as well as separate series for macro-regions and for construction and manufacturing, and, within manufacturing, we estimate high and low skill premia for blue collars. We interpret the results with an extended version of the classic Katz and Autor (in: Ashenfelter, Card (eds) Handbook of labor economics, Elsevier, Dordrecht, pp 1463–1555, 1999) framework. The overall premium remained stable until the 1890s and then declined for the joint effect of migrations (almost exclusively of unskilled workers) and the rise in literacy, which was not compensated by the modest increase in industrial employment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Sources Wages, this study. Regional shares in total population: our own elaboration on Census data. Occupational shares in agriculture, construction, manufacturing, and mining: Broadberry et al. (2013). Notes: the “sector-specific” estimate of the Italian skill premium starts in 1876 due to the lack of wage data for all sectors before that date

Fig. 4

Sources This study and Federico et al. (2019)

Fig. 5

Sources Italy, this study. Other countries, Betrán and Pons (2013). Notes: the French data are consistent with the benchmark estimates for 1896 and 1911 reported in Bayet (1997, Tab. 5, p. 169)

Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Sources Education: literacy rates of brides and grooms from Annuario Statistico Italiano; Data on technical education from Vasta (1999). Population aged more than 15 years from ISTAT, Statistiche storiche online database. Intervening values have been interpolated linearly. The series labelled “workers trained in technical schools” represents the stock of workers trained in technical schools (Istituti tecnici and Scuole di arti e mestieri) computed on the population aged 15 years or more assuming 40-year work-life after the end of the education. Migration: Migration data from ISTAT, Annuario statistico dell’emigrazione italiana (1926) tables I and VII (unskilled includes farmers (agricoltori) and unskilled workers (terraioli, braccianti); Population, current boundaries, from ISTAT, Statistiche storiche, online database. Capital stock: Machinery and equipment from Broadberry et al. (2013). Strikes: Annuario Statistico Italiano (1905–1907; 1911–1914)

Fig. 9

Sources MAIC—Statistica degli Scioperi (1907, 1908, 1911, 1912a, 1912b, 1913, 1914, 1915, 1916). Notes: The source reports the total wage bill lost by strikers and the total days of strike. Wages of different type of male workers have been computed using the share of male strikers reported in the Statistica degli Scioperi of 1913 (MAIC—Statistica degli Scioperi 1916) and the gender wage gap estimated in Fig. 7

Fig. 10

Sources Italy, this study. Netherlands, Betrán and Pons (2013). Other countries, Anderson (2001)

Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Source our own elaboration on Census data. For 1861, data by age are not available for 5 and 6 years

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The other pillars of Allen’s standard model are the construction of a national transport infrastructure for creating a large national market, an external tariff for protecting “infant” industries, and the establishment of banks to stabilize the currency and provide business with capital.

  2. Milanovic (2016) acknowledges the possible existence of Kuznets waves of inequality also in preindustrial societies, but their nature is fundamentally different from those taking place after the Industrial Revolution.

  3. For recent estimates of inequality in Italy during the Liberal age, see Amendola and Vecchi (2017).

  4. For an updated review, see Olivetti and Petrongolo (2016).

  5. There are two recent contributions on the evolution of Italian real wages in the period 1861–1913: Daniele and Malanima (2017) and Federico et al. (2019), but they are both focused on the divergence in living standard and economic performance between the north and the south, rather than on the dynamics of the skill premium in this historical phase.

  6. In this framework, globalization would affect the skill bias via the effects on skill intensity and composition of VA by sector. This may include a change in exports towards more skill-intensive products, but this is not strictly necessary.

  7. We have estimated provincial series of daily wages in agriculture from these data with information on the number of days for each task in the crop year from technical sources (for details, see Federico et al. 2019).

  8. A complete list of the sources is provided in “Appendix 2”.

  9. We omit workers with some managerial roles, most notably the “capomastri” in construction sector, since their skills are not strictly related to the ability of performing specific production tasks.

