Skip to main content
Log in

Information environment and interfirm alliance

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Interfirm alliances require effective mechanisms that facilitate the integration of pertinent knowledge between independent firms. This paper examines whether a firm’s information environment helps improve collaborative outcomes. Using a large panel of firms engaging in global research and development (R&D) collaboration, we find that firms with better information environments are associated with a higher level of collaborative outputs and a broader scope of collaborative networks. The improvements in collaborative outcomes are more pronounced when alliance partners have a greater reliance on informal relationships instead of formal contracts. Further analysis shows that a better information environment helps foster a more durable relationship between partners. Lastly, a path analysis shows that facilitating interfirm collaboration is one of the main channels through which transparency boosts a firm’s innovative productivity. Overall, our findings suggest that the quality of a firm’s information environment plays a crucial role in sustaining efficient relational contracting in interfirm alliances.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The number of interfirm alliances has been growing 25% per year since 1985. Alliances have consistently produced a return on investment of close to 17% among the top 2,000 companies in the world for a decade. That’s 50% more than the average return on investment for those same companies.

  2. Another example is Qualcomm and Daimler's joint development of new technologies to enable wireless charging of electric vehicles as well as in-car wireless charging of mobile devices (Forbes 2015). Other examples of interfirm collaboration include Samsung selling displays to Apple; General Motors and Ford sharing transmission technologies, and Google placing advertisements for Yahoo (Brandenburger and Nalebuff 2021).

  3. Relational contracting theories suggest that cooperative and efficient behaviors can be sustained through reciprocal interactions in a long-term relationship, even though formal agreements are not fully enforceable through third parties. For more examples in relational contracting theories, see (Bernheim and Whinston 1998; Bull 1987; Halac 2012; Levin 2003; MacLeod and Malcomson 1989).

  4. The alliance between General Motors (GM) and Toyota is a classic example. GM was keen to learn some of Toyota’s manufacturing management practices, whereas Toyota wanted to learn how to manage labor and how to run a manufacturing plant in the United States. However, both partners needed to prevent leakage of some of their core proprietary skills, i.e., Toyota’s small car design and supplier management and GM’s management of its dealerships.

  5. Although public firms could file confidential treatment (CT) requests with the SEC to protect some information from public disclosure for a time, there are two limitations. First, it is uncertain whether a request would be approved. Second, such requests can only be justified if the information is immaterial to investors but is proprietary in nature.

  6. This differs from financial contracts where the lenders usually assume oversight authority and impose restrictive covenants upon violation.

  7. These contracts are necessarily self-enforcing. The partners must jointly understand the implicit relational knowledge, including “actions that constitute cooperation,” as well as “the payoff to cooperation for each party, of each party’s ability and incentive to defect, and of the actions and payoffs that constitute punishment” (Gibbons and Henderson 2012).

  8. While firms can privately communicate with collaborative partners, unverifiable and distorted information can also lead to mistrust given the private interests of each party. Instead, verified public information and information from analysts can help minimize information asymmetries among partners, allowing them to make reliable inferences about the prospects of collaboration.

  9. The alliance between General Motors and Toyota is a classic example of such a dilemma. General Motors was keen to learn some of Toyota's manufacturing management practices through the alliance, whereas Toyota wanted to learn how to manage U.S. labor and how to run a manufacturing plant in the United States from GM. However, both partners were also keen to prevent leakage of some of their core proprietary skills to the other. Toyota was keen to protect its skills of small car design, effective supplier management, and GM's ability to manage dealerships in the United States.

  10. Consistent with the literature (Griliches et al. 1987), we compute joint patent counts based on the patent’s application year, instead of its grant year, as the application year better captures the actual effective time of R&D. We also exclude those co-owned patents filed by individual inventors.

  11. As an untabulated sensitivity test, we also implement a lead-lag analysis in examining the effect of the information environment on subsequent collaboration. Our results are qualitatively unchanged.

  12. Using USPTO patent data to measure cross-country R&D performance has been widely adopted in international studies (Acharya and Subramanian 2009; Griffith et al. 2006; Hsu et al. 2014).

  13. We conduct several additional analyses on sample selection. First, we restrict our sample to successful collaborative firms with nonzero co-owned patents during sample period and find that our results are stronger. Second, to mitigate the concern that firm choice to engage in collaboration may not be random in a pooled sample, we construct a propensity-score-matched sample to eliminate the pre-treatment systematic differences between collaborating and noncollaborating firms that may be correlated with firm collaboration choice. Our inferences remain unchanged.

  14. To be sure, we also repeat our analysis using only the U.S. sample and find consistent results. Results are available upon request.

  15. As a robustness check, we also control for total R&D inputs by scaling our outcome variable by total R&D expenditure and report the results in Table 10. As shown, our results remain inferentially unchanged.

  16. The average number of joint patents filed is 0.022 (Table 2). An interquartile increase in IE translates into an increase in JOINT_PATENT of 0.014 * 0.220 = 0.003, i.e., from 0.022 to 0.025. The percentage change in the number of patent filings is 14%.

  17. The average number of partners is 0.049 (Table 2). An interquartile increase in IE translates into an increase in NUM_PARTNER of 0.022 * 0.220 = 0.005, i.e., from 0.049 to 0.054. The percentage change in the number of patent filings is 10%.

  18. Research suggests that formal contracts are less enforceable in countries with weak legal environments and thus the signaling role of accounting information in a contractual relationship may be more valuable (Bova and Pereira 2012; Chen et al. 2011; Chen et al. 2010a; Chen et al. 2010b; Fan and Wong 2002; Hope et al. 2011; Kaplan 1994a; Kaplan 1994b).

  19. The data is obtained from the World Bank database, with a coverage of 213 economies over the period 1996–2009. It is available for download at http://databank.worldbank.org/data/databases/rule-of-law. For a detailed description, see http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/pdf/rl.pdf.

  20. The data is available for download at http://scholar.harvard.edu/nunn/pages/data-0.

  21. As an untabulated analysis, we further examine whether transparency-duration relation varies with collaborative output. Supportive of a relational contracting perspective, we find that the positive effect of IE on DURATION is more pronounced when collaborative performance is low and partners have greater incentive to renege.

  22. Similar to Hirshleifer et al. (2013), we set missing R&D to zero in computing RDC. The RDC variable represents the R&D assets that would exist if firms capitalized annual R&D expenditures, assuming a straight-line method of depreciation and an annual depreciation rate of 20% over a five-year useful life (Chan et al. 2001; Lev et al. 2005).

  23. The coefficient estimate on IE alone in column (2) remains statistically significant, suggesting that transparency may also enhance R&D productivity through other channels, e.g., the reduction of agency cost (Zhong 2018).

  24. As shown by Bhattacharya and Daouk (2002), it is the first prosecution, rather than the introduction, of these laws that matters for capital market participants to update their priors. Note that we do not stipulate that insider trading enforcement per se leads to an improvement in the information environment but rather that these events proxy for changes in the disclosure and reporting policies of some firms around the time the enforcement happened. As an untabulated sensitivity analysis, we also use mandatory IFRS adoption as another economic shock to firm transparency and find consistent results.

  25. Insider trading can contribute to the timely incorporation of new information into stock prices. Fernandes and Ferreira (2008) find that, in their global sample of firms, tightening insider trading laws improves the information environment via either more informative stock prices or increased public information collection.

References

  • Acharya VV, Subramanian KV (2009) Bankruptcy codes and innovation. Rev Financ Stud 22:4949–4988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya VV, Baghai RP, Subramanian KV (2013) Labor laws and innovation. J Law Econ 56:997–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agndal H, Nilsson U (2010) Different open book accounting practices for different purchasing strategies. Manag Account Res 21:147–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SW, Cheng MM, Phua YS (2021) Influence of control precision and prior collaboration experience on trust and cooperation in inter-organizational relationships. Account Rev. https://doi.org/10.2308/TAR-2019-0514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ardito L, Messeni Petruzzelli A, Pascucci F, Peruffo E (2019) Inter-firm R&D collaborations and green innovation value: the role of family firms’ involvement and the moderating effects of proximity dimensions. Bus Strateg Environ 28:185–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyres N, Mayer KJ (2007) Contract design as a firm capability: an integration of learning and transaction cost perspectives. Acad Manag Rev 32:1060–1077

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyres N, Bercovitz J, Zanarone G (2020) The role of relationship scope in sustaining relational contracts in interfirm networks. Strateg Manag J 41:222–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A, Athreye S, Huang C (2016a) The paradox of openness revisited: collaborative innovation and patenting by UK innovators. Res Policy 45:1352–1361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A, Cohen WM, Walsh JP (2016b) The acquisition and commercialization of invention in American manufacturing: incidence and impact. Res Policy 45:1113–1128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R, Keohane R (1986) Achieving cooperation under anarchy: strategies and institutions. In: Oye KA (ed) Cooperation under anarchy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 226–254

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Baker G, Gibbons R, Murphy KJ (2002) Relational contracts and the theory of the firm. Q J Econ 117:39–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth ME, Landsman WR, Lang MH (2008) International accounting standards and accounting quality. J Account Res 46:467–498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belderbos R, Carree M, Lokshin B (2004) Cooperative R&D and firm performance. Res Policy 33:1477–1492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Whinston MD (1998) Incomplete contracts and strategic ambiguity. Am Econ Rev 88:902–932

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya U, Daouk H (2002) The world price of insider trading. J Finance 57:75–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya S, Ritter JR (1983) Innovation and communication: signalling with partial disclosure. Rev Econ Stud 50:331–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bova F, Pereira R (2012) The determinants and consequences of heterogeneous IFRS compliance levels following mandatory IFRS adoption: evidence from a developing country. J Int Account Res 11:83–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandenburger A, Nalebuff B (2021) The rules of co-opetition. Harv Bus Rev 99:48–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Bull C (1987) The existence of self-enforcing implicit contracts. Q J Econ 102:147–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bushman RM, Piotroski JD, Smith AJ (2005) Insider trading restrictions and analysts’ incentives to follow firms. J Finance 60:35–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan LK, Lakonishok J, Sougiannis T (2001) The stock market valuation of research and development expenditures. J Finance 56:2431–2456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chassang S (2010) Building routines: learning, cooperation, and the dynamics of incomplete relational contracts. Am Econ Rev 100:448–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen H, Chen JZ, Lobo GJ, Wang Y (2010a) Association between borrower and lender state ownership and accounting conservatism. J Account Res 48:973–1014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen F, Hope O-K, Li Q, Wang X (2011) Financial reporting quality and investment efficiency of private firms in emerging markets. Account Rev 86:1255–1288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen M-C, Evans III JH, Hwang Y (2010b) The effect of accounting on compensation design and employee turnover. Working paper, University of Pittsburgh

  • Chesbrough H (2006) Open innovation: a new paradigm for understanding industrial innovation. Open Innov Res New Paradigm 400:1–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough HW (2006) Open innovation: the new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Harvard Business Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough H (2010) Business model innovation: opportunities and barriers. Long Range Plan 43:354–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das TK, Teng B-S (2000) A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. J Manag 26:31–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer JH (1996) Specialized supplier networks as a source of competitive advantage: Evidence from the auto industry. Strateg Manag J 17:271–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyer JH (1997) Effective interfirm collaboration: how firms minimize transaction costs and maximize transaction value. Strateg Manag J 18:535–556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyer JH, Singh H (1998) The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Acad Manag Rev 23:660–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards TH, Ferrett B, Gravino D (2020) Inter-firm R&D collaboration within and across national borders. World Econ 43:810–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fahn M, Zanarone G (2022) Transparency in relational contracts. Strateg Manag J 43:1046–1071

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan JP, Wong TJ (2002) Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of accounting earnings in East Asia. J Account Econ 33:401–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandes N, Ferreira MA (2008) Insider trading laws and stock price informativeness. Rev Financ Stud 22:1845–1887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes (2015) Qualcomm and daimler announce strategic collaboration to develop in-car tech. Forbes, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R, Henderson R (2012) Relational contracts and organizational capabilities. Organ Sci 23:1350–1364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil R, Zanarone G (2017) Formal and informal contracting: theory and evidence. Annu Rev Law Soc Sci 13:141–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilson R, Sabel C, Scott R (2008) Contracting for innovation: vertical disintegration and interfirm collaboration. ECGI Law Working Paper 118

  • Grant RM (1991) The resource-based theory of competitive advantage: implications for strategy formulation. Calif Manag Rev 33:114–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greven A, Fischer-Kreer D, Müller J, Brettel M (2022) Inter-firm coopetition: the role of a firm’s long-term orientation. Ind Mark Manag 106:47–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffith R, Huergo E, Mairesse J, Peters B (2006) Innovation and productivity across four European countries. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 22:483–498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z, Pakes A, Hall B (1987) The value of patents as indicators of economic activity. Economic policy and technological performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gulati R, Gargiulo M (1999) Where do interorganizational networks come from? Am J Sociol 104:1439–1493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagedoorn J (2002) Inter-firm R&D partnerships: an overview of major trends and patterns since 1960. Res Policy 31:477–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hail L, Tahoun A, Wang C (2014) Dividend payouts and information shocks. J Account Res 52:403–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halac M (2012) Relational contracts and the value of relationships. Am Econ Rev 102:750–779

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart JF (1988) A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strateg Manag J 9:361–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer D, Hsu P-H, Li D (2013) Innovative efficiency and stock returns. J Financ Econ 107:632–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hope O-K, Thomas W, Vyas D (2011) Financial credibility, ownership, and financing constraints in private firms. J Int Bus Stud 42:935–957

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu P-H, Tian X, Xu Y (2014) Financial development and innovation: cross-country evidence. J Financ Econ 112:116–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kale P, Singh H, Perlmutter H (2000) Learning and protection of proprietary assets in strategic alliances: building relational capital. Strateg Manag J 21:217–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan SN (1994a) Top executive rewards and firm performance: a comparison of Japan and the United States. J Political Econ 102:510–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan SN (1994b) Top executives, turnover, and firm performance in Germany. J Law Econ Organ 10:142–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr JN (2018) Transparency, information shocks, and tax avoidance. Contemp Account Res forthcoming

  • Knight GA, Cavusgil ST (2004) Innovation, organizational capabilities, and the born-global firm. J Int Bus Stud 35:124–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut B, Zander U (1993) Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. J Int Bus Stud 24:625–645

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kothari SP, Leone AJ, Wasley CE (2005) Performance matched discretionary accrual measures. J Account Econ 39:163–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1998) Law and finance. J Political Econ 106:1113–1155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai R, Amour A, Yu A, Sun Y, Torvik V, Fleming L (2011) Disambiguation and co-authorship networks of the US Patent inventor database. Harvard Institute for Quantitative Social Science, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang MH, Lundholm RJ (1996) Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. Account Rev 71:467–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang MH, Lins KV, Miller DP (2004) Concentrated control, analyst following, and valuation: do analysts matter most when investors are protected least? J Account Res 42:589–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang M, Lins KV, Maffett M (2012) Transparency, liquidity, and valuation: international evidence on when transparency matters most. J Account Res 50:729–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lev B, Sarath B, Sougiannis T (2005) R&D reporting biases and their consequences. Contemp Account Res 22:977–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin J (2003) Relational incentive contracts. Am Econ Rev 93:835–857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenthaler U (2011) Open innovation: past research, current debates, and future directions. Acad Manag Perspect 25:75–93

    Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod WB, Malcomson JM (1989) Implicit contracts, incentive compatibility, and involuntary unemployment. Econom J Econom Soc 57:447–480

    Google Scholar 

  • Mouritsen J, Hansen A, Hansen CØ (2001) Inter-organizational controls and organizational competencies: episodes around target cost management/functional analysis and open book accounting. Manag Account Res 12:221–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicita A, Olarreaga M (2007) Trade, production, and protection database, 1976–2004. World Bank Econ Rev 21:165–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn N (2007) Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Q J Econ 122:569–600

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pae S (2002) Optimal disclosure policy in oligopoly markets. J Account Res 40:901–932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poppo L, Zenger T (2002) Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements? Strateg Manag J 23:707–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ring PS, Van de Ven AH (1992) Structuring cooperative relationships between organizations. Strateg Manag J 13:483–498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmonds K (1982) Strategic management accounting for pricing: a case example. Account Bus Res 12:206–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmonds K (1986) The accounting assessment of competitive position. Eur J Mark 20:16–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simons R (1990) The role of management control systems in creating competitive advantage: new perspectives. Account Organ Soc 15:127–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel ME (1982) Asymptotic confidence intervals for indirect effects in structural equation models. Sociol Methodol 13:290–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece D, Pisano G (1994) The dynamic capabilities of firms: an introduction. Ind Corp Change 3:537–556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tether BS (2002) Who co-operates for innovation, and why: an empirical analysis. Res Policy 31:947–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verrecchia RE (1983) Discretionary disclosure. J Account Econ 5:179–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vosselman E, Van der Meer-Kooistra J (2009) Accounting for control and trust building in interfirm transactional relationships. Account Organ Soc 34:267–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vrontis D, Christofi M (2021) R&D internationalization and innovation: a systematic review, integrative framework and future research directions. J Bus Res 128:812–823

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West J, Bogers M (2011) Profiting from external innovation: a review of research on open innovation. SSRN Electron J. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1949520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West J, Salter A, Vanhaverbeke W, Chesbrough H (2014) Open innovation: the next decade. Res Policy 43:805–811

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. Simon and Schuster, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang H, Lin Z, Lin Y (2010) A multilevel framework of firm boundaries: firm characteristics, dyadic differences, and network attributes. Strateg Manag J 31:237–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin X, Shanley M (2008) Industry determinants of the “merger versus alliance” decision. Acad Manag Rev 33:473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang IX, Zhang Y (2018) Insider trading restrictions and insiders’ supply of information: evidence from earnings smoothing. Contemp Account Res 35:898–929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhong R (2018) Transparency and firm innovation. J Account Econ 66:67–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zucker LG (1986) Production of trust: Institutional sources of economic structure, 1840–1920. Res Organ Behav 8:53–111

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Divya Anantharaman, Peter Demerjian, Ellen Engel, Atif Ellahie, Inder K. Khurana, Cheng-Few Lee (editor), Valeri Nikolaev, Raynolde Pereira, Bharat Sarath, two anonymous reviewers, and the workshop participants at the Annual Accounting Association meeting, International Accounting Section Midyear Meeting, Rutgers Business School, and University of Illinois at Chicago for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Feng Gao.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix A. Variable description

Appendix A. Variable description

Variables

Description

Source

Dependent variable

R&D collaboration

 JOINT_PATENT

= Natural log of one plus total number of joint patents

USPTO

 NUM_PARTNER

= Natural log of one plus total number of a firm's co-authorship for all joint patents applied in a given year

USPTO

 DURATION

= Number of years between the application year of first joint patent and that of last joint patent

USPTO

 LOG_DURATION

= Natural log of one plus DURATION

USPTO

R&D productivity

 PATENT/RDC

= Natural log of one plus total number of patents applied by a firm in a given year scaled by R&D capital (RDC). RDC is calculated as RDEXPt + 0.8*RDEXPt-1 + 0.6*RDEXPt-2 + 0.4*RDEXPt-3 + 0.2*RDEXPt-4, where RDEXP equals annual R&D expense

USPTO, Worldscope

 CITATION/RDC

= Natural log of one plus total number of citations summed across all patents applied by a firm in a given year scaled by R&D capital (RDC). RDC is calculated as RDEXPt + 0.8*RDEXPt-1 + 0.6RDEXPt-2 + 0.4*RDEXPt-3 + 0.2*RDEXPt-4, where RDEXP equals annual R&D expense

USPTO, Worldscope

Test variable

 DISC_ACCR

= Absolute value of discretionary accruals calculated based on Jones's model modified by Kothari et al. (2005). Discretionary accruals are estimated based yearly regressions across all firms within each country and industry (2-digit SIC code)

Worldscope

 INT_GAAP

= An indicator variable equals to one if the firm reports under IFRS or U.S. GAAP during the year and zero otherwise

Worldscope

 ANALYST

= Total number of analysts making a forecast for year t's earnings. Higher values indicate greater transparency

Worldscope

 ACCURACY

= Product of (-1) times the absolute value of the forecast error scaled by beginning stock price, where the forecast error is analysts' mean annual earnings forecast less the actual earnings as reported by I/B/E/S. Higher values indicate greater transparency

Worldscope

 IE

= A composite measure of information environment, calculated as the average of the scaled percentile rank of four variables: the inverse measure of DISC_ACCR, INT_GAAP, ANALYST, ACCURACY. If ACCURACY is unavailable, IE captures the average percentile rank of the remaining three variables

Worldscope

Control variable

 R&D

= Total research and development expenditure scaled by total assets

Worldscope

 PATENT

= Natural log of one plus total number of patents applied by firm in a given year

USPTO

 SALES

= Natural log of sales (in thousands of US$)

Worldscope

 EMPLOYMENT

= Natural log of one plus total number of employees (in thousands)

Worldscope

 ROA

= Net income before extrordinary items scaled by total assets

Worldscope

 SALES_GROWTH

= Annual change in net sales scaled by beginning total sales

Worldscope

 FIRM_AGE

= Natural log of one plus the number of years listed in Worldscope

Worldscope

 STOCK_ISSUE

= The sum of a firm's net equity issues (scaled by total assets) over a rolling five-year window ending in the current fiscal year. Higher values indicate greater access to external financing

Worldscope

 LEV

= Total liabilities scaled by total assets

Worldscope

 CFO

= Cash flows from operations scaled by total assets

Worldscope

 K/L

= Ratio computed as net property, plant, and equipment scaled by total number of employees

Worldscope

 CLOSE%

= Total number of shares held by insiders as a percentage of the total number of shares outstanding

Worldscope

 MTB

= Market value of equity divided by book value of equity

Worldscope

 HERFINDAHL

= Industry Herindahl index based on all firms within each country, where industries are defined by three-digit SIC code

Worldscope

 IND_GROWTH

= Average industry sales growth for firms within each country and industry, where industries are defined by three-digit SIC code

Worldscope

 INTRODUCTION

= An indicator variable capturing the introduction stage in a firm's life cycle, which equals one if CFO < 0, CFI < 0 and CFF > 0, and zero otherwise

Worldscope

 GROWTH

= An indicator variable capturing the growth stage in a firm's life cycle, which equals one if CFO > 0, CFI < 0, and CFF > 0, and zero otherwise

Worldscope

 MATURE

= An indicator variable capturing the mature stage in a firm's life cycle, which equals one if CFO > 0, CFI < 0, and CFF < 0, and zero otherwise

Worldscope

 DECLINE

= An indicator variable capturing the decline stage in a firm's life cycle, which equals one if CFO < 0, CFI > 0, and CFF ≤ or ≥ 0

Worldscope

 IMPORT

= the logarithm of the level of imports that the country has with the US in each year at each three-digit ISIC industry level

Nicita and Olarreaga (2007)

 EXPORT

= the logarithm of the level of exports that the country has with the US in each year at each 3-digit ISIC industry level

Nicita and Olarreaga (2007)

 REL_VALUE

= Ratio of value added in a three-digit ISIC industry in a particular year to the total value added by that country in that year

Nicita and Olarreaga (2007)

Conditioning variable

 WEAK

= An indicator variable capturing the strength of a country's legal environment, which equals one if a country (1) has civil law origin or (2) the value of rule of law index is below the sample median and zero otherwise

La Porta et al. (1998)

 RELATION_SPEC

An index measuring the degree to which firms in an industry rely on relationship-specific investments

Nunn (2007)

 CROSS_BORDER

= An indicator variable that equals to one if the co-owned patent in year t is generated based on cross-border (international) collaborations, and zero otherwise

USPTO

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gao, F., Zhong, R. Information environment and interfirm alliance. Rev Quant Finan Acc 60, 643–677 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-022-01105-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-022-01105-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation