1 Introduction

Ecuador is an unequal country. In 2000, the official income-based Gini coefficient reached 0.565 (SIISE 2016a). Since then, however, and in line with the general trend observed in Latin America, inequality in Ecuador has fallen significantly (Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010; Lustig et al. 2013; Ponce and Vos 2014; ECLAC 2017). According to SICES (2017), by 2016 its Gini coefficient had fallen to 0.466. Between-group inequality has also decreased. For instance, the ratio of household per capita income between urban and rural households fell from 2.38 in 2005 to 1.69 in 2016.

Inequality reduction in Ecuador—both vertical (i.e. at the individual level—VI) and horizontal (i.e. between groups—HI)—was particularly large between 2007 and 2011. This period coincides with the first half of the leftist government of President Rafael Correa, which was characterized by its redistributive policies including increases in social spending, public employment, and cash transfers. It also coincides with the peak of oil prices, which meant large windfalls for the Ecuadorian government.

In the context of concurrent oil windfalls and redistributive policies, we ask whether the recent reduction in inequality is sustainable, i.e. if the current level of inequality can be maintained over time. We recognize that further inequality reductions are difficult to achieve (e.g. it is harder to reduce the Gini coefficient from .45 to .40 than it is to reduce it from .55 to .50), and thus we do not expect the decline in inequality to continue in the future; we expect inequality to remain at the current level. We would also like to determine the extent to which the observed reduction in inequality is due to the oil revenues or to the redistributive policies. This is a difficult endeavour because of the simultaneity between these two factors. As we discuss below, the main challenge is that it is precisely the abundance of resources that allowed the government to implement these policies.

To shed light into the question of sustainability we look briefly at the theoretical arguments that have been put forward to explain the relationship between commodity booms and inequality, and also look at some empirical evidence. Gylfason and Zoega (2003) develop a theoretical model showing that the abundance of natural resources leads to increased inequality and provide empirical evidence of this effect in a cross-country sample. Their view is consistent with the notion that revenue accruing from oil and minerals is often unequally distributed because elites hold control over the resources and, as a consequence, tend to direct them towards their own benefit. Likewise, Buccellato and Mickiewicz (2009), in a study of the effect of oil and gas on inequality among Russian regions, find that production of these resources increases inequality within the regions. Loayza and Rigolini (2016) find a similar effect of mining in Peru’s districts. Contrary to these results, Howie and Atakhanova (2014) find that a resource boom led to a reduction in inequality within Kazakhstan’s regions.

Indeed, as pointed out by Ross (2007), the effect can go in either direction. On the one hand, assuming that there are limits to intersectoral labour mobility, inequality should increase following a Dutch Disease argument. The rise in oil exports leads to an appreciation of the real exchange rate, which in turn causes a fall in the competitiveness of sectors other than oil. If the distribution of natural resources is relatively unequal, the associated fall in employment in those sectors will cause inequality to rise. On the other hand, Ross (2007) points out that a mineral boom may lead to increased government employment due to the rise in revenue. Since governments tend to compress salaries of their employees, the added public employment would cause inequality to fall. As we point out in this paper, these are clearly not the only mechanisms through which a resource boom can affect inequality. Most importantly, public policies and institutions may have an important effect.

In the case of Ecuador, revenue from the oil boom has been successfully used to finance an expansion of the cash transfer program as well as social security and retirement pensions, both of which have contributed to reduce inequality. As the boom came to an end, however, keeping inequality low has become increasingly costly. As a consequence, we argue that the lower levels of inequality are unlikely to be sustainable in the medium run. Most importantly, the strong economic growth observed since 2008—with the exception of 2009—has morphed into a recession in 2016, and it is expected to continue in 2017 and 2018, followed by weak economic growth up to 2022 (International Monetary Fund 2017). The reduction in inequality stopped after 2011, and poverty and extreme poverty started to increase following the drop in oil prices in 2014. Weak growth has also meant a deterioration of public finances, and the rise of private and public debt. Because macroeconomic conditions in Ecuador are not expected to change in the near future, the pressure on public finances is likely to increase, turning fiscal consolidation unavoidable. As we explain below, this will drastically limit the ability of the government to continue with its redistributive policies.

Goderis and Malone (2011) provide theoretical and empirical evidence along these lines. They find that although a natural resource boom is associated with a contemporaneous inequality reduction, this effect diminishes gradually as time goes by, until it disappears in the long-run. Our argument is quite similar, but we emphasize different mechanisms. In the short-run, redistributive policies financed with the windfalls from the boom are the key contributors to reducing inequality. In the long-run, deterioration of the fiscal and external sectors, along with labour market distortions and institutional decay are the culprits that lead to the disappearance of this effect.

Throughout the paper, we focus on measures of both vertical inequality (VI) and horizontal inequality (HI). Recent research highlights the relevance of each type of inequality for different outcomes. Stewart (2000, 2008) provides evidence that HI plays a central role to explain humanitarian crises and conflict; Donoso et al. (2015) and Stewart (2016) show that VI is relevant to explain criminality. Furthermore, as a middle point between aggregate VI and HI we also analyse within-group VI. This is important because, as argued by Stewart (2008), conflict is more likely to occur when intra-group differences are small—providing cohesiveness to the group—and inter-group differences are large—highlighting the notion of the “other”.

The contributions of the paper are threefold. First, we present a long-run overview of VI and HI in Ecuador, and highlight the progress made during the period 1990–2016, especially during the commodities boom. The analysis of HI is particularly relevant because, to the best of our knowledge, there are no studies on this regard for Ecuador. Second, we provide empirical evidence of the lack of sustainability of the recent inequality reduction in Ecuador. Our focus here is on the fiscal and external imbalances that emerged after the 2008 financial crisis, as well as the labour market downturn and institutional deterioration that followed. Finally, we provide a political economy explanation for this result.

The paper is structured as follows. In the next section we discuss Ecuador’s long-term trends in VI and HI. Section three looks at the dynamics of inequality for the 2005–2016 period, and analyses the links with the commodities boom and government’s policies. Section four provides a brief explanation for these results, and section five concludes.

2 Long-Term Trends of VI and HI in Ecuador

Ecuador is a Latin American middle-income country characterized by its geographic, economic, and ethnic diversity. In 2014, its human development index (HDI) was 0.732, corresponding to the high human capital category (World Bank 2017). Ecuador has experienced significant social and economic progress in recent years. Gross national income (GNI) per capita reached 5246 in 2015 (in 2010 PPP $), compared to 3413 in the year 2000 (World Bank 2017). Inequality has fallen significantly and poverty declined from 64.4% in 2000 to 22.5% in 2014 (SIISE 2016a). To understand the significance of the recent progress regarding inequality in Ecuador, in this section we look at VI and HI from a long-term perspective.

2.1 Vertical Inequality (VI)

Figure 1 provides VI measures for Ecuador for the 1963–2015 period. We include the Ecuadorian official series of income-based Gini coefficients (SIISE 2016a), as well as Gini coefficients from ECLAC (2017) and World Bank (2017). These are survey-based data and thus provide reliable information; their main limitation is that national data are only available for a few years before 2000. To complement these measures, we also include information from the University of Texas Inequality Project—EHII (2016).Footnote 1 This dataset provides information on the Gini coefficient for the period 1963–2008.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on data from ECLAC (2017), World Bank (2017), SIISE (2016a), and EHII (2016)

Ecuador: Inequality over time, 1950–2015.

Inequality in Ecuador has varied significantly over time. Based on the EHII data, there was a large fall in inequality during the 1970s. This is relevant for our analysis because the reduction in inequality during this period coincides with the start of oil extraction in Ecuador and the first oil boom. Oil was discovered in 1967 and oil exports began in August, 1972 (Gachet et al. 2011). Between 1971 and 1978 the Ecuadorian economy grew by an average of 8% per year (Central Bank of Ecuador 2012) and the Gini coefficient—based on EHII data—fell almost six percentage points (see Fig. 1). As is the case with the latest commodities boom, inequality reduction in Ecuador during the 70 s resembles the experience of other countries in Latin America during the same years (with the exception of Argentina, Chile and Uruguay) (Birdsall et al. 2011; Gasparini and Lustig 2011).

The end of the oil boom at the beginning of the 1980s along with the military conflict with Peru and the onset of the debt crisis led to a decline in Ecuador’s economic growth. The economic deceleration was associated with an increase in inequality, which at the end of the decade had reverted back to the level preceding the oil boom (see Fig. 1). In the 1990s, inequality continued to rise amid adjustment policies and market-oriented reforms (Ponce and Vos 2014); and, in 1999 the floods caused by El Niño and the drop of oil prices led to an economic and financial crisis (Gachet et al. 2011).Footnote 2 As a consequence, poverty and inequality increased. The evolution of inequality during the 1980s and 1990s is also reminiscent of other Latin American countries, although their experiences were more heterogeneous during the latter decade (Gasparini and Lustig 2011).

Figure 1 also shows that starting in 2000 inequality in Ecuador fell significantly. Data from SIISE (2016a), ECLAC (2017), and World Bank (2017) provide a similar picture of strong inequality decline. The EHII data show a decline at the beginning of the 2000s followed by an increase in the middle of the decade. The increase is also shown in the other databases, although it seems less dramatic.Footnote 3 The drop in the 2006–2014 period from a Gini coefficient of .540 to .467 (SIISE 2016a) is remarkable as it implies a decline in the Gini coefficient of almost one percentage point per year. The picture for Latin America is similar, although less pronounced: from 2002 to 2014 the Gini coefficient fell six points (0.55–0.49) (ECLAC 2017). Thus, it seems that the commodities boom helped reduce inequality in the majority of countries in the region, despite their heterogeneous policies.

Several lessons follow from this brief analysis. First, inequality in Ecuador tends to fluctuate significantly over time once we look at a longer historical period. This means that the common notion of persistent inequality in Ecuador should be reconsidered. In particular, persistence does not seem to imply that inequality does not change, but that it tends to revert back to its original high level. Second, inequality in Ecuador tends to follow general regional trends. Third, and most importantly, the recent reduction of inequality is not the first one in Ecuador. A similar fall in inequality occurred during the 1970s, precisely during the first oil boom.

Some authors, looking at survey-based data, argue that the current reduction of inequality in Latin America constitutes a break with the region’s history (Birdsall et al. 2011; Cornia 2014; Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010; ECLAC 2015). As shown above for the case of Ecuador, the fall in inequality—while remarkable—constitutes a break with history only if we do not look back beyond the 1980s. The evidence presented above for Ecuador, as well as additional evidence provided by Gasparini and Lustig (2011) for other Latin American countries, shows that inequality also fell during the 1970s.

The dynamics of inequality for Ecuador and Latin America during commodity booms seems at odds with the argument presented by Ross (2007) and Ross et al. (2012). According to these authors, revenue accruing from oil and minerals is often unequally distributed within countries because elites hold control over the resources and, as a consequence, tend to direct them towards their own benefit. Thus, contrary to our observations, a resource boom is expected to increase inequality. In light of this argument, Ecuador’s recent reduction of inequality is indeed remarkable, and the reduction that took place during the 1970s even more so. Most of that decade the country was governed by a dictatorship and thus governing elites had weak political incentives to distribute oil revenues.

The fact that the abundance of resources does not automatically translate into a reduction in inequality highlights the relevance of government’s policies. Social spending (mainly in education), cash transfer programs and other government policies play an important role in reducing inequality (Tsounta and Osueke 2014). But, despite the policies’ contribution to reducing inequality, our interpretation of the historical evidence is that they are feasible only when revenues from resource booms become available. In Ecuador, oil windfalls helped sustain strong economic and employment growth, which combined with increased social spending, government employment, and cash transfer programs, led to a large fall in inequality. As shown in Fig. 1, because resource booms are temporary, these reductions in inequality tend to be inherently unsustainable.

2.2 Horizontal Inequality

HI is important in Ecuador because of its social, economic, and political cleavages. The Ecuadorian population is composed of an important fraction of indigenous and Afro-Ecuadorians, who are concentrated in different parts of the country. There are at least 13 indigenous nationalities distributed across the country (SIISE 2017). According to Alesina et al. (2003), ethnic fractionalization in Ecuador in 1989 was 0.6550, language fractionalization 0.1308 and religious fractionalization 0.1417.Footnote 4 Likewise, according to Fearon (2003) cultural fractionalization in Ecuador was 0.48. These ethnic and cultural scores make Ecuador one of the most fractionalized countries in Latin America.

As argued by Stewart (2000), ethnicity and cultural differences are not the only relevant dimensions to define social cleavages; class and regional location may also matter. In our analysis we make an attempt to balance relevant cleavages with the availability of historical data and representativeness of the survey samples. We include four dimensions: ethnicity, gender, area, and poverty. Before turning to these dimensions, however, we present the databases used.

2.2.1 Inequality Databases

We use three different sources of data, as shown in Table 1: national censuses (1990, 2001, and 2010), living standard measurement surveys (LSMSs) (1995, 1998, 1999, 2006, and 2014) and December Employment Surveys (ESs) (2005–2016).Footnote 5 We discuss each one of these sources in turn.Footnote 6

Table 1 Ecuador: principal microeconomic databases, 1950–2016.

In Ecuador, seven censuses have been implemented (1950, 1964, 1974, 1982, 1990, 2001, and 2010), but complete data files are only available for the last three. Censuses have the advantage of covering the whole population, but at the cost of not acquiring much information. Most importantly, they do not collect data on either income or consumption, which are the standard variables for measuring poverty and inequality. Thus, to categorize an individual as poor or non-poor in the censuses we use the concept of unsatisfied basic needs (UBN).Footnote 7 To calculate inequality we use years of education.Footnote 8

Because of these limitations, we complement the censuses with two sets of surveys: the LSMSs and the ESs. Ecuador’s LSMSs collect information on many dimensions of household well-being such as housing characteristics, consumption, sources of income, some labour market characteristics, educational attainment, and access to public services, among others. These are used to assess household welfare, understand household behaviour, compute consumption poverty lines and evaluate the effect of various government policies on living conditions. They, as well as the censuses, are carried out by Ecuador’s National Institute of Statistics and Censuses (INEC). Six LSMSs have been conducted in the country (1994, 1995, 1998, 1999, 2006 and 2014), but complete databases are only available starting with 1995. Up to 1999, they are representative only at the national, urban and rural levels. The last two surveys are also representative at the provincial level and for the main cities. Besides having comparable information over time with little methodological changes, an important element of the LSMSs is that it is possible to calculate educational attainment. An additional advantage is that the 1998 and 1999 LSMSs provide information on the effects of the 1999 crisis on VI and HI. Furthermore, the years 1999–2014 coincide with the period of strong poverty and inequality reduction in Ecuador, with the rise of President Correa’s government and also with the peak of the last oil boom. The main limitation of the LSMSs—especially in the older datasets—is that the size of the sample does not allow to separate all ethnic groups or to combine various dimensions simultaneously (e.g. gender and ethnicity).

The ESs are national surveys currently carried out quarterly by Ecuador’s National Institute of Statistics and Censuses (INEC). The ESs cover a wide range of economic and socio-demographic information such as labour data, different sources of income, housing, migration, education, and other social indicators, and are used mainly to estimate labour market indicators (unemployment, underemployment, etc.) and poverty rates using income poverty lines. Up to 2002, ESs were conducted in November of each year for urban households only, with the exceptions presented in Table 1. Since 2007, they appear quarterly for urban households, and twice a year (June and December) for urban and rural households, excluding the Galapagos Islands before 2014. The ESs provide information representative at the national level starting in 2003, but we only use data since 2005 because we found inconsistencies in the 2003 and 2004 datasets.

2.2.2 Dimensions of Analysis

We focus on four dimensions of HI that capture the most relevant aspects of between-group inequality in Ecuador:

  1. 1.

    Language (non-indigenous vs. indigenous), as a proxy for ethnic cleavages. This is a dichotomous variable defined as 1 if there is a person in the household who speaks an indigenous language and 0 otherwise. We highlight this variable in our analysis of ethnic cleavages because of comparability over time. It is not possible to have long series on ethnicity in either the censuses or the LSMSs using data on ethnic groups because self-reported identification is only available starting with the 2001 census and the 2006 LSMS.Footnote 9

  2. 2.

    Gender (male vs. female).

  3. 3.

    Area (urban vs. rural).

  4. 4.

    Poverty (non-poor vs. poor). This variable is defined in a different way for censuses, LSMSs, and ESs. In the first case, it is based on unsatisfied basic needs (UBN), as explained above. In the LSMSs it is determined by a household consumption-based per capita poverty line, and in the ESs it is determined by a household income-based per capita poverty line. LSMSs and ESs are used to calculate Ecuador’s official poverty measures (based on consumption and income, respectively). ESs poverty data is used to monitor this indicator due to its high frequency.

Because we use education as our main variable to measure VI and HI over the full period, we focus our analysis on people who are 15 years old and above.

Table 2 provides a first glance at VI and HI over time. It presents information based on all the censuses (the three columns on the left) and LSMSs (the five columns on the right) for which we have data. There are four panels showing the population division by language spoken (indigenous vs. non-indigenous), gender, living area, and poverty. In each case, the table shows the shares of the relevant groups in the population and average years of education. In the case of LSMSs, it also shows average consumption.

Table 2 Ecuador: educational attainment and consumption, censuses and LSMSs, 1990–2014.

Let us first consider education. Consistent with the improvement observed worldwide (Barro and Lee 2015), years of education in Ecuador have increased significantly at the aggregate level and also for every subgroup. This progress is concentrated in the last part of the period. Average years of education have increased by around two full years in the last quarter of a century.

As expected, people who do not speak an indigenous language, men, people living in urban areas, and the non-poor have more years of education relative to their respective counterparts, although there is significant heterogeneity. For example, while in 2014 the difference in average years of education between people that do not speak an indigenous language and people that do -and also between people living in urban areas versus those living in rural areas- is around 3.5 years, the difference between men and women is less than .16 years.

Progress among disadvantaged groups (people who speak an indigenous language, women, people living in rural areas, and the poor) has been stronger than among their advantaged counterparts. To see this, we introduce the concept of RAD: the ratio of advantaged to disadvantaged, which we use throughout the paper. The RAD compares the average value of a variable (years of education, household per capita consumption, and household per capita income) for the advantaged and disadvantaged group in each dimension of analysis (language, gender, area, and poverty). Because we calculate this ratio for each year of the available databases, it provides a first glance at the dynamics of horizontal inequality in Ecuador. As can be seen, in every panel, the ratio of years of education of the advantaged group to the disadvantaged group (RAD) has fallen. The most significant variation occurs among groups classified by language where the ratio falls from 2.03 to 1.49 based on the censuses. This means that, while in 1990 people who did not speak an indigenous language had slightly more than twice as many years of education than people who did, they had only 49% more years of education in 2010. A similar trend can be observed in the other panels.

The LSMSs show that this progress has not been monotonic. As mentioned before, the LSMSs also capture the years 1998 and 1999 in which Ecuador suffered a serious economic and financial crisis. It is notable how between 1998 and 1999 the RAD increases for all four dimensions. The most dramatic change is the one based on language, where the RAD goes from 1.61 to 2.01. Indeed, between these years there was a decline in average years of education among people who speak an indigenous language and those living in rural areas. This may seem strange, but some possible reasons include migration and also a change in the pattern of education accumulation as people—especially those belonging to disadvantaged groups—were forced to leave school due to the impact of the crisis. An increase in the RAD for education in 1999 thus shows how households facing an economic slowdown may neglect their education.

The effect of the 1999 crisis is even clearer when we analyse household per capita consumption, which is also presented in Table 2. Consumption in 1999 fell for every group in every panel relative to 1998.Footnote 10 Moreover, this occurred despite the fact that consumption already fell in 1998 relative to 1995, consistent with the economic slowdown. While the RAD for poverty, and area did not change much between 1998 and 1999, the rise in the RAD for language (1.78–2.14) should be noted. This change means that consumption among indigenous language speakers fell even more than among speakers of a non-indigenous language. In addition, in the language and poverty panels, the RAD increased between 1999 and 2006, falling only thereafter. This might occur because the post-crisis recovery among disadvantaged groups takes place more slowly, or it might reflect a change in policies after 2006. As mentioned above, the available data do not allow for disentangling the two effects.

Comparing education and consumption, the consumption-based RADs tend to be higher than the corresponding education-based RADs. This is consistent with intuition as there is much more variation in consumption than in education. The most extreme case is shown in the poverty panel. On average, the consumption-based RAD in this panel was 3.91 (i.e. the non-poor consumed on average close to four times what the poor consumed), but the education-based RAD was only 1.66, which means that the non-poor had only 66% more years of education than the poor.

Finally, it is important to highlight the large increase in average consumption between 2006 and 2014. In this period, consumption grew by a factor greater than 3.2 (and by a factor close to four for indigenous language speakers), while the CPI increased by around 40%.Footnote 11 This rise in consumption is consistent with the large increase in resources during the oil boom.

Next, we turn to a more detailed analysis of vertical and horizontal inequality among groups. Table 3 shows aggregate Gini coefficients, within-group Gini coefficients, and group-based Gini coefficients (GGini) based on the censuses and the LSMSs. The main difference with Table 2 is that Gini coefficients look at the entire distribution and not only the means, as is the case with the ratios of advantaged to disadvantaged (RADs). As before, we include years of education for the censuses and LSMSs, and also household per capita consumption for the latter.Footnote 12

Table 3 Ecuador: Gini and group-weighted Gini, censuses and LSMSs, 1990–2014.

Looking at the data based on the censuses, the first notable result is the reduction in VI, especially during the period 2001–2010. The education-based Gini coefficient went from 0.38 in 1990 to 0.31 in 2010. The same trend can be observed in all disaggregated groups, except for the non-poor for whom there was an increase up to 2001 and a decrease thereafter. A similar reduction can be seen based on the LSMSs for the period 1995–2014.

Second, all disadvantaged groups show higher VI than the corresponding advantaged ones. This is important because it is a signal that there exists heterogeneity regarding education among disadvantaged groups and thus, that cohesiveness among them may be weak. Third, in part because of the larger initial inequality among disadvantaged groups, inequality has fallen more among these groups than among the advantaged ones. The greatest difference is between people that speak an indigenous language and those that do not. While the Gini coefficient among the former fell from .37 to .31 over the period 1990–2010, it fell from .61 to .42 for the latter. A similar dynamic can be observed based on the LSMSs for the period 1995–2014. The education-based Gini coefficient fell from .34 to .29. There were stronger declines for the disadvantaged groups who, despite these declines, still face consistently higher within-group inequality.

Between-group inequality (HI) has also decreased, but with important variations across dimensions. Language HI increased during the period 1990–2001 and then fell back to around the original level by 2010. The gender GGini fell by around 87% during the same period. The largest decline in absolute terms occurred for area, where the GGini fell by 0.04 during this period. Looking at the LSMSs, education-based HI also fell. As before, however, the crisis had a strong effect: HI increased in 1998 and 1999 relative to 1995 in all cases except area, where it fell marginally.

Looking at consumption provides again a more complete picture. VI declined over the 1995–2014 period at the aggregate level and also within groups, except for the non-poor. HI fell for area and poverty, but it actually increased for language. Interestingly, while education-based Gini coefficients are higher for disadvantaged groups, this is reversed in the cases of area and poverty for the consumption-based Gini coefficients. Most dramatically, the Gini for non-poor has been around twice as high as the one for the poor.

Looking at education and consumption together, it is notable that the reduction in VI and HI did not occur during the whole period, but mainly in the period 2006–2014. Indeed, consumption-based VI was higher in all cases in 2006 than in 1995, and it fell only thereafter. The 1998–1999 crisis also contributed to this pattern. In all the dimensions analysed, the 1999 levels of consumption-based VI and HI were higher than in 1995. Furthermore, as discussed above, the crisis seems to have had a stronger effect on VI among disadvantaged groups. For instance, consider the non-poor versus poor during the 1995–1999 period. While the Gini for the former group increased by less than .005, it increased by almost .3 for the latter. In percentage terms, these changes correspond to 1 and 16%, respectively. Thus, consumption VI tends to increase during the crisis, and even more for disadvantaged groups. Consistent with this, HI also increased during the crisis: the consumption-based GGini was larger in 1998 and 1999 than in 1995 for all groups.

To conclude this section, we note that the long-run analysis of VI and HI shows that the inequality dynamics are much more complex than just a reduction over time. There has been great progress with regard to education since 1990, although most of it took place after 2000. In general, disadvantaged groups have reduced the educational gap and, particularly in the case of men and women, this gap has been almost completely closed. The crisis of 1999 had a negative effect on the accumulation of education, especially among some disadvantaged groups, who seem to have faced more difficulties in recovering from it. With regard to consumption, most of the reduction in VI and HI occurred in the last period (2006–2014). Overall, there has been significant progress in reducing inequality. As this progress seems to have concentrated in the latter period, in the next section we turn to the analysis of VI and HI during the commodities boom.

3 VI and HI During and After the Commodities Boom

In this section we analyse the dynamics of VI and HI in the period 2005–2016 and its relationship with the commodities boom. We provide evidence that the trend of VI and HI reduction has stopped and argue that there is evidence that inequality may start fluctuating in the near future.

3.1 Dynamics of VI and HI

Table 4 provides December data on years of education and household per capita income for the period 2005–2016 based on the ESs. We focus the analysis on income, as this is the variable on which official poverty lines, and poverty and vertical inequality indicators are constructed in Ecuador.

Table 4 Ecuador: educational attainment and income, ESs, 2005–2016.

The first aspect that we note is the very large increase in income over the period 2005–2015. Income increased by 91%, while the CPI increased by 51%. This implies an increase in real income of over 20% in 10 years. Likewise, during this period, average years of education increased by more than one year. In 2016, however, we already observe a reversal of this trend as nominal income fell by 4.2%, while CPI rose by 1.1%.

Consider next the evolution of VI and HI. Because we look at consecutive years, changes are more nuanced than in the analysis of the previous section. Despite this fact, we are able to establish various general patterns in line with the evidence presented above.

Let us first take a brief look at education. Consistent with the general trend, average years of education increased almost monotonically over the period for each group, except in the poverty panel. Indeed, in this case, it might seem that not much progress has been made, particularly among the non-poor. However, this is explained in large part by the reduction in poverty. Over the period 2005–2016 the share of poor fell from 37 to 20%. Because the poor tend to be less educated than the non-poor, the mobility of the former into the non-poor pushes down average years of education among the non-poor. Furthermore, if the former poor are on average more educated than the remaining poor—which seems likely—their exit also pushes down average years of education among the poor. Thus, the progress in average years of education shown in the poverty panel provides a lower bound for the actual improvement that took place.

Regarding the education-based ratios of advantaged to disadvantaged (RADs), there is a slow but consistent decline, particularly after 2012. The decline for gender is limited because the educational gap between men and women at the beginning of the period was already very small (.21 years). By 2016, it fell to 0.06 years. This is an important milestone regarding gender equality, as it means that women are acquiring essentially as many years of education as men.Footnote 13

Income has a similar evolution as education, but the data show early signs of a reversal in the last year. There was a strong increase in income for every group up to 2014. In 2015, income continued to increase for every group except those who speak an indigenous language; and in 2016 income fell across the board. Interestingly, in all cases the RADs fell between 2015 and 2016, meaning that so far the negative effect of the economic slowdown has been stronger for the advantaged than for the disadvantaged.

Table 5 provides further information on the 2005–2016 period, including measures of VI and HI. With regard to education, the pattern of VI and HI is also one of consistent decline until 2014. After this, only in the case of gender do we observe a clear continuation of the trend. In the other three panels, there are initial signs of stagnation.

Table 5 Ecuador: Gini and group-weighted Gini, ESs, 2005–2016.

With regard to per capita income, there is also a pattern of decline of VI at the aggregate level and for all groups until 2014. HI also fell, especially in the cases of poverty and area. The most interesting dynamic, however, appears at the end of the sample between 2014 and 2016. Within-group inequality continued to fall among advantaged groups, but it increased among all disadvantaged groups. For instance, while the Gini coefficient for people who do not speak an indigenous language fell from .4601 to .4561 between these years, for people who speak an indigenous language it went from .4753 to .4914. HI also increased in the cases of language and poverty. For the former, HI increased from .0245 to .0337, while for the latter it rose from .1450 to .1537.

We conclude that—for the most part—the cleavages in the four dimensions analysed have been reduced during the last 25 years. All databases show a consistent story along this line, be it in terms of educational attainment, consumption or income. However, consistent with our argument, using the most recent data we showed that there are initial signs of stagnation and, in some cases, of a trend reversal.

3.2 Effects of the Commodities Boom

The evidence presented so far shows that Ecuador has reduced its VI and HI in the last decades. In some cases, as in gender and area, existing cleavages have been reduced significantly. However, the data presented in the last section also show the first signs of stagnation, both in terms of VI and HI.

In this section we look at Ecuador’s experience with the commodities boom and argue that the recent reduction in inequality, while remarkable, was dependent on the windfalls obtained from the oil boom. To see the context in which the reduction of VI and HI took place, Table 6 summarizes the main macroeconomic, social, and public sector indicators of Ecuador for the period 2005–2016.

Table 6 Ecuador: macroeconomic indicators, 2005–2016.

With the exception of 2009, 2015 and 2016, GDP growth in Ecuador during the period analysed has been very strong. Indeed, between 2004 and 2014 the average growth rate of GDP was 4.48%. The three years of slow or negative growth were associated with unfavourable external conditions, which can be seen as large drops in the real price of oil and the terms of trade. On the contrary, the years of high growth were associated with increases and/or high levels of these variables. As a consequence, for the period 2005–2016 the correlation between the change in the real price of oil and GDP growth was .71. During this period, as already discussed, poverty and inequality (VI and HI) fell significantly. Although admittedly crude, a simple way to see the relation between the oil boom and the reduction in inequality is to look at the correlation between the changes in the Gini coefficient and the changes in the oil revenues of the Non-financial public sector (NFPS). For the period analysed, this correlation is − .65.

The recovery following the drop in oil prices in 2009 was sharp, as the shock turned out to be temporary. Following the decline, the real price of oil reached a peak in 2012, while the terms of trade peaked in 2013. In spite of the fast recovery, the initial shock already changed the macroeconomic structure of Ecuador. The trade balance, which had been positive since 2005, became negative in 2009, and remained negative until 2015. The clearest effects, however, took place in the public sector. The primary surplus became negative in 2009 and shifted from a peak of 4.83% of GDP in 2006 to a low of − 5.88% in 2016. The financing needs shifted from − 2.91% in 2006 to 7.48% in 2016. Public internal and external debt as a percentage of GDP—which had reached a minimum in 2009 following a decision of the Ecuadorian government to stop its debt payments in December 2008—have more than doubled since then, and in 2016 were the highest of the whole period.Footnote 14

These macroeconomic changes have important consequences for the mechanisms that helped reduce inequality in Ecuador, as we explain in detail below. The Social policies panel in Table 6 provides a first look at them. Public social spending as a percentage of GDP increased monotonically between 2005 and 2013. After that, however, it started to decline falling around one percentage point. Spending on the cash transfers program also increased starting in 2008. It reached a peak of 1.08% in 2013, declining significantly afterwards.Footnote 15 Indeed, in 2015, the cash transfer program represented a smaller fraction of GDP than it did in 2008. Of course, a large part of this reduction follows from the “graduation” process that started in 2013, according to which beneficiary households not living in extreme poverty had to exit the program. However, looking at the years 2014 and 2015, the decline in expenditure on the program (as a percentage of GDP) is not consistent with the rise in extreme poverty. Indeed, between 2014 and 2016 poverty and extreme poverty increased. Inequality has stagnated after 2011.

Considering this context, in what follows we analyse the causes of the recent inequality reduction in Ecuador. There are several possible mechanisms, which we discuss in turn.

Following Gasparini et al. (2016), the first reason for the reduction in inequality is the recovery following a crisis. As these authors mention, the crises at the end of the 1990s in Latin America led to increases in inequality, which were reverted during the recovery that followed. But, once the recovery took hold, the equalizing effect ended. At first glance, this might seem consistent with the Ecuadorian experience and the crisis of 1999, as indeed we do have evidence of an increase in VI and HI during the crisis (see Table 3) and a decline thereafter (see Fig. 1). However, if this is the case, the dynamic ended during the first half of the 2000s. According to EHII (2016), the income-based Gini coefficient in 2005 was only slightly lower than in 1999 (see Fig. 1). Likewise, following the Ecuadorian LSMSs, the consumption-based Gini coefficient was almost identical in 1999 and in 2006 (see Table 3). The strongest reduction in VI and HI occurred between 2007 and 2014 (see Fig. 1 and Table 5), and thus the argument explains only a small part of the Ecuadorian experience.

An additional argument is that the reduction in inequality comes from changes in the labour market. First, the expansion of education that took place during the 1990s should reduce the earnings gap between skilled and unskilled workers in the 2000s due to the increased supply of the former (Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010; Lustig et al. 2013; Ponce and Vos 2014). Second, the government may use public employment as a means of redistributing income when other tax-based redistribution mechanisms are more difficult to implement (Alesina et al. 2000). Third, associated with the commodities boom and the availability of resources, employment and minimum salaries may rise.

Tables 7 and 8 provide evidence on these mechanisms. Table 7 portrays the dynamic of the minimum nominal wage along with other labour market variables at the aggregate level and by groups.Footnote 16 There has been a strong rise in the minimum wage, far above the increment in the CPI.Footnote 17 Between 2007 and 2016, the minimum wage increased by 115% while the CPI rose by 43%, implying an increment in the real minimum salary of 50%. The improvement in the minimum wage, however, has occurred in parallel with a more complex dynamic of the aggregate labour market variables: labour force participation, unemployment and underemployment (see Table 7).Footnote 18 The evolution of these variables is u-shaped, i.e. they fell at the beginning of the period in line with the fall in inequality; but then, at some point between 2012 and 2014, they started to rise again. By 2016, unemployment and underemployment were higher than in 2007. The largest effect occurs with underemployment. From an initial level of 18.24% in 2007, it reached a minimum of 9.01% in 2012, only to then rise to 19.87% in 2016. This is probably the clearest example of the cycle that Ecuador has gone through in the last decade.

Table 7 Ecuador: labour market indicators, ESs, 2007–2016.
Table 8 Ecuador: labour market mechanisms of inequality reduction, ESs, 2005–2016.

To further understand the evolution of the labour market over the period, the lower panels of Table 7 present the same labour market variables but disaggregated for each one of the groups analysed throughout the paper. This shows a mechanism that allow to explain the absence of a reversion of inequality so far: a different response by advantaged and disadvantaged groups. All groups reduced their participation in the labour force up to 2012–2013, increasing it thereafter. The interesting aspect is that in every case the disadvantaged group increased its labour participation much more than the advantaged one. For instance, while people who do not speak an indigenous language raised their participation by five percentage points, people who do speak an indigenous language raised it by almost 12 percentage points. The larger flexibility among disadvantaged groups can help them cope better with an economic slowdown, at least initially, by sending to work more household members and thus compensating for the reduced income. Yet, looking at the underemployment panel, we see the limitations of this strategy. Although underemployment rose among all groups since 2012, the largest increments occurred among people who speak an indigenous language (over 12 percentage points) and the poor (almost 16 percentage points). Moreover, in 2016 the levels of underemployment are higher than they were in 2007 for all groups except people living in rural areas. As a consequence, disadvantaged groups will find it increasingly difficult to continue raising their participation, and the benefits from underemployment are likely to become smaller as the labour market turns more competitive.

Unemployment shows a complementary dynamic. There has been a rapid deterioration among advantaged groups since 2014, particularly in the cases of language and area. In the latter case, while unemployment among rural households remained essentially unchanged since 2010, among urban households it increased by around two percentage points between 2014 and 2016.

Table 7 thus shows how the disadvantaged groups’ response to cope with the economic slowdown has been more aggressive in terms of increased participation. This has helped them compensate for lost income and, as a consequence, we still do not observe large increases in poverty and/or inequality.

Table 8 provides a comparison of public versus private employment. Between 2005 and 2015 the share of public employment increased by 2.37 percentage points, which might seem small but represents an increment of 29%. In 2016 this share fell. Labour income also increased consistently between 2005 and 2016, falling in both sectors only in 2016 and in the private sector in 2009. Although labour income in the public sector was significantly larger throughout the period, the RADs—either in terms of average or median income—do not show a clear trend. The final panel presents a comparison between skilled and unskilled workers. During the period the share of the skilled workers increased by 2.17 percentage points, which is consistent with the idea that increments in education should lead to a larger share of skilled workers. Consistent with Lustig and Lopez-Calva (2010), Lustig et al. (2013), and Ponce and Vos (2014), the ratio of skilled to unskilled average and median incomes has fallen over the period, although with significant fluctuations.

Tables 7 and 8 thus show that the mechanisms mentioned above have actually taken place in Ecuador during recent years. Faced with a reduction in resources and an economic slowdown, these mechanisms for inequality reduction are not likely to continue in the future (Lustig et al. 2013; Ponce and Vos 2014).

A final mechanism for reducing inequality is to increase government transfers to the poor (Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010; Lustig et al. 2013; Ponce and Vos 2014), as well as social security and retirement pensions. In Ecuador, a cash transfer program began in 1998, and it was continuously expanded until 2013.Footnote 19 Until 2005, the grant was around USD 15 per month.Footnote 20 Starting in 2007, the government raised its value three different times: to USD 30 in 2007, USD 35 in 2009, and USD 50 in 2013. In line with these increments, the number of beneficiaries also increased dramatically over time. According to estimations based on the LSMS-2014, in 1998, there were close to 190,000 beneficiaries, but in 2013, the number reached over 1.57 million. Relative to other programs in Latin America, Ecuador’s cash transfer program was particularly large in terms of population coverage (44% in 2010 according to Cecchini and Mandariaga 2011) and its share of GDP (see Table 6). Since its peak in 2013, many beneficiaries graduated from the program because, due to their improved economic conditions, they did not satisfy the participation requirements anymore.

To see the effects of the cash transfer program, in Table 9 we show the results of a decomposition of income inequality by source for the period 2005–2016, based on the methodology proposed by Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985).Footnote 21 These authors show that the Gini coefficient of total income, G, can be written as:

$$G = \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{K} S_{k} G_{k} R_{k} ,$$
(1)

where \(G\) is the Gini coefficient, \(S_{k}\) is the share of component \(k\) in total income, \(G_{k}\) is the Gini coefficient of income source \(k\), and \(R_{k}\) is the correlation between income source \(k\) and total income. \(R_{k}\) measures the strength and direction of the linear relationship between income source \(k\) and total income. Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985) derive the marginal effect of a percentage change in income source \(k\) (\(e_{k}\)) on inequality relative to the overall Gini:

$$\frac{{\partial G/\partial e_{k} }}{G} = \frac{{S_{k} G_{k} R_{k} }}{G} - S_{k}$$
(2)

Clearly, this effect can be positive or negative (or zero) depending on the relationship between the parameters. In particular:

$$\frac{{\partial G/\partial e_{k} }}{G}{ \gtrless }0 \quad {\text{if }}G_{k} R_{k}\,{ \gtrless }\,G,$$
(3)

i.e. the marginal effect is positive when income source \(k\) is relatively unequal with respect to total income and the correlation between source \(k\) and total income is relatively high.

Table 9 Ecuador: contributions of income sources to income-based inequality, ESs, 2005–2016.

We separate sources of income into labour, capital, cash transfers, remittances, and other sources of income.Footnote 22 Furthermore, we provide estimations of each component’s marginal effect on inequality.

The first aspect to note is that the shares of the different sources of income have changed during the period. On the one hand, since 2005 the share of labour income fell by almost five percentage points, representing only 82% in 2016. The share of capital income also fell, although not as much. And, consistent with the economic recession in the developed countries, the share of remittances declined since 2008. On the other hand, cash transfers have become more important over time, representing more than 3% of income at the peak in 2013. These changes are in line with the increments in the value of the grant in 2007, 2009, and 2013. Consistent with the decline in the number of beneficiaries, the share of cash transfers has fallen since 2013. Finally, the share of other sources of income has increased by more than five percentage points over the period, highlighting the expansion of social security benefits and retirement pensions.

In general, cash transfers have an equalizing effect, while labour, capital and other sources of income contribute to increase inequality. The effect of remittances is unclear, as it shifts signs over the years. However, it seems that their effect has become more equalizing during the second half of the period.

The marginal effect of labour income lies between .01 and .02 for most of the period and is significant in most years. This range implies that a 1% increase in labour income is associated with a 1–2% increase in the Gini coefficient. The effect of capital income is similar in magnitude, although with more precise coefficients. Cash transfers have a stronger negative effect. A 1% increase in cash transfers leads to a reduction in the Gini coefficient of 1.2–4.8%. Remittances have a much smaller effect. In the second half of the period an increase of 1% is associated with a fall in the Gini coefficient of .1–.3%. The fact that remittances have an equalizing effect—although small—may seem counterintuitive. In Ecuador, the majority of households with international migrants are in the upper quantiles of the income distribution, and the amounts that they receive are also larger. Indeed, the Gini coefficient of remittances is significantly larger than the Gini coefficient of total income. However, the correlation between remittances and total income is small. In terms of (Eq. 3), although \(G_{k} > G\), \(R_{k}\) is small, and thus the marginal effect ends up being negative. It is important to note that this result is consistent with the findings of Acosta et al. (2008). Finally, other sources of income contribute to increase inequality, with a 1% increment leading to a .2–1.4% increase in the Gini coefficient.

Two main conclusions follow from the income decomposition. First, part of the reduction in inequality comes from the shift in shares from labour income to other sources of income and cash transfers. To understand the mechanism, consider labour and other sources of income. While income from other sources tends to increase inequality, the magnitude of the effect is much smaller than the effect of labour income. As a consequence, a shift in the shares away from labour income translates into a lower level of inequality. Cash transfers have a strong equalizing effect, and thus an increase in their share leads to lower inequality.

Second, because cash transfers and other sources of income come mainly from government resources, there seem to be two possible outcomes given the current fall in oil revenues. Either people will become more dependent on these resources or they will face a decline in their income as the government is no longer able to provide them. The limited evidence seems to show both effects. On the one hand, other sources of income represent an ever increasing share of income. On the other hand, the reduction in the number of beneficiaries of the cash transfers program since 2013 has lowered its share in income as well as its marginal effect.

These results are important because they show that a significant part of the reduction in income inequality came through expanded government benefits. The economic slowdown following the fall in oil prices has led the government to reduce its cash transfers program, and also its contributions to social security and pensions programs. As the economic downturn deepens, however, there will be more pressure on these benefits and a reform will become inevitable.

To provide additional evidence on the lack of sustainability of inequality reduction in Ecuador, we conclude this section with an analysis of the evolution of poverty over the period 2005–2016. The reduction in inequality should help reduce poverty (Bourguignon 2004) and, as shown in Table 6, the reduction in inequality in Ecuador has indeed gone hand in hand with a reduction in poverty and extreme poverty.

We use the poverty decomposition proposed by Son (2003), who decomposes the change in poverty in three components and explicitly considers between-group variations. The components are: within group growth effect, within group inequality effect, and population shift among groups, i.e. changes in the share of each of the groups.Footnote 23

Table 10 shows the results for each of the dimensions that we have analysed throughout the paper: language, gender, and area.Footnote 24 As can be seen, poverty declined in most years, except in 2009, 2015 and 2016. Growth during this period tended to be pro-poor in the sense that it contributed to reducing poverty. The contraction of 2016 contributed to a rise in poverty with respect to 2014. The effect of inequality is perfectly in line with intuition. In years in which inequality increased, it contributed to a rise in poverty, and in years in which it declined, it contributed to reducing poverty.

Table 10 Ecuador: contributions of growth, inequality, and group share changes to poverty, ESs, 2005–2016.

The general perspective provided by Table 10 is that economic slowdowns tend to increase poverty. This is clearly shown for the contraction in 2016. More importantly, the drop in oil prices since 2014 has changed the dynamics of poverty, which has been higher in the last two years than in 2014. In 2015 this was mainly due to the effect of a rise in inequality and in 2016 it was mainly due to the economic contraction.

The dynamics of poverty shown above and especially the recent rise thereof, provide further evidence of the unsustainable path of inequality reduction. After an economic boom, increases in poverty are associated with increases in inequality. Thus, as poverty rises, we expect inequality to rise as well.

4 Discussion

The previous section provided evidence that Ecuador’s large inequality reduction during the last decade is not sustainable. Here, we present a discussion and a possible explanation for this result, consistent with much of the literature on the resource curse, and the historical Latin American experience.

As discussed by Gasparini et al. (2016), the Ecuadorian experience of inequality reduction is not isolated. The decline in inequality was a regional phenomenon, as is the recent stagnation, although with some heterogeneity. Consistent with previous studies, the reduction in growth will most likely lead to an increase in inequality and poverty (Psacharopoulos et al. 1995; Ravallion and Chen 1997; Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010). On the one hand, the closing gap between skilled and non-skilled workers’ salaries followed at least in part from the strong demand for commodities, whose production is intensive in low-skilled workers. The fall in the prices of commodities means a lower demand for this type of workers, which in turn implies a decline in their relative wages. On the other hand, slow economic growth means lower taxes, which limit social spending (including education) and also transfer, social security, and pension programs. Indeed, Aldunate and Martner (2006) argue that social spending in Latin America has a large pro-cyclical bias.

The dynamic of inequality is, to a large extent, a reflection of the lack of sustainability of the policies followed during the last decade. Despite the optimism of some authors regarding a change in macroeconomic policies (see e.g. Sáenz 2014), the fall in the price of commodities has uncovered the structural weaknesses of some Latin American economies, and Ecuador in particular. The lack of sustainable social policies along with the suboptimal administration of fiscal resources means that part of the progress made may be lost in the next years. In this context, authors such as Lustig et al. (2013) and Ponce and Vos (2014) emphasize the need for a change in the economic structure so that it becomes less dependent on commodities—particularly oil—, an improvement in the quality of education, and a broad-based tax reform. The recent experience shows that these mechanisms are hard to implement.

But the real challenge lies elsewhere. As argued by Acemoglu et al. (2003), macroeconomic imbalances—and their consequences—are symptoms of a deeper cause: institutional weaknesses, and particularly weak political institutions that distribute power unequally. In the context of inequality reduction, it seems that the lack of sustainability comes from the pro-cyclical policies followed by the governments in charge of administering the revenues from the commodities boom. Reducing inequality in social and economic dimensions requires sustained redistributive policies, which in turn require strong democratic institutions (Robinson 2006; Lustig and Lopez-Calva 2010).

Reducing inequality thus requires political equality, understood as equality in the distribution of political power, political rights, influence, and access to the political system (Robinson 2006). The reason is that political institutions affect economic institutions and, most importantly, the political distribution of power affects the distribution of economic power in a virtuous or vicious circle (Acemoglu et al. 2005). What needs to change then is not the elite in power but the incentives of the elite that comes to power.

Failure to understand this fundamental point risks falling into the iron law of oligarchy, which Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) describe as follows:

The iron law of oligarchy emerges when the current elite are replaced by newcomers, sometimes with a popular mandate, and yet once these newcomers are in power they have no incentive to change the oligarchic structure, and instead use the entrenchment provided by the existing political institutions for their own benefit (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006, p. 329).

When this occurs, weak political and economic institutions tend to persist and, as a consequence, social and economic outcomes such as inequality and poverty are difficult to change. Indeed, this perspective explains the pattern of persistent inequality in Ecuador shown above. While the country was able to reduce inequality in the past, the reversal that followed occurred precisely because of a lack of strong institutions.

Throughout its history, Ecuador has been characterized by institutional weaknesses as exemplified most recently by having had eight presidents in the period 1997–2007. Looking back over a longer time frame, Ecuador is notorious for its lack of institutional stability. During its republican period Ecuador has had 20 constitutions, each one lasting on average 9 years, and its laws are routinely disrespected. Furthermore, as discussed in Andrango et al. (2016), Ecuador is characterized by continuous political conflict and a disdain for institutions by strong political leaders.

After the 1997–2007 period of political and economic volatility—and thanks in large part to the high price of oil—since 2007 Ecuador has enjoyed a period of political stability and strong economic growth, accompanied by important social achievements. However, the country has become less democratic. Andrango et al. (2016) provide evidence on the reduction of executive constraints and the lack of freedom of the press. Table 11 shows disaggregated scores from Freedom House (2017) for the period 2005–2016. Higher scores imply more political rights and civil liberties.

Table 11 Ecuador: evolution of political rights an civil liberties, 2005–2016.

As can be seen, there is a clear trend towards lower scores. In Ecuador, the electoral process is dominated by the executive, and political pluralism and participation, as well as freedom of expression and organization rights have been severely limited. As a consequence, power has been centralized in the state and civil society has lost its voice and representation. A new governing elite has replaced the old one but, in the process, it has adopted similar behaviours, precisely along the logic of the iron law of oligarchy. The incentives of the elite have not changed, and the current elite has not made progress in changing the incentives for the future governments. Indeed, as argued by Conaghan (2016):

Using the 2008 Constitution as a starting point and with help from the judicial branch, Correa has overseen an exhaustive legal restructuring. Whether in his hands or those of a successor, the illiberal features now thereby entrenched will allow for nondemocratic governance to continue (Conaghan 2016, p. 117).

The abundance of resources due to the oil boom along with a new Constitution and extremely high popularity constituted a once in a generation opportunity to change these incentives. For example, Gachet et al. (2017) document the impressive fact that the middle class in Ecuador doubled between 2005 and 2015. Despite this and other significant improvements presented in this article, the lack of a democratic perspective prevented the country from taking advantage of this favourable time.

5 Conclusions

After a rise in inequality during the 1990s, Ecuador has experienced an important reduction in vertical and horizontal inequality during the last 15 years, and particularly during the last decade. This reduction in inequality coincided with an oil boom—two elements that do not necessarily go together. As argued by Ross (2007), and Ross et al. (2012), faced with a natural resource boom, politicians have an incentive to direct the revenues towards their own benefit. The reduction in inequality is an encouraging sign that politicians have at least in part resisted the temptation of concentrating the windfalls from oil. Maybe, at least in the short-run, the still fresh experience of the 1999 crisis and the significant political instability of the 1997–2006 period imposed an implicit check on politicians, who became more conscious of the need to respond to the electorate.

The progress made regarding poverty and inequality during the last 15 years is undeniable, as all the evidence presented here confirms. Moreover, education, consumption, and income gaps between advantaged and disadvantaged groups have all improved during this period. It is also undeniable, however, that there are early signs of a reversal, with poverty and inequality stagnating or rising.

As we mentioned in the introduction, at least two questions become relevant in this context. First, what were the causes of the reduction in inequality? The simultaneity between the rise to power of a leftist government and the peak of the oil boom makes it difficult to provide a definitive answer. Yet, there is evidence that government policies including expansion of the cash transfer program, public employment, higher minimum salaries, and social security benefits and pensions have contributed to the reduction in inequality. These policies, however, are all dependent on the availability of resources associated with the oil boom. Hence, while policies did matter, it seems highly unlikely that they could have been implemented in the absence of the windfalls from the commodities boom.

Second, there is the question to which we have attempted to provide an answer: are the results sustainable? The fall in the price of oil since October 2014 has led to a clear deterioration of Ecuador’s macroeconomic indicators, especially the fiscal ones. As a consequence, the well-being of Ecuador’s households, and particularly of the more vulnerable groups, is declining. The full effect of the economic slowdown, however, has been limited so far in large part thanks to the rise in internal and external public debt. But this cannot be sustained indefinitely and a broad reform will need to be implemented in the near future. Thus, the available evidence along with the economic prospects support the argument that the reduction in inequality was indeed unsustainable. It seems that the pattern of inequality presented in Fig. 1 for the 1970s and the 1980s is likely to repeat itself.

In the end, it clearly makes more sense to have slow but sustainable progress than spectacular results that are reversed soon after (Collier 2007). This sort of progress requires a strong democratic sense to promote political equality and to alter the elites’ incentives.