  10. A simple measure of this variety is the cross-sectional coefficient of variation of wages by year, which is the more meaningful the larger is the number of observations (we have only eight years with more than 100 observations). The coefficient, for males only, is very high in the early period (0.52 in 1859, 0.47 in 1866, 0.45 in 1874) and then drops to about 0.30 in the 1900s (0.26 in 1903, 0.29 in 1904, 0.30 in 1906 and 1907 and 0.27 in 1911).

  11. In “Appendix 1” (Tables 6, 7, and 8), we present the lists of the most common occupations for each skill category.

  12. According to Giordano and Zollino (2015), agriculture accounted for 75.1% of total workforce excluding services in 1881 and 71.5% in 1911. See Sect. 5 for a more detailed analysis of economy-wide structural change.

  13. The weight on observation i (\( w_{i} \)) is given by the share of the region r in the national population in year t (\( sh_{rt} \)) divided by the number of observations of region r in year t (\( n_{rt} \)): \( w_{i} = \frac{{sh_{rt} }}{{n_{rt} }} \).

  14. We use three-year periods in order to have enough observations for the regression model estimates with interaction (not for smoothing).

  15. We estimate the following equations for the gender wage gap, the sectoral, and area-specific skill premia, respectively:

    $$ \ln \left( {w_{\text{p}} } \right) = \alpha + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{1} \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{J} \beta_{ij} GENDER_{i} PERIOD_{j} + \gamma SKILL + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{K} \delta_{k} SECTOR_{k} + \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 1}^{L} \theta_{l} SOURCE_{l} + \mathop \sum \limits_{m = 1}^{M} \varphi_{m} LOC_{m} + \varepsilon_{\text{p}} $$
    $$ \ln \left( {w_{\text{p}} } \right) = \alpha + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{1} \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{J} \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{K} \beta_{ijk} SKILL_{i} PERIOD_{j} SECTOR_{k} + \gamma GENDER + \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 1}^{L} \theta_{l} SOURCE_{l} + \mathop \sum \limits_{m = 1}^{M} \varphi_{m} LOC_{m} + \varepsilon_{\text{p}} $$
    $$ \ln \left( {w_{\text{p}} } \right) = \alpha + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 0}^{1} \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{J} \mathop \sum \limits_{m = 1}^{M} \beta_{ijm} SKILL_{i} PERIOD_{j} LOC_{m} + \gamma GENDER + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{K} \delta_{k} SECTOR_{k} + \mathop \sum \limits_{l = 1}^{L} \theta_{l} SOURCE_{l} + \varepsilon_{\text{p}} $$

    We interpret the results of these series in Sects. 5, 6, and 7.

  16. Unskilled wages in agriculture and the building industry followed a similar trend also in France between 1250 and 1860 (Ridolfi 2019).

  17. For a useful overview of industrialization waves, see von Tunzelmann (1995) and for the industrialization in the periphery, see O’Rourke and Williamson (2017).

  18. According to Frankema and Van Waijenburg (2019), in the nineteenth century, skill premia in Africa and Asia were very high relative to Europe but with the growth in school attainment rates, these rapidly converged to the levels prevailing in Western European countries during the twentieth century.

  19. According to Ortaggi Cammarosano (1991, p. 181): “one of the most constant discrimination against women was their low level of wages. In agricultural as in industrial work, for work done at home as well as in the factory, women received half the wages for men for doing the same job. This ratio remained constant over many decades […]. It testified to the presence of custom and attitudes which went very far back in time”.

  20. The average age at marriage (1865–1913) was 29 years and 6 months for men and 25 years and 4 months for women (seriestoriche.istat.it, Table 3.6).

  21. This increase suggests a change in the nature of Italian emigration. Until the end of the twentieth century, Italian emigrants were almost exclusively males looking for jobs. Subsequently, some of these emigrants started to settle abroad and they were reached by their families. Thus, the “not in workforce” category includes chiefly housewives and small children. The share is indeed lower than emigrants younger than 15 years.

  22. Using height data, Spitzer and Zimran (2018) have shown that Italian migration in the USA was negatively selected at the national level, but positively selected at the provincial level.

  23. See also Nuvolari and Vasta (2017) for an analysis of the spatial patterns of inventive activity in Italy in the period 1861‒1913 using patent data.

  24. For a description of Italian trade database, see Federico and Vasta (2015).

  25. We compute cumulating imports under the assumption of 17-year life-cycle (from Giordano and Zollino 2015). Accordingly, the initial imported capital stock in 1862 is assumed 85 million lire—equivalent to 17 times the import value of that year.

  26. Advanced industry includes metal-making, engineering, chemicals, printing and publishing, rubber and plastics, and utilities. The denominator is the sum of manufacturing and utilities. Data for 1871 come from Ciccarelli and Missiaia (2013, Table C.1), who reproduce the census figures without correction. Data for 1881, 1901, and 1911 are taken from Vitali (1970, Table 3), who adjusts for different minimum ages but not for the inconsistent treatment of women employment. The 1881 census classified as workers all females who were employed part time at home, while the other censuses included only full-time workers (Mancini 2018). The effect was particularly large in textile industries in the south. Thus, we correct by extrapolating backwards the number of females in 1901 with the rate of change of male employment from 1881 to 1901.

  27. Strikes were formally illegal until 1889 and, around 1900, government declared itself neutral in capital/labour conflicts. The first major general strike took place only in 1904 (Lay et al. 1973; Berra and Revelli 1978).

  28. The number of strikers in agriculture peaked in 1907 (254,000).

  29. Note that, potentially, strikes on hours might increase wages, if they achieved a cut in hours worked with the same salary. We neglect this issue as all our data refer to days of work rather than hours. The following discussion refers to the number of strikes, which is the only information about motivation and outcome available in the source. We have to implicitly assume that the average number of strikers was equal.

  30. We have estimated the wage of male strikers using the following formula: ws = a · wsm + (1 − a) · b ·wsf, where ws is the average wage of strikers, a is the share of male strikers, b is the gender wage gap, and wsm and wsf are the wages of male and female strikers, respectively. This formula yields: wsm = ws/[a + (1 − a)  · b]. The share a is taken from MAIC—Statistica degli scioperi (1916); this share is obtained by interpolating the values between 1903 and 1913. The gender wage gap is taken from Fig. 7.

  31. This discontinuity is broadly consistent with the results of the econometric analysis by Felice and Carreras (2012) on the pattern of Italian industrialization.

  32. We consider only males as they accounted for four-fifths of migrants.

  33. The exact value of the elasticity is irrelevant, as it cancels itself out in the final formula.

References

  • Allen RC (2001) The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explor Econ Hist 38(4):411–447

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2011) Global economic history. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Amendola N, Vecchi G (2017) Inequality. In: Vecchi G (ed) Measuring wellbeing. A history of Italian living standards. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 293–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson E (2001) Globalisation and wage inequalities 1870–1970. Eur Rev Econ Hist 5(1):91–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Baffigi A (2015) Il PIL per la storia d’Italia: istruzioni per l’uso. Marsilio, Padova

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardini C (1997) Without coal in the age of steam: a factor-endowment explanation of the italian industrial lag before World War I. J Econ Hist 57(3):633–653

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayet A (1997) L’accroissement spectaculaire des salaires et de leur pouvoir d’achat. In: Marchand O, Thélot C (eds) Le travail en France, 1800–2000. Nathan, Paris, pp 155–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Berra M, Revelli M (1978) Salari. In: Tranfaglia N (ed) Storia d’Italia. Il mondo contemporaneo. La Nuova Italia, Firenze, pp 1167–1194

    Google Scholar 

  • Betrán C, Pons MA (2004) Skilled and unskilled wage differentials and economic integration 1870–1930. Eur Rev Econ Hist 8(1):29–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Betrán C, Pons MA (2013) Comparing past and present wage inequality in two globalisation periods. Scand Econ Hist Rev 61(2):140–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Betrán C, Ferri J, Pons MA (2010) Explaining UK wage inequality in the past globalisation period 1880–1913. Cliometrica 4(1):19–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolt J, Inklaar R, de Jong H, van Zanden JL (2018) Rebasing ‘Maddison’: new income comparisons and the shape of long-run economic development. Working paper of Maddison Project, 10

  • Broadberry SN, Giordano C, Zollino F (2013) Productivity. In: Toniolo G (ed) The Oxford handbook of the Italian economy since unification. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 187–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Cappelli G, Vasta M (2018) The human capital gender gap and educational reforms in Italy (1861–1921), Mimeo

  • Cappelli G, Vasta M (2020) Can school centralisation foster human capital accumulation? A quasi-experiment from early XX century Italy. Econ Hist Rev (forthcoming)

  • Ciccarelli C, Missiaia A (2013) The industrial labor force of Italy’s provinces: estimates from the population censuses 1871–1911. Riv Stor Econ 29(2):141–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccarelli C, Weisdorf JL (2018) Pioneering into the past: regional literacy developments in Italy before Italy. Eur Rev Econ Hist. https://doi.org/10.1093/ereh/hey014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2005) The condition of the working class in England 1209–2004. J Polit Econ 113(6):1307–1340

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen J, Federico G (2001) The development of the Italian economy 1820–1960. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniele V, Malanima P (2017) Regional wages and the North-South disparity in Italy after the unification. Riv Stor Econ 33(2):117–158

    Google Scholar 

  • De Fort E (1996) La Scuola elementare dall’unità alla caduta del Fascismo. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • de Pleijt A, van Zanden JL (2018) Two Worlds of Female Labour: Gender Wage Inequality in Western Europe 1300–1800. Working Papers in Economic History of EHES, 138

  • dell’Emigrazione Generale (1926) Annuario statistico dell’emigrazione italiana dal 1876 al 1925. Commissariato Generale dell’Emigrazione, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Le Chapelain C, Menard A-R (2019) Neither the elite, nor the mass. The rise of intermediate human capital during the French industrialization process. Cliometrica (forthcoming)

  • Federico G (2009) An economic history of the silk industry. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Federico G, Vasta M (2015) What do we really know about protection before the Great Depression: evidence from Italy. J Econ Hist 75(4):993–1029

    Google Scholar 

  • Federico G, Natoli S, Tattara G, Vasta M (2011) Il commercio estero italiano 1862–1950. Editori Laterza, Roma-Bari

    Google Scholar 

  • Federico G, Nuvolari A, Vasta M (2019) The origins of the Italian regional divide: evidence from real wages 1861–1913. J Econ Hist 79(1):63–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Felice E, Carreras A (2012) When did modernization begin? Italy’s industrial growth reconsidered in light of new value-added series 1911–1951. Explor Econ Hist 49(4):443–460

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankema E, Van Waijenburg M (2019) The great convergence. Skill accumulation and mass education in Africa and Asia, 1870–2010. CEPR Working paper, DP14150

  • Gerschenkron A (1962) Economic backwardness in historical perspective. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti R (1998) Tecnologia e Sviluppo Economico Italiano (1870–1990). Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Giordano C, Zollino F (2015) A historical reconstruction of capital and labour in Italy 1861–2013. Riv Stor Econ 31(2):155–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin C (1990) Understanding the gender gap: an economic history of American women. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin C (1995) The U-shaped female labor force function in economic development and economic history. In: Schultz TP (ed) Investment in Women’s human capital and economic development. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 61–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin C, Katz LF (2008) The race between education and technology. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphries J (2003) English apprenticeship: a neglected factor in the first industrial revolution. In: David PA, Thomas M (eds) The economic future in historical perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 73–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz LF, Autor D (1999) Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Elsevier, Dordrecht, pp 1463–1555

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly M, Mokyr J, O’Grada C (2014) Precocious Albion: a new interpretation of the british industrial revolution. Annu Rev Econ 6(1):363–389

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets S (1955) Economic growth and income inequality. Am Econ Rev 45(1):1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Lay A, Marucco D, Pesante ML (1973) Classe operaia e scioperi: ipotesi per il periodo 1880–1923. Quaderni Storici 22:87–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee JW, Lee H (2016) Human capital in the long run. J Dev Econ 122:147–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindert P, Williamson J (2016) Unequal gains: American growth and inequality since 1700. Juncture 22(4):276–283

    Google Scholar 

  • Luzzato G (1968) L’economia italiana dal 1861 al 1894. Einaudi, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1907) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1904. Tipografia nazionale G, Bertero, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1908) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1905. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1911) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1906. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1912a) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1910. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1912b) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1911. Tipografia nazionale G, Bertero, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1913) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1907. Tipografia nazionale G, Bertero, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1914) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1912. Tipografia nazionale G, Bertero, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1915) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1908 e 1909. Tipografia nazionale G, Bertero, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura Industria e Commercio Ufficio del lavoro (1916) Statistica degli scioperi avvenuti in Italia nell’anno 1913. Tipografia ditta L, Cecchini, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Mancini G (2018) Women’s labour force participation in Italy 1861–2011. Riv Stor Econ 34(1):3–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic B (2016) Global inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Morcaldi M (2004) Le scuole industriali (1880–1930). Formazione e capitale umano, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Nuvolari A, Vasta M (2015) The ghost in the attic? The Italian national innovation system in historical perspective. Enterp & Soc 16(2):270–290

    Google Scholar 

  • Nuvolari A, Vasta M (2017) The geography of innovation in Italy 1861–1913: evidence from patent data. Eur Rev Econ Hist 21(3):326–356

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke K, Williamson J (2017) The spread of modern industry to the periphery since 1871. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Olivetti C, Petrongolo B (2016) The evolution of gender gaps in industrialized countries. Ann Rev Econ 8(2):403–434

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortaggi Cammarosano S (1991) Labouring women in northern and central Italy in the nineteenth century. In: Davis JA, Ginsborg P (eds) Society and politics in the age of the risorgimento. Essays in honour of Denis Mack Smith. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 152–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Prado S (2010) Fallacious convergence? Williamson’s real wage comparisons under scrutiny. Cliometrica 4(2):171–205

    Google Scholar 

  • Prados de la Escosura L (2015) World human development: 1870–2007. Rev Income Wealth 61(2):220–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridolfi L (2019) Six centuries of real wages in France from Louis IX to Napoleon III: 1250–1860. J Econ Hist 79(3):589–627

    Google Scholar 

  • Saxonhouse GR, Wright G (2010) National leadership and competing technological paradigms: the globalization of cotton spinning 1878–1933. J Econ Hist 70(3):535–566

    Google Scholar 

  • Società Umanitaria (1907) Le condizioni generali della classe operaia in Milano: Salari Giornate di lavoro Reddito ecc. Ufficio del lavoro, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Soldani S (1981) L’istruzione tecnica nell’Italia liberale (1861–1900). Studi Storici 22(1):79–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Sori E (1979) L’emigrazione italiana dall’Unità alla seconda guerra mondiale. Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Spitzer Y, Zimran A (2018) Migrant self-selection: anthropometric evidence from the mass migration of Italians to the United States 1907–1925. J Dev Econ 134:226–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor AM, Williamson J (1997) Convergence in the age of mass migration. Eur Rev Econ Hist 1(1):27–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Leeuwen M, Ineke M et al (2002) Hisco-historical standard classification of occupations. University Press Leiden, Leiden

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Zanden JL (2009) The skill premium and the ‘great divergence’. Eur Rev Econ Hist 13(1):121–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasta M (1999) Capitale umano e Ricerca scientifica e tecnologica. In: Amatori F, Bigazzi D, Giannetti R, Segreto L (eds) Storia d’Italia Annali 15—L’industria. Einaudi, Torino, pp 1041–1124

    Google Scholar 

  • Vitali O (1970) Aspetti dello sviluppo economico italiano alla luce della ricostruzione della popolazione attiva italiana attraverso i censimenti. Istituto di Demografia Università di Roma, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Tunzelmann GN (1995) Technology and industrial progress. Edward Elgar, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis P (2008) Apprenticeship and training in Premodern England. J Econ Hist 68(3):832–881

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson J (1985) Did British capitalism breed inequality?. Unwin Hyman, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson J, Lindert P (1980) American inequality. A macroeconomic history. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeev BN, Mokyr J, Van Der Beek K (2017) Flexible supply of apprenticeship in the British industrial revolution. J Econ Hist 77(1):208–250

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Maria Angeles Pons and Mauro Rota for sharing their data with us and Gabriele Cappelli, Giulia Mancini, Luca Mocarelli, and Tiziano Razzolini for very useful comments and suggestions. We thank Alberto Montesi and Sara Pecchioli for excellent research assistance. The paper has benefited from the comments of all participants at the 8th edition of EH/tune Economic History Workshop (Siena, 2018), the FRESH meeting (Groningen, 2018), the Economic History Society Annual Conference (Belfast, 2019), the BETA Workshop (Strasbourg, 2019), the 16th Annual STOREP Conference (Siena, 2019), the European Historical Economics Society Conference (Paris, 2019), and the Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne’s International economics and labor markets seminar (Paris, 2019).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Leonardo Ridolfi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Figs. 15, 16, and 17 and Tables 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, and 13.

Fig. 15
figure 15

Wage observations by year and skill level in manufacturing

Fig. 16
figure 16

Wage observations by region and macro-area

Fig. 17
figure 17

Sources and Notes as in Fig. 9

Wages of strikers in manufacturing in Italy (1903–1913).

Table 5 Wage observations by source
Table 6 Unskilled occupations
Table 7 Low-skilled occupations
Table 8 High-skilled occupations
Table 9 Wage observations by sector
Table 10 Sources for international comparisons
Table 11 Literacy rate by countries (1860–1913)
Table 12 Strikes’ motivation and outcomes, Italy (1901–1913)
Table 13 Technical and vocational education in Italy (1862–1911)

Appendix 2: List of sources for wages

2.1 Primary sources

ISTAT-DGS-MAIC (1885) Annali di statistica, Serie III, vol. 14. Tipografia eredi Botta, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1887) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1886. Tipografia eredi Botta, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1888) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1887–1888. Tipografia eredi Botta, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1893) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1892. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1904) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1904. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1908) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1905–1907. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1912) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1911. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1913) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1912. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1914) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1913. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

ISTAT-DGS (1915) Annuario Statistico ltaliano 1914. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma.

MAIC (1904–1922) Bollettino dell’Ufficio del lavoro. Tipografia nazionale G. Bertero, Roma (ad annum).

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio (1905) Materiali per lo studio delle condizioni dei lavoratori della terra nel Mezzogiorno, vol 1 Capitanata e Puglie. Pubblicazioni dell’Ufficio del Lavoro, Roma.

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio, Ufficio del lavoro (1908) Notizie sulle variazioni dei Salari e degli orari nell’industria serica italiana dal 1901 al 1907. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma.

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio, Ufficio del lavoro (1910) Le condizioni di lavoro nell’industria laterizia in Italia. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma.

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio, Ufficio del lavoro (1911) Salari ed orari nell’industria edilizia in Italia negli anni 1906–1910. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma.

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio, Ufficio del lavoro (1911) Salari ed orari nell’industria serica italiana nell’anno 1909. Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma.

MAIC—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio (1913) Tariffe di salario e di orario nell’arte muraria (1911 e 1912). Officina poligrafica italiana, Roma.

MAIC-DGA—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio—Direzione Generale dell’Agricoltura (1876–1879) Relazione intorno alle condizioni dell’agricoltura in Italia nel quinquennio 1870–74. Tipografia Barbera, Roma.

MAIC-DGS—Ministero di Agricoltura, Industria e Commercio—Direzione Generale di Statistica (1862–1878) Salari. Prezzi medi di un’ora di lavoro degli operai addetti alle opere di muratura ed ai trasporti di terra e mercedi medie giornaliere degli operai addetti alle miniere. n. d., Roma.

2.2 Secondary sources

Aleati G (1961) Le retribuzioni dei lavoratori edili in Milano, Pavia e nei rispettivi territori dal 1819 al 1890. ILTE, Torino.

De Maddalena A (1974) Prezzi e mercedi a Milano dal 1701 al 1860. Banca Commerciale Italiana, Milano.

Di Rollo F (1965) Le retribuzioni dei lavoratori edili a Roma dal 1826 al 1880. ILTE, Torino.

Felloni G (1963) Le retribuzioni dei lavoratori edili a Genova dal 1815 al 1890. ILTE, Torino.

Felloni G (1998) Un secolo di salari edilizi a Genova 1815–1913, pp. 1217–1230, «Atti della Società Ligure di Storia Patria, nuova serie», XXXVIII/2.

Hansen B (1985) Wage Differentials in Italy and Egypt. The Incentive to Migrate before World War I. J Eur Econ Hist 14(2):347.

Levi G (1966) I salari edilizi a Torino dal 1815 al 1874. In: Maturi W (ed) Miscellanea. Giappichelli, Torino pp 366, 372, 378.

Societa Umanitaria (1907) Le condizioni generali della classe operaia in Milano: Salari, Giornate di lavoro, Reddito, ecc. Editore l’Ufficio del lavoro, Milano.

Appendix 3: Estimate of the effects of emigration

We follow the partial equilibrium approach by Taylor and Williamson (1997). By definition, the effect of a change in labour supply L* on wages is equal to the labour supply change times the elasticity of labour demand η:

$$ w^{*} = \eta^{ - 1} L^{*}. $$

Taylor and Williamson (1997) show that η−1 is equal to:

$$ \eta^{ - 1} = - \sigma^{ - 1} \left( {1 - \theta } \right) $$

where σ is the elasticity of substitution in the production function and θ is the share of labour. We compute separately the effects on skilled and unskilled wages, assuming the elasticity to be the same. We estimate w* with two different no-emigration counterfactual hypotheses. We compute total migration since 1876 (‘long run’) or 1903 (‘short run’), and we compare it with (an estimate of) the number of skilled and unskilled workers in 1911.

We retrieve the total number of emigrants, gross and (since 1902) net, the division by gender, and the share of ‘condizioni professionali’ (working) from Statistiche ISTAT (Tables 2.9.1 and 2.9.2) and the number of emigrated farming emigrants (labourers, farmers, and tenants) from Annuario Statistico dell’emigrazione (Commissariato generale dell’emigrazione, various years). We compute the total number of working male emigrants as net migrants times the share of males in total migrants (assuming the same percentage of returns for males and females) times the share of working people for both genders.Footnote 32 This latter assumption clearly understates the number of working males, as the share of workers was substantially higher for males than for females. We assume that all farmers and 15% of other (non-farming) emigrants were unskilled. This yields a total of 6.1 million unskilled and 0.7 million skilled migrants in the long run (and, respectively, 2.6 and 0.4 since 1903). We get the number of male workers by sector in 1911 from Vitali (1970, tab. 1). We count as unskilled all males working in agriculture, 42% of workers in construction (MAIC-DGS, Population census of 1911, vol. V, tab. 7, p. 345) and 25% of workers in manufacturing and services for a total of 7.6 million out of 11.2 million males in gainful occupation. This implies that skilled workers (3.7 million) accounted for 32.7% of the total. The long-run no-emigration counterfactual amounts to an increase in the workforce of 80% for unskilled and 19.5% for unskilled workers (35% and 10.5% for the short run). According to Giordano and Zollino (2015), labourers got 66% of GDP in 1911. We disaggregate this share between raw labour (of all workers) and human capital (of skilled ones only) as:

$$ \theta_{\text{u}} = L_{\text{u}} /\left( {L_{\text{u}} + \, L_{\text{s}}\,{\cdot}\,s} \right)\,{\cdot}\, \theta $$

where Lu and Ls are total unskilled and skilled workers, respectively, and s, the skill premium, is assumed to have been 1.5. The formula yields a share of 41.7% for raw labour and 24.2% for human capital. Thus, with a unitary elasticity σ = 1 (i.e. a Cobb-Douglass), demand elasticities are equal to − 0.58 and − 0.76.Footnote 33 Without emigration, wages of unskilled and skilled workers would have been 43% and 17.4% lower, respectively, while the skill premium would have been 39% higher.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Federico, G., Nuvolari, A., Ridolfi, L. et al. The race between the snail and the tortoise: skill premium and early industrialization in Italy (1861–1913). Cliometrica 15, 1–42 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-019-00200-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-019-00200-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